Title: LUISS Master in European Studies 200809 European Macroeconomics 4
1LUISSMaster in European Studies
2008-09European Macroeconomics4
- Francesco Farina
- University of Siena
2FISCAL POLICY Public deficit / GDP and public
debt / GDP
3In the EMU, after a 2 fall in GDP automatic
stabilizers create a 1 deficit but the GDP
recovery is only 0,5. They can only absorb a
shock by a quarter. Higher absorption only in UK
and two Scandinavian countries (non cyclically
correlated with EMU ).
4(No Transcript)
5(No Transcript)
6FIG. 9.1 sums up the European Commission (EC)
critiques to European governments In the two
decades that preceded the monetary union, fiscal
policy was characterized by1) a falling deficit
ratio with a negative output gap, whereas it
increases with positive output gaps (1976-81 and
1989-91). 2) a constantly growing average debt to
GDP ratio since the start of EMS. In the EC
judgement, the high P.Def./GDP ratios caused the
high P.Debt / GDP ratios.
7- The EC has blamed governments for not having set
aside additional fiscal revenues stemming from
expansionary business cycles, in order to prevent
the progressive accumulation of debt during the
subsequent downwards. - The IPBC implies that governments should control
the overall public deficit (the primary deficit
plus interest payments). Yet, only the first
component is under direct control of governments.
In fact, interest rates are determined by
monetary policy and international financial
markets, and represent an exogenous impact on
public finances.
8- The deficit/GDP ratio rises as an effect of both
deficit components, and the debt ratio is also
affected by the issue of new bonds to cover the
secondary component of the deficit (the spending
on interest payments on outstanding debt) and by
the growth dynamics (a fast income growth brings
down the deficit and debt ratios). - All in all, since the beginning of the 90s
until 1995, the rise in debt does not seem to be
due to a less rigorous management of fiscal
policy, but rather to bad economic conditions.
9- Sluggish growth and the recession of the early
nineties induced many governments to follow an
active fiscal policy, and give some
discretionary boosts to the economy. This caused
public deficits (and debt) to grow. - Moreover, the expansion of public spending in
the EMS can be in part interpreted in this way
fiscal policy substituted a monetary policy
that was rather restrictive.
10- The next figure displays the overall situation
of taxation and public spending between the years
1993 and 2000. The 45 degree line separates the
area in two above the line, the primary
structural deficit increases below the line it
falls. The downward sloping line shows the
contribution of spending and taxes to the
deficit. Below the line, a rising primary surplus
is mainly due to spending cuts above the line,
higher taxation improves the deficit ratio. These
data confirm the success of fiscal consolidation
for the average of all EMU countries.
11By how much did governments reduce the structural
fiscal deficit/GDP ratios in 1993-2000?Were
restrictive fiscal impulses obtained by exp.
cuts or tax increases?
12- Questions Upward diagonal Does the
discretionary fiscal intervention by governments
increase or reduce the primary structural
deficit? Downward diagonal Does the fiscal
impulse mainly consist in higher T or lower p.
exp.? - ANSWERS
- All countries, except Greece and Portugal, saw
the primary structural balance improve. - A majority of countries below the downward
diagonal. Five countries Belgium, Italy,
Finland, the Netherlands and Spain have cut
spending more than they reduced taxation. - Ireland is an outlyer.
13Fiscal policy automatic stabilizers fiscal
impulses
- Governments conduct discretionary fiscal
expansions in order to sustain output. To measure
these fiscal impulses, we cancel out the output
increase (Yt Yt-1) due to the reaction to the
business cycle due to the operation of the
automatic stabilizers. - TAB. 9.3 shows how periods of fiscal restriction
and expansion have alternated. - Yet, a non-balanced budget could force a
government to a fiscal restraint during a
downward, by cutting the operation of automatic
stabilizers.
14 15- Deficit and debt ratios rise when fiscal policy
sustains output in the years after the 1991-93
crises. In contrast, they fall in the years
before the admission to the eurozone when
macroeconomic stabilization was put aside for
consolidating debt instead. - In order to ensure participation in the EMU, most
governments had to follow highly restrictive
policies. The 2001 recession shows that after EMU
entry, both ratios start to rise again. Why?
