Title: IPM and Agricultural Economics
1IPM and Agricultural Economics
2Outline
- 1. Decision Makers - This is Economics
- 2. Context for Making Decisions
- 3. What is Profit? How is it Calculated?
- 4. What are Externalities?
- 5. IPM and Pest Control Decisions Damping off
Example - 6. Risk Technology Adoption
3Outline
- 1. Decision Makers - This is Economics
- 2. Context for Making Decisions
- 3. What is Profit? How is it Calculated?
- 4. What are Externalities?
- 5. IPM and Pest Control Decisions Damping off
Example - 6. Risk Technology Adoption
4What are we talking about here?
- Economics is about making decisions The actions
taken (or not taken) have an impact from the farm
scale to global markets and on the local to
global environment - - Who are these decision makers?
- - On what information do they base their
decisions?
- For Later How is RISK different for
these decision makers? How does risk affect their
decisions? Consider both scale and the type of
risk
5Decision Makers
Information Source
- Experience
- Education
- Actual/Projected Prices
- Local Community
- Extension Agents
- Chemical Reps
- Scientific Advisors
- Agribusiness (esp. donors)
- International Trade Partners
- Constituents
- Marketing
- Nutrition Taste
- Availibility
- Farmers
- Policy Makers
- Consumers
- Agribusiness
- Processing Industry
- Distributors
- Insurance
6Making Decisions Utilitarianism
- Economic theory is often based upon the
philosophy of creating the greatest good for the
greatest number of people - Utilitarian philosophy suggests that decisions be
made with the ultimate objective of maximizing
societal welfare. -gtSimple only in theory - The most political act we do on a daily basis is
to eat, as our actions affect farms, landscapes,
and food businesses," (Jules Pretty)
7Outline
- 1. Decision Makers - This is Economics
- 2. Context for Making Decisions
- 3. What is Profit? How is it Calculated?
- 4. What are Externalities?
- 5. IPM and Pest Control Decisions Damping off
Example - 6. Risk Technology Adoption
8Lets Start at the Beginning We have at any
given time the economic and ecological conditions
for a given farm, city, region, country, or
global network
Ecosystem Services What the ecosystem offers
us
-Productive Soil -Water Resources -Pollination -En
ergy (Solar Fossil Fuel)
CONDITIONS FOR FARMING
Economic Services What the economy offers
us
QUESTION What influences the Economic and
Ecological Conditions for farming?
-Infrastructure -Markets -Lending
Institutions -Subsidies
9 IPM An Ecologically Complex Approach
- IPM tries to manage the agroecosystem to enhance
- ?resilience
- ?biodiversity
- ?sustainability
-
- In this context successful IPM is inextricably
tied to the - continued, long-term health of the
agroecosystem.
10What are Ecosystem Services?
- Anthropocentric perspective These are the
services humans derive from ecosystems. In
agriculture - Energy Processes Consider external and internal
E inputs - Hydrological functions (e.g. H2O purification,
runoff, ) - Biogeochemical Processes Nutrient Cycling, N
fixation - Soil Protection
- Crop Pollination
- Biotic Regulation IPM Pest Control, disease
regulation - Recreation Ecotourism
11The Big Picture Ecology and Economics
Ecosystem Services Valuation
Our Farms Finances Profitability
Ecosystem Services What the ecosystem offers
us
Economic Policy
Ecosystem Health
Our Farm Management
Information Knowledge Education
Information Knowledge Education
Economic Health
Environmental Policy
Economic Services What the economy offers
us
Our Farms Ecosystem
Economic Services Valuation
12The Big Picture Ecology and Economics
Ecosystem Services Valuation
Our Farms Finances Profitability
Ecosystem Services What the ecosystem offers
us
Economic Policy
Ecosystem Health
Our Farm Management
Information Knowledge Education
Information Knowledge Education
Economic Health
Environmental Policy
Economic Services What the economy offers
us
Our Farms Ecosystem
Economic Services Valuation
13A Little Reality
- Most farms and ranches have only limited
flexibility to respond to changing factors in
their environment because of narrow profit
margins and due to their fixed geographical
locations. - Every farm is a complex system of interacting
components in a natural and socioeconomic
environment. A high degree of management skill is
required of modern producers.
14How does IPM fit in here?
- One of the goals of IPM is to translate
ecological considerations into economic ones for
growers. - Understanding inherent externalized costs in many
agricultural practices.
15Externalized Costs
- What are externalized costs?
