LUISS Master in European Studies 200809 European Macroeconomics 4 - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

1 / 43
About This Presentation
Title:

LUISS Master in European Studies 200809 European Macroeconomics 4

Description:

In the EMU, after a 2% fall in GDP automatic stabilizers create a 1% deficit but ... that an expansionary fiscal impulse has a negative impact on income is refuted. ... – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:47
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 44
Provided by: francesc65
Category:

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: LUISS Master in European Studies 200809 European Macroeconomics 4


1
LUISSMaster in European Studies
2008-09European Macroeconomics4
  • Francesco Farina
  • University of Siena

2
FISCAL POLICY Public deficit / GDP and public
debt / GDP
3
In the EMU, after a 2 fall in GDP automatic
stabilizers create a 1 deficit but the GDP
recovery is only 0,5. They can only absorb a
shock by a quarter. Higher absorption only in UK
and two Scandinavian countries (non cyclically
correlated with EMU ).
4
(No Transcript)
5
(No Transcript)
6
FIG. 9.1 sums up the European Commission (EC)
critiques to European governments In the two
decades that preceded the monetary union, fiscal
policy was characterized by1) a falling deficit
ratio with a negative output gap, whereas it
increases with positive output gaps (1976-81 and
1989-91). 2) a constantly growing average debt to
GDP ratio since the start of EMS. In the EC
judgement, the high P.Def./GDP ratios caused the
high P.Debt / GDP ratios.
7
  • The EC has blamed governments for not having set
    aside additional fiscal revenues stemming from
    expansionary business cycles, in order to prevent
    the progressive accumulation of debt during the
    subsequent downwards.
  • The IPBC implies that governments should control
    the overall public deficit (the primary deficit
    plus interest payments). Yet, only the first
    component is under direct control of governments.
    In fact, interest rates are determined by
    monetary policy and international financial
    markets, and represent an exogenous impact on
    public finances.

8
  • The deficit/GDP ratio rises as an effect of both
    deficit components, and the debt ratio is also
    affected by the issue of new bonds to cover the
    secondary component of the deficit (the spending
    on interest payments on outstanding debt) and by
    the growth dynamics (a fast income growth brings
    down the deficit and debt ratios).
  • All in all, since the beginning of the 90s
    until 1995, the rise in debt does not seem to be
    due to a less rigorous management of fiscal
    policy, but rather to bad economic conditions.

9
  • Sluggish growth and the recession of the early
    nineties induced many governments to follow an
    active fiscal policy, and give some
    discretionary boosts to the economy. This caused
    public deficits (and debt) to grow.
  • Moreover, the expansion of public spending in
    the EMS can be in part interpreted in this way
    fiscal policy substituted a monetary policy
    that was rather restrictive.

10
  • The next figure displays the overall situation
    of taxation and public spending between the years
    1993 and 2000. The 45 degree line separates the
    area in two above the line, the primary
    structural deficit increases below the line it
    falls. The downward sloping line shows the
    contribution of spending and taxes to the
    deficit. Below the line, a rising primary surplus
    is mainly due to spending cuts above the line,
    higher taxation improves the deficit ratio. These
    data confirm the success of fiscal consolidation
    for the average of all EMU countries.

11
By how much did governments reduce the structural
fiscal deficit/GDP ratios in 1993-2000?Were
restrictive fiscal impulses obtained by exp.
cuts or tax increases?
12
  • Questions Upward diagonal Does the
    discretionary fiscal intervention by governments
    increase or reduce the primary structural
    deficit? Downward diagonal Does the fiscal
    impulse mainly consist in higher T or lower p.
    exp.?
  • ANSWERS
  • All countries, except Greece and Portugal, saw
    the primary structural balance improve.
  • A majority of countries below the downward
    diagonal. Five countries Belgium, Italy,
    Finland, the Netherlands and Spain have cut
    spending more than they reduced taxation.
  • Ireland is an outlyer.

13
Fiscal policy automatic stabilizers fiscal
impulses
  • Governments conduct discretionary fiscal
    expansions in order to sustain output. To measure
    these fiscal impulses, we cancel out the output
    increase (Yt Yt-1) due to the reaction to the
    business cycle due to the operation of the
    automatic stabilizers.
  • TAB. 9.3 shows how periods of fiscal restriction
    and expansion have alternated.
  • Yet, a non-balanced budget could force a
    government to a fiscal restraint during a
    downward, by cutting the operation of automatic
    stabilizers.