Consolidation fatigue or the Twin Towers
negative shock?
16- During recessions output stabilization (let
automatic stabilizers to freely operate despite
the high structural deficits) or debt
decumulation (by conducting pro-cyclical f.p.)? - In many countries, the strong slowdown of demand
is responsible for slow economic growth. - In the three major European economies, the
deficit ratio increased in this way above the 3
limit. - Public debt in some countries (Italy, Belgium and
Greece) is still near or above 100 of GDP.
17- g 5 3 / 60 (the percentages imposed on
fiscal policy by Maastricht Treaty are a 3
deficit /GDP ratio - (G-T)/Y iB/Y - and a b
constant at 60). So the two fiscal constraints
(3 and 60) are compatible with a growth of
nominal income equal to 5. In 1991, nominal
economic growth in Germany was equal to 5 (2,5
in real terms). The current growth rate of
nominal income in the EMU has fallen by about
40, however. It now is more or less 3.
18- The fall in average growth reported in Europe
casts some doubts on the consistency of the 3
constraint. If we follow the reasoning of the RBC
model, the loss of one percentage point in
average labour productivity growth in the EU
(from 2,3 between 1975-90 to 1,3 in the
nineties) is not due to cyclical factors but is
due to a structural fall of economic growth from
2,5 to 1,5. On average, real economic growth is
only 1,4 per year, and varies for Continental
Europe in a range from 0,5 to 2. - With g3, a correction of the public deficit /
GDP limit from 3 to 1,8 would be necessary.
19(No Transcript)
20- THE STABILITY AND GROWTH PACT
- The SGP introduces a system of fiscal
discipline that is certainly more advanced
compared to the Maastricht Treaty. By prohibiting
the money financing of public deficits, Art. 194
of the TEU and Art. 21.1 of the ECB Statute left
to national fiscal authorities the responsibility
of fiscal policy. The TEU claims that a balanced
fiscal position is a necessary condition for the
good functioning of a monetary union. If the
budget deficit tends towards the 3 limit, a
procedure is started that, in case of a breach of
the rules of the SGP ends with a penalty.
21- The articles of the Pact allow for deficits
higher than 3 under three particular conditions.
The deficit should be - 1. exceptional the reason for the breach has to
be a serious recession, defined as a sudden fall
of real output equal at least to -0,75 - 2. transitory the deficit returns within the 3
limits after one year - 3. close the deficit ratio should not move to
far away from 3. -
-
22- The New SGP (2005)
- 1. The close to balance or in surplus rule
imposes the obligation to reach the normal
fiscal position of balance in the medium term.
When a shock occurs, a country will be able to
exploit the budgetary room for letting automatic
stabilizers work up to the 3 limit. In order to
keep budgets anchored to balance in the medium
term, member countries should give up using
discretionary stabilization policies. - 2. the appropriate method for assessing the
fiscal position of a country is the public budget
balance corrected for the cycle (structural
budget balance)
23- 3. the new SGP revised in March 2005,
introduced some changes to make the SGP
constraints less stringent. More discretion is
allowed in the evaluation of the three conditions
for an excessive deficit. A) exceptional
conditions can not only be interpreted in terms
of negative growth, but also of prolonged slow
growth below potential. B) a low debt to GDP
ratio raises the deficit limit to 3,5. A higher
deficit may be tolerated for two consecutive
years. Some spending items (e.g. investment exp.)
that promote economic growth may be deducted from
the calculation.
24- The EC has a monitoring role on deficit and debt
ratios but also the power to propose to sanction
a EMU country for excessive deficit. - Yet, the power division between European
Commission and Ecofin on the implementation of
sanctions shows a precarious compromise between
political choice and economic constraints. This
is a weakness of the enforcement mechanism, which
reduces the credibility of the SGP in financial
markets. Political power matters. When France and
Germany were in the same conditions in 2003 that
caused to Portugal a pecuniary (unenforced)
sanction in 2002, the proposal of the EC was not
approved.