- In order to really understand externalized costs,
one must first understand the components of profit
16Outline
- 1. Decision Makers - This is Economics
- 2. Context for Making Decisions
- 3. What is Profit? How is it Calculated?
- 4. What are Externalities?
- 5. IPM and Pest Control Decisions Damping off
Example - 6. Risk and Technology Adoption
17The Bottom Line Profit
- How would you define Profit?
- If you were growing a hothouse of tomatoes and
selling them all to Wegmans, how would you
calculate your profit? - What dictates revenues?
- Where do costs come from?
- Which costs are flexible?
- Which are fixed?
- Are there any real costs that are not considered
in a profit analysis?
18Costs and Benefits
- Since resources in any given scenario are often
fixed, there are limitations to production. The
concept of opportunity cost reminds us that every
time we make a choice, something else must be
given up. Economists would call this weighing the
marginal benefits against the marginal costs. - These concepts are useful in constructing
- Cost Benefit Analysis
- Maximizing Profit/Utility
- Evaluating Economic Efficiency
- How do we define what constitutes a cost or a
benefit?
19Marginal Costs
- Marginal Costs are the additional costs imposed
when one more unit of a given product is
produced. If a bakers cost of making 10 carrot
cakes is 15 and the cost of making 11 is 17,
the marginal cost of producing the tenth is 2. - Marginal costs tend to rise as production
increases. When trying to clean up the air, for
example, the first efforts are relatively
inexpensive. A law can mandate, for example, that
the dirtiest cars be taken off the road. But as
one tries to make the air cleaner and cleaner,
more expensive technology is needed. Therefore,
marginal costs rise.
20(No Transcript)
21Marginal Benefits
- Marginal Benefits are the additional benefits
received when one more unit is produced. - Marginal Benefits tend to fall as consumption of
a good or service increases. This is because the
first few pieces of cake are very appetizing when
one is hungry. But with each additional piece,
the added benefits to the person diminish. Then
you get sick and cant even finish your coffee. - Generally speaking, the marginal benefits curve
slopes downward. For example, if we are used to
breathing filthy air and that air has been
cleaned for the first time, the health benefits
are large. But when one breathes relatively clean
air already and that air is made even cleaner,
the health benefits are not as dramatic.
22EfficiencySupply, Demand, and Price
23Beyond Profit
- What goals might growers have besides profit?
- What about Agribusiness? -Policy Makers?
-Consumers?
24Outline
- 1. Decision Makers - This is Economics
- 2. Context for Making Decisions
- 3. What is Profit? How is it Calculated?
- 4. What are Externalities?
- 5. IPM and Pest Control Decisions Damping off
Example - 6. Risk Technology Adoption
25Back to Externalities
- Externalized Costs It is well acknowledged many
unsustainable practices are possible only because
society bears these costs rather than the
individuals making agricultural decisions.
Examples? - gt Costs to Society Agricultural activities are
some of the most serious and widespread sources
of pollution, soil erosion, loss of biodiversity,
and overall destruction of environmental quality
worldwide. - gt Costs to farmers Degradation of soil and
overall agroecological health leads to increased
external/purchased inputs
26Externalities and Economic Inefficiency
27Economic Growth Some Issues
- What we conventionally call economic growth in
the sense of growth of the economy has
ironically become uneconomic growth in the
literal sense of growth that increases costs by
more than it increases benefits. - As the scale of the economy expands relative to
the fixed dimensions of an ecosystem, we
necessarily encroach upon that system and must
pay the opportunity cost of lost ecosystem
services as we enjoy the extra benefit of
increased human scale. - We see that increasing marginal costs and
decreasing marginal benefits will accompany
increasing human scale. The optimum scale, from
the human perspective, occurs when marginal cost
equals marginal benefit this is the point of
greatest efficiency. Beyond that point growth
becomes uneconomic in the literal sense of
costing more than it is worth.
28Faulty Assumptions Behind Some of Our Cost
Benefit Analysis
- 1. Markets exist for all goods and services
exchanged - 2. This implies that all goods and services are
private not public goods. - 3. A system of property rights exists.
- 4. All markets are perfectly competitive
- 5. No externalities exist - all the benefits
and costs of producing goods are reflected in the
market price of goods - 6. Both producers and consumers have perfect
information regarding available goods and their
prices. - 7. All producers aim to maximise their profits
while all households attempt to maximise their
welfare or utility. - 8. There are no costs associated with trading
goods other than their prices and production
costs (i.e. transaction costs are zero).