14

15
  • Deficit and debt ratios rise when fiscal policy
    sustains output in the years after the 1991-93
    crises. In contrast, they fall in the years
    before the admission to the eurozone when
    macroeconomic stabilization was put aside for
    consolidating debt instead.
  • In order to ensure participation in the EMU, most
    governments had to follow highly restrictive
    policies. The 2001 recession shows that after EMU
    entry, both ratios start to rise again. Why?
    Consolidation fatigue or the Twin Towers
    negative shock?

16
  • During recessions output stabilization (let
    automatic stabilizers to freely operate despite
    the high structural deficits) or debt
    decumulation (by conducting pro-cyclical f.p.)?
  • In many countries, the strong slowdown of demand
    is responsible for slow economic growth.
  • In the three major European economies, the
    deficit ratio increased in this way above the 3
    limit.
  • Public debt in some countries (Italy, Belgium and
    Greece) is still near or above 100 of GDP.

17
  • g 5 3 / 60 (the percentages imposed on
    fiscal policy by Maastricht Treaty are a 3
    deficit /GDP ratio - (G-T)/Y iB/Y - and a b
    constant at 60). So the two fiscal constraints
    (3 and 60) are compatible with a growth of
    nominal income equal to 5. In 1991, nominal
    economic growth in Germany was equal to 5 (2,5
    in real terms). The current growth rate of
    nominal income in the EMU has fallen by about
    40, however. It now is more or less 3.

18
  • The fall in average growth reported in Europe
    casts some doubts on the consistency of the 3
    constraint. If we follow the reasoning of the RBC
    model, the loss of one percentage point in
    average labour productivity growth in the EU
    (from 2,3 between 1975-90 to 1,3 in the
    nineties) is not due to cyclical factors but is
    due to a structural fall of economic growth from
    2,5 to 1,5. On average, real economic growth is
    only 1,4 per year, and varies for Continental
    Europe in a range from 0,5 to 2.
  • With g3, a correction of the public deficit /
    GDP limit from 3 to 1,8 would be necessary.

19
(No Transcript)
20
  • THE STABILITY AND GROWTH PACT
  • The SGP introduces a system of fiscal
    discipline that is certainly more advanced
    compared to the Maastricht Treaty. By prohibiting
    the money financing of public deficits, Art. 194
    of the TEU and Art. 21.1 of the ECB Statute left
    to national fiscal authorities the responsibility
    of fiscal policy. The TEU claims that a balanced
    fiscal position is a necessary condition for the
    good functioning of a monetary union. If the
    budget deficit tends towards the 3 limit, a
    procedure is started that, in case of a breach of
    the rules of the SGP ends with a penalty.

21
  • The articles of the Pact allow for deficits
    higher than 3 under three particular conditions.
    The deficit should be
  • 1. exceptional the reason for the breach has to
    be a serious recession, defined as a sudden fall
    of real output equal at least to -0,75
  • 2. transitory the deficit returns within the 3
    limits after one year
  • 3. close the deficit ratio should not move to
    far away from 3.

22
  • The New SGP (2005)
  • 1. The close to balance or in surplus rule
    imposes the obligation to reach the normal
    fiscal position of balance in the medium term.
    When a shock occurs, a country will be able to
    exploit the budgetary room for letting automatic
    stabilizers work up to the 3 limit. In order to
    keep budgets anchored to balance in the medium
    term, member countries should give up using
    discretionary stabilization policies.
  • 2. the appropriate method for assessing the
    fiscal position of a country is the public budget
    balance corrected for the cycle (structural
    budget balance)

23
  • 3. the new SGP revised in March 2005,
    introduced some changes to make the SGP
    constraints less stringent. More discretion is
    allowed in the evaluation of the three conditions
    for an excessive deficit. A) exceptional
    conditions can not only be interpreted in terms
    of negative growth, but also of prolonged slow
    growth below potential. B) a low debt to GDP
    ratio raises the deficit limit to 3,5. A higher
    deficit may be tolerated for two consecutive
    years. Some spending items (e.g. investment exp.)
    that promote economic growth may be deducted from
    the calculation.

24
  • The EC has a monitoring role on deficit and debt
    ratios but also the power to propose to sanction
    a EMU country for excessive deficit.
  • Yet, the power division between European
    Commission and Ecofin on the implementation of
    sanctions shows a precarious compromise between
    political choice and economic constraints. This
    is a weakness of the enforcement mechanism, which
    reduces the credibility of the SGP in financial
    markets. Political power matters. When France and
    Germany were in the same conditions in 2003 that
    caused to Portugal a pecuniary (unenforced)
    sanction in 2002, the proposal of the EC was not
    approved.