25- The theoretical explanation for the SGP
- High deficits would disrupt the capacity of the
ECB to control the interest rate in the eurozone. - The ECB may grant credit to a country in
difficulty. If a government is obliged to
refinance its own debt at increasingly high rates
and there are doubts regarding its fiscal
solvency, the ECB is by its Statute not allowed
to save the government (no-bail-out clause). A
weak instrument, as the ECB could anyway finance
the indisciplined government in the secondary
market.
26- A fiscal expansion in one or more countries of
the EMU would raise the interest rate for the
currency zone as a whole. In fact, large issues
of government bonds would boost the demand for
liquidity and thus generate upward tensions on
the interest rate in European financial markets. - This argument has been downplayed. First,
econometric studies do not find large effects of
higher deficits (a 1 increase in the deficit of
a European country of average dimension has an
impact on interest rates of around 10 basis
points). -
27- Second, a government in difficulty would pay a
default premium on the issued bonds, especially
if this country has a high public debt. - Yet, due to the higher interdependence between
capital markets, in a period of excess demand for
liquidity, the euro interest rate could raise
very much. - Hence, with increasing interest rates,
governments that resort too much to EMU financial
markets might cause a negative externality on the
eurozone interest rate.
28- Financial market would start to expect the
monetization of public debt by the ECB. As a
consequence, financial agents would reduce their
positions in euro. - Another controversial aspect of the SGP is its
limited focus on the public deficit. Sanctions
apply only if the deficit ratio passes 3. There
are no additional restrictions on countries whose
debt to GDP ratio is higher than 60. - In order to stabilize the debt to GDP ratio,
the overall deficit ratio should not be larger
than the product of economic growth and the debt
to GDP ratio.
29- In a monetary union, domestic inflation and
output are not only determined by domestic
factors but also by economic activity in the
other countries of the eurozone via two
transmission channels - 1. trade interdependence a change in the level
of output and inflation in one country produces a
multiplier effect in other countries via trade
flows - 2. financial interdependence a change in output,
inflation and fiscal policy in one country
affects output, inflation and fiscal policy in
all other countries through the effect on the
average interest and inflation rates of the
monetary union, and on the euro exchange rate.
30- The NKE inclines to think of a positive income
multiplier (provided that there is unemployment
in a flexible L mkt). The RBC models support
non-Keynesian effects of macroeconomic
stabilization policies. - The SGP is in line with the NCE. The modest
positive effect of public spending in deficit via
the trade channel is fully compensated by the
crowding out of aggregate demand via the
financial channel. Still, the extreme position of
RBC theory that an expansionary fiscal impulse
has a negative impact on income is refuted.
31- According to the Tax Smoothing principle, using
automatic stabilizers is sufficient to make
fiscal stabilization policy effective. Then, the
SGP rationale is that giving up discretionary
policy manoeuvres has no effects. - In case of a supply shock, inflation and income
move in opposite directions. It is more probable
that coordination makes the two authorities
behave like substitutes when monetary policy is
restrictive (expansionary), fiscal policy is
expansionary (restrictive). In contrast, after a
demand shock, both inflation and output move in
the same direction. Both policies are likely to
be complements.
32- Besides, stabilization by the two authorities
depends on the domestic macroeconomic conditions
(e.g., the degree of flexibility of L mkt, the
intra EMU inflation differentials, etc.). - By imposing the SGP, the European Commission
endorses the Tax Smoothing principle. NKE models
do not adopt the Ricardian Equivalence
hypothesis as consumers face liquidity
constraints. Simulations with dynamic versions of
the NKE model confirm that discretionary fiscal
policy increase inflation but also reduce the
volatility of output.
33- In order not to violate the SGP, during the
first years of the new millennium Germany, France
and Italy should have adopted a pro-cyclical
budget and cut short the work of automatic
stabilizers. - This would have created an additional primary
surplus and avoided breaching the 3 limit. - The difficulty in respecting this constraint
increases when international interest rates are
rising. - If the ECB raises the interest rate the public
balances of EMU countries are burdened by
additional interest payments. In a recession, a
breach of the 3 barrier will only be avoided by
sterilizing the automatic stabilizers. - This affects mainly those countries with a high
stock of public debt.