29Part II IPM and Agricultural Economics
30Outline
- 1. Decision Makers - This is Economics
- 2. Context for Making Decisions
- 3. What is Profit? How is it Calculated?
- 4. What are Externalities?
- 5. IPM Pest Control Decisions Damping off
Example - 6. Risk Technology Adoption
31The Big Picture Ecology and Economics
Ecosystem Services Valuation
Our Farms Finances Profitability
Ecosystem Services What the ecosystem offers
us
Economic Policy
Ecosystem Health
Our Farm Management
Information Knowledge Education
Information Knowledge Education
Economic Health
Environmental Policy
Economic Services What the economy offers
us
Our Farms Ecosystem
Economic Services Valuation
32Outline
- 1. Decision Makers - This is Economics
- 2. Context for Making Decisions
- 3. What is Profit? How is it Calculated?
- 4. What are Externalities?
- 5. IPM Pest Control Decisions Damping off
Example - 6. Risk Technology Adoption
33Pest Control Decisions
- Partial Budget Analysis
- The Production Function Often control is not a
discrete event, but a treatment with various
levels of intensities. -
- The partial cost (C) generally increases
linearly with the intensity of control effort.
Partial revenue (R) generally increases at a
diminishing rate -
34Optimization
- Real management situations usually involve
several variables, all of which simultaneously
affect crop yield. We may also have to make
decisions at several times throughout the season.
Figure 1. Each data point in this example
represents the output from one simulation.
35 Optimization of Ecological Processes
- Management to enhance recycling of biomass,
nutrient availability, (soil aeration, cover
crops, etc..) - Provide favorable soil conditions
- Minimize energy loss
- Diversify species intraspecific genetic
diversity - Enhance beneficial biological interactions and
synergies (e.g. IPM, alley cropping)
36Damping Off
-Underground, soil line, or crown rot, especially
of seedlings, due to various causes -Covers
several soil borne diseases includes rotting
caused by Rhizoctonia, Pythium, Miscellaneous
Fungi
37Fungicides to Control Damping Off
DOSE g fung./L PLANTS Per Tray
0 10
2 41
4 65
6 83
8 92
10 98
12 100
14 97
16 90
- A greenhouse experiment showed that less
damping off of bedding plants could be achieved
with increasing doses of a fungicide drench.
38- Case 1 We grow our plants in trays, with 100
plants/tray. If we have 90-100 healthy plants per
tray, we can get a price of 10.00 per tray. If
there are fewer than 90 plants but at least 60,
the price drops to 7.00 per tray. Between 60 and
40 plants per tray, the price is 4.00, and if
there are fewer than 40 plants per tray, the
customers will not buy them, and we have to throw
the plants away. Our fungicide costs .50 per
gram, and our production costs exclusive of the
fungicide are 3.00 per tray. - Case 2 Instead of growing our plants in large
trays, we produce them in cell trays with 100
cells per tray that can be broken apart so that
the plants can be sold individually. These trays
cost .50 more per tray than the conventional
trays, and sorting out the cells in which the
plants have died adds to the labor cost,
averaging .05 for each cell that has to be
removed. However, being able to sell plants
individually adds a small premium to the price,
and we can charge .12 per plant. - The questions that we want to answer are
Should we apply the fungicide, and if so, at what
dose? Should we change to the cell trays, despite
their greater cost, and if we do, how does that
affect our fungicide decision?
39Hypothetical Example Case 2 Hypothetical Example Case 2 Hypothetical Example Case 2 Hypothetical Example Case 2 Hypothetical Example Case 2 Hypothetical Example Case 2 Hypothetical Example Case 2 Hypothetical Example Case 2
Marketable Partial Fixed Sorting Total Total
Fungicide Dose Plants Cost Cost of Tray Cost (0.05 per dead cell) Cost Revenue (0.12 per plant) Profit per Tray
(grams/ liter) per Tray () () () () () ()
0 10 0.00 3.50 4.50 8.00 1.20 -6.80
2 41 1.00 3.50 2.95 7.45 4.92 -2.53
4 65 2.00 3.50 1.75 7.25 7.80 0.55
6 83 3.00 3.50 0.85 7.35 9.96 2.61
8 92 4.00 3.50 0.40 7.90 11.04 3.14
10 98 5.00 3.50 0.10 8.60 11.76 3.16
12 100 6.00 3.50 0.00 9.50 12.00 2.50
14 97 7.00 3.50 0.15 10.65 11.64 0.99
16 90 8.00 3.50 0.50 12.00 10.80 -1.20
40How would an IPM Approach Change our Approach
Cost Benefit Analysis?