25
  • The theoretical explanation for the SGP
  • High deficits would disrupt the capacity of the
    ECB to control the interest rate in the eurozone.
  • The ECB may grant credit to a country in
    difficulty. If a government is obliged to
    refinance its own debt at increasingly high rates
    and there are doubts regarding its fiscal
    solvency, the ECB is by its Statute not allowed
    to save the government (no-bail-out clause). A
    weak instrument, as the ECB could anyway finance
    the indisciplined government in the secondary
    market.

26
  • A fiscal expansion in one or more countries of
    the EMU would raise the interest rate for the
    currency zone as a whole. In fact, large issues
    of government bonds would boost the demand for
    liquidity and thus generate upward tensions on
    the interest rate in European financial markets.
  • This argument has been downplayed. First,
    econometric studies do not find large effects of
    higher deficits (a 1 increase in the deficit of
    a European country of average dimension has an
    impact on interest rates of around 10 basis
    points).

27
  • Second, a government in difficulty would pay a
    default premium on the issued bonds, especially
    if this country has a high public debt.
  • Yet, due to the higher interdependence between
    capital markets, in a period of excess demand for
    liquidity, the euro interest rate could raise
    very much.
  • Hence, with increasing interest rates,
    governments that resort too much to EMU financial
    markets might cause a negative externality on the
    eurozone interest rate.

28
  • Financial market would start to expect the
    monetization of public debt by the ECB. As a
    consequence, financial agents would reduce their
    positions in euro.
  • Another controversial aspect of the SGP is its
    limited focus on the public deficit. Sanctions
    apply only if the deficit ratio passes 3. There
    are no additional restrictions on countries whose
    debt to GDP ratio is higher than 60.
  • In order to stabilize the debt to GDP ratio,
    the overall deficit ratio should not be larger
    than the product of economic growth and the debt
    to GDP ratio.

29
  • In a monetary union, domestic inflation and
    output are not only determined by domestic
    factors but also by economic activity in the
    other countries of the eurozone via two
    transmission channels
  • 1. trade interdependence a change in the level
    of output and inflation in one country produces a
    multiplier effect in other countries via trade
    flows
  • 2. financial interdependence a change in output,
    inflation and fiscal policy in one country
    affects output, inflation and fiscal policy in
    all other countries through the effect on the
    average interest and inflation rates of the
    monetary union, and on the euro exchange rate.

30
  • The NKE inclines to think of a positive income
    multiplier (provided that there is unemployment
    in a flexible L mkt). The RBC models support
    non-Keynesian effects of macroeconomic
    stabilization policies.
  • The SGP is in line with the NCE. The modest
    positive effect of public spending in deficit via
    the trade channel is fully compensated by the
    crowding out of aggregate demand via the
    financial channel. Still, the extreme position of
    RBC theory that an expansionary fiscal impulse
    has a negative impact on income is refuted.

31
  • According to the Tax Smoothing principle, using
    automatic stabilizers is sufficient to make
    fiscal stabilization policy effective. Then, the
    SGP rationale is that giving up discretionary
    policy manoeuvres has no effects.
  • In case of a supply shock, inflation and income
    move in opposite directions. It is more probable
    that coordination makes the two authorities
    behave like substitutes when monetary policy is
    restrictive (expansionary), fiscal policy is
    expansionary (restrictive). In contrast, after a
    demand shock, both inflation and output move in
    the same direction. Both policies are likely to
    be complements.

32
  • Besides, stabilization by the two authorities
    depends on the domestic macroeconomic conditions
    (e.g., the degree of flexibility of L mkt, the
    intra EMU inflation differentials, etc.).
  • By imposing the SGP, the European Commission
    endorses the Tax Smoothing principle. NKE models
    do not adopt the Ricardian Equivalence
    hypothesis as consumers face liquidity
    constraints. Simulations with dynamic versions of
    the NKE model confirm that discretionary fiscal
    policy increase inflation but also reduce the
    volatility of output.

33
  • In order not to violate the SGP, during the
    first years of the new millennium Germany, France
    and Italy should have adopted a pro-cyclical
    budget and cut short the work of automatic
    stabilizers.
  • This would have created an additional primary
    surplus and avoided breaching the 3 limit.
  • The difficulty in respecting this constraint
    increases when international interest rates are
    rising.
  • If the ECB raises the interest rate the public
    balances of EMU countries are burdened by
    additional interest payments. In a recession, a
    breach of the 3 barrier will only be avoided by
    sterilizing the automatic stabilizers.
  • This affects mainly those countries with a high
    stock of public debt.