34- A fiscal constraint determined also by the debt
ratio? - Lets link the deficit constraint (already
reached by all countries, although some violated
it recently) to a debt constraint (still far from
being fulfilled in some countries) d 0,03 x
(b 0,6), where x can for example be equal to
0,10. - A country with a high debt ratio (bgt60)
should respect a stricter limit on the deficit
than the 3 rule e.g. b80 d 0,01. In
contrast, a virtuous country, thanks to its
better fiscal solvency, could run higher
deficits e.g. b40 d 0,05.
35- Has the SGP been deflationary during the EMU?
- The SGP seems not to have affected economic
stabilization discretionary fiscal policy less
pro-cyclical in the post-Maastricht era (lower
coefficient of the OG after 1992). - The coefficient has reduced as during
expansionary business cycles fiscal surpluses
have been devoted to public debt reduction, and
during recessions, in order to avoid a dramatic
fiscal restriction, many governments have reduced
the sensitivity of automatic stabilizers to the
output gap.
36- Why did public deficit/GDP and debts/GDP
increase at the EMU inception? - 1. In 1999 and 2000, the economic boom might
have been an opportunity to reduce public debt
and/or put aside the additional tax revenues for
future bad years. This opportunity was not
seized, as governments resorted to discretionary
policies in addition to the automatic
stabilizers, thus eroding primary surpluses.
37- The origin of the worsening primary structural
deficit is due to the adoption of a neutral
fiscal policy (i.e., no Tax Smoothing). It is
true than in 2002, due to the increase of public
spending aimed at stabilising the negative demand
shock produced by the Twin Towers attacks, the
primary structural deficit ratio decreased in the
eurozone only by 0,3. But it is likely that the
main impulse behind the increase in the deficit
ratio came from slow economic growth in the
presence of high interest rates.
38Fiscal policy at the inception of the Eurozone
39- After the excessive rise in 1999-2000, too
modest interest rate cuts by the ECB. - The left graph would seem to confirm, at first
glance, the thesis of the European Commission no
Tax Smoothing, as governments left public debt to
grow. Yet, the right graph shows how in both
recession periods following an increase in
interest rates - debt dynamics resumed. - EMU 2000-04 due to the recession, to curb
rising deficit and debt ratios is difficult. - First, the slow growth of output pushed up the
total deficit/GDP ratio. Second, the
consolidation of public debt entered into a
conflict with output stabilization.
40- The progressively falling surplus at the start
of the millennium suggests that stabilization has
not been sacrificed for consolidation. This might
have produced a further increase in the debt
ratio in some countries (a typical example is
Italy). - An alternative interpretation to the theses of
a more anti-cyclical discretionary policy in
the after-Maastricht period and of consolidation
fatigue. We already saw that it is doubtful
that a) the Maastricht constraints and the SGP
represented an obstacle for the implementation of
a stabilizing fiscal policy, and b) consolidation
efforts diminished.
41- Results of the empirical analysis carried out
for the pre-Maastricht, pre-EMU and EMU period
show that the lower pro-cyclicality since
Maastricht comes from a minor effort to stabilize
when the output gap is positive. - It is also the consequence of using fiscal
resources for the consolidation of the debt with
the aim to comply with the 3 and 60 limits. - After the Twin Tower shock and the fall in
aggregate demand, the trade-off between
stabilization and consolidation has caused a fast
deterioration in the deficit/GDP ratio.
42- To abide by Tax Smoothing, countries renounced
to economic stabilization and pursued restrictive
fiscal policies that turned off the impact of
automatic stabilizers. - The high debt countries financed high
secondary deficits with new debt issues, so that
debt consolidation came to a halt . The
consolidation fatigue is not just the effect of
reneging on the SGP, but reflects a trade-off
between further consolidating debt and
stabilizing income in a recession. - The social cost of increasing tax pressure, or a
further cut in social spending items (health and
pensions), might be very high.
43- The paradox of national fiscal policies is that
EMU governments have at the same time to account
for their actions to European institutions
(Commission and Ecofin) and stand up to the
judgment of citizens. From a social choice point
of view, this seems rather hard. Governments give
in to stiff opposition against welfare reform and
a reduction in social spending, and consequently
choose to break the fiscal rules. They would
rather run the risk of incurring in the sanctions
of the Commission and the Ecofin in case of a
violation of the SGP.