- What else prevents damping off besides
fungicides?? - Consider a systems approach - is there anything
we can do to create an environment inhospitable
to the establishment of these diseases? - Investigate biocontrol options In this case
there are some microbial fungicides that are a
possibility depending on your target disease and
system - If using fungicides, (especially the targeted
varieties like DMIs Benzimidazoles) manage
application to avoid resistance
41Many Other Options in Our Case
- Purchase disease free plants and seeds.
Consider fungicidal coatings on seeds which
will be direct sown out doors in cold soils, such
as corn and peas. - Seed borne disease can also be avoided by
soaking the seeds for 15 minutes in a bleach
solution - Use sterile well drained soil mediums. Try to
maintain a soil mix pH at the low end of the
average scale (tap water will increase pH) - Keep plant crowns above soil line dont bury
seeds too deeply - Avoid overcrowding and overfeeding (maintain
consistent growth) - Avoid taking cuttings or transplanting when the
soil is wet. - Disinfect tools and containers
- Rotate plantings on a 2 to 3 year schedule using
plants from different families in order to starve
out existing pathogens. - Provide constant air movement not tied in with
the light timer. This helps the seedlings to
aspirate, and excess soil moisture to wick.
42Outline
- 1. Decision Makers - This is Economics
- 2. Context for Making Decisions
- 3. What is Profit? How is it Calculated?
- 4. What are Externalities?
- 5. IPM Pest Control Decisions Damping off
Example - 6. Risk Technology Adoption
43Risk Technology Adoption
- So why dont all farmers move toward IPM in an
attempt to conserve ecosystem services? - They arent aware of the financial loss
- They lack the appropriate technology/management
to conserve the service - or
- Choosing a management practice that leads to
unpredictable yields presents unacceptable risk
for most farmers. These technologies often
incorporate the unpredictability of ecological
systems. - There are often economically difficult transition
periods in adopting these technologies - Many technologies, including expensive ones, are
often adopted precisely because they make yields
reliable (irrespective of long-term
sustainability).
44Risk Valuation Problems
- Unfortunately non-target effects of farm
management are rarely easy to quantify on a
local scale. - The fact that soil fertility in the US is worth
an estimated 45 billion annually is important
for macro-economic policy, but is useless in
specific land-use or pollution-permitting
decisions - Most policy decisions are incremental. Local
decision makers need to know where and by how
much ecosystem services are degraded by
development or land management
45Valuation Replacement Costs
- Using the cost to replace a given ecological
service is often the best measure to pin a dollar
value on ecosystem services. - Example NY City drinking water in the early 90s
failed EPA quality standards - Instead of
investing 6-8 billion in a treatment plant,
1-1.5 billion was spent in the restoration of
the Catskills Mountains watershed. - This investment in natural rather than physical
capital provides an excellent example of
incorporating ecosystem services into policy.
46Issues for Scientists
- How an ecosystem works is not the same as the
services it provides - Relatively few ecosystem services have been the
focus of research and monitoring information is
generally related to either the characteristics
of the ecological system or the characteristics
of the social system, not to the all-important
interactions between the two -
- This focus has even been reinforced by policy
for example, federal and state wetland mitigation
is assessed largely on the basis of the sites
physical characteristics (e.g. as measured by
vegitation) and not at all on the services it
provides to humans.
47Information Markets
- Current environmental law could actually help
resolve our inability to value ecosystem
services through the creation of information
markets. - Clean Water Act regulations and the Superfund law
(CERCLA) have established the need for
information on wetlands vegetation and
increasingly sophisticated hydrological models.
Successful ecological consulting businesses have
arisen to fill this economic niche. - Information markets could be used to generate the
appropriate knowledge of key ecosystem services.
Were data required by governmental officials in
permit and damage assessments or for agricultural
management practices then this market would
certainly arise. - The role of Scientists in developing and
changing environmental law should not be
underestimated
48Some Conclusions Role for IPM
- Realistically growers are motivated by personal,
local goals, especially profit rather than
large-scale sustainability goals. - To get farmers to use IPM the uncertainty
must be turned into measurable and
manageable risk. - It must be cost effective
- The public policy environment must be one
that encourages integrated technologies - Technology adoption in agriculture is very
word-of-mouth and community based -