34
  • A fiscal constraint determined also by the debt
    ratio?
  • Lets link the deficit constraint (already
    reached by all countries, although some violated
    it recently) to a debt constraint (still far from
    being fulfilled in some countries) d 0,03 x
    (b 0,6), where x can for example be equal to
    0,10.
  • A country with a high debt ratio (bgt60)
    should respect a stricter limit on the deficit
    than the 3 rule e.g. b80 d 0,01. In
    contrast, a virtuous country, thanks to its
    better fiscal solvency, could run higher
    deficits e.g. b40 d 0,05.

35
  • Has the SGP been deflationary during the EMU?
  • The SGP seems not to have affected economic
    stabilization discretionary fiscal policy less
    pro-cyclical in the post-Maastricht era (lower
    coefficient of the OG after 1992).
  • The coefficient has reduced as during
    expansionary business cycles fiscal surpluses
    have been devoted to public debt reduction, and
    during recessions, in order to avoid a dramatic
    fiscal restriction, many governments have reduced
    the sensitivity of automatic stabilizers to the
    output gap.

36
  • Why did public deficit/GDP and debts/GDP
    increase at the EMU inception?
  • 1. In 1999 and 2000, the economic boom might
    have been an opportunity to reduce public debt
    and/or put aside the additional tax revenues for
    future bad years. This opportunity was not
    seized, as governments resorted to discretionary
    policies in addition to the automatic
    stabilizers, thus eroding primary surpluses.

37
  • The origin of the worsening primary structural
    deficit is due to the adoption of a neutral
    fiscal policy (i.e., no Tax Smoothing). It is
    true than in 2002, due to the increase of public
    spending aimed at stabilising the negative demand
    shock produced by the Twin Towers attacks, the
    primary structural deficit ratio decreased in the
    eurozone only by 0,3. But it is likely that the
    main impulse behind the increase in the deficit
    ratio came from slow economic growth in the
    presence of high interest rates.

38
Fiscal policy at the inception of the Eurozone
39
  • After the excessive rise in 1999-2000, too
    modest interest rate cuts by the ECB.
  • The left graph would seem to confirm, at first
    glance, the thesis of the European Commission no
    Tax Smoothing, as governments left public debt to
    grow. Yet, the right graph shows how in both
    recession periods following an increase in
    interest rates - debt dynamics resumed.
  • EMU 2000-04 due to the recession, to curb
    rising deficit and debt ratios is difficult.
  • First, the slow growth of output pushed up the
    total deficit/GDP ratio. Second, the
    consolidation of public debt entered into a
    conflict with output stabilization.

40
  • The progressively falling surplus at the start
    of the millennium suggests that stabilization has
    not been sacrificed for consolidation. This might
    have produced a further increase in the debt
    ratio in some countries (a typical example is
    Italy).
  • An alternative interpretation to the theses of
    a more anti-cyclical discretionary policy in
    the after-Maastricht period and of consolidation
    fatigue. We already saw that it is doubtful
    that a) the Maastricht constraints and the SGP
    represented an obstacle for the implementation of
    a stabilizing fiscal policy, and b) consolidation
    efforts diminished.

41
  • Results of the empirical analysis carried out
    for the pre-Maastricht, pre-EMU and EMU period
    show that the lower pro-cyclicality since
    Maastricht comes from a minor effort to stabilize
    when the output gap is positive.
  • It is also the consequence of using fiscal
    resources for the consolidation of the debt with
    the aim to comply with the 3 and 60 limits.
  • After the Twin Tower shock and the fall in
    aggregate demand, the trade-off between
    stabilization and consolidation has caused a fast
    deterioration in the deficit/GDP ratio.

42
  • To abide by Tax Smoothing, countries renounced
    to economic stabilization and pursued restrictive
    fiscal policies that turned off the impact of
    automatic stabilizers.
  • The high debt countries financed high
    secondary deficits with new debt issues, so that
    debt consolidation came to a halt . The
    consolidation fatigue is not just the effect of
    reneging on the SGP, but reflects a trade-off
    between further consolidating debt and
    stabilizing income in a recession.
  • The social cost of increasing tax pressure, or a
    further cut in social spending items (health and
    pensions), might be very high.

43
  • The paradox of national fiscal policies is that
    EMU governments have at the same time to account
    for their actions to European institutions
    (Commission and Ecofin) and stand up to the
    judgment of citizens. From a social choice point
    of view, this seems rather hard. Governments give
    in to stiff opposition against welfare reform and
    a reduction in social spending, and consequently
    choose to break the fiscal rules. They would
    rather run the risk of incurring in the sanctions
    of the Commission and the Ecofin in case of a
    violation of the SGP.
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)
About PowerShow.com