Title: Designing Large Value Payment Systems: An Agent-based approach
1Designing Large Value Payment Systems An
Agent-based approach
- Amadeo Alentorn CCFEA, University of Essex
- Sheri Markose Economics/CCFEA, University of
Essex - Stephen Millard Bank of England
- Jing Yang Bank of England
2Roadmap
- Payment system 101
- The Interbank Payment and Settlement Simulator
(IPSS) - Demonstration Experiment results
- Conclusions
3Payment system 101
4Payment System DNS vs RTGS
Liquidity
DNS 0
RTGS 40
Bank D
5LVPS design issues
- Two polar extremes
- Deferred Net Settlement (DNS)
- Real Time Gross Settlement (RTGS)
Liquidity Delay
DNS Low High
RTGS High Low
Hybrids
6Risk-efficiency trade off (I)
- RTGS avoids the situation where the failure of
one bank may cause the failure of others due to
the exposures accumulated throughout a day - However, this reduction of settlement risk comes
at a cost of an increased intraday liquidity
needed to smooth the non-synchronized payment
flows.
7Risk-efficiency trade off (II)
- Free Riding Problem
- Nash equilibrium à la Prisoner's Dilemma, where
non-cooperation is the dominant strategy - If liquidity is costly, but there are no delay
costs, it is optimal at the individual bank level
to delay until the end of the day. - Free riding implies that no bank voluntarily
post liquidity and one waits for incoming
payments. All banks may only make payments with
high priority costs. - So hidden queues and gridlock occur, which can
compromise the integrity of RTGS settlement
capabilities.
8UK payment system CHAPS
- 13 direct members, and other banks have indirect
access to CHAPS through correspondent
relationship. - Payments through the system average about ?175 bn
per day (175 of UK annual GDP). - CHAPS is a Real time gross settlement system
(RTGS). - Each direct member has an account at the BoE.
-
- Bank A ? ?X amount to Bank B Bank A
instruct the BoE to transfer ?X to bank Bs
account.
9Liquidity
- A bank may obtain liquidity needed to make
payments in two ways. - 1). Obtain liquidity directly by posting
collateral with the Bank. - 2). Obtain liquidity by receiving a payment from
another bank. - Total amount of liquidity in the system is
determined by the amount of collateral the member
banks post with the BoE.
10What are the design issues in a Large Value
Payment Systems (LVPS)?
- Three objectives
- Reduction of settlement risk
- Improving efficiency of liquidity usage
- Improving settlement speed (operational risk)
11What are agent-based simulations?
- Using a model to replicate alternative realities
- Agent-based simulations allow us to model these
characteristics - Heterogeneity
- Strategies rule of thumb or optimisation
- Adaptive learning
12- The Interbank Payment and Settlement Simulator
(IPSS) -
13What can IPSS do?1. Payments data and statistics
- Each payment has
- time of Request tR
- time of Execution tE
- Payment arrival at the banks can be
- Equal to tE from CHAPS data files (Chaps Real)
- IID Payments arrival arrival time is random
subject to being earlier than tE. (CHAPS IID
Real) - Stochastic arrival time (Proxied Data)
14Upperbound Lowerbound liquidity
- Upper bound (UB) amount of liquidity that banks
have to post on a just in time basis so that all
payment requests are settled without delay. Note
that the UB is not know ex-ante. - Lower bound (LB) amount of liquidity that a
payment system needs in order to settle all
payments at the end of the day under DNS. It is
calculated using a multilateral netting algorithm.
15What can IPSS do?2. Interbank structure
- Heterogeneous banks in terms of their size of
payments and market share - -tiering N1
- -impact of participation structure on risks.
16Herfindahl Index
- measures the concentration of payment activity
- In general, the Herfindahl Index will lie between
0.5 and 1/n, where n is the number of banks. - It will equal 1/n when payment activity is
equally divided between the n banks.
17Herfindahl Index and Asymmetry
Bilateral DNS Lower Bound (Multilateral DNS) Upper Bound
Equal Size Banks (Proxied Data ) Herfindhal Index 1/14 0.071 0 0 2.4 bn
Chaps Data Herfindhal Index 0.2 19.6 bn 5.6 bn 22.2 bn
Note that total value of payments is the same in
all scenarios
18 Liquidity posting
- Two ways of posting liquidity in RTGS
- Just in Time (JIT) raise liquidity whenever
needed paying a fee to a central bank, like in
FedWire US - Open Liquidity (OL) obtain liquidity at the
beginning of the day by posting collateral, like
in CHAPS UK - A good payment system should encourage
participants to efficiently recycle the liquidity
in the system.
19Open Liquidity
- Banks start the day by posting all liquidity
upfront to the central bank. The factor a applied
exogenously gives liquidity ranging from LB to
UB - In the benchmark OL case, IPSS simply applies the
FIFO (first in first out) rule to incoming
payment requests if it has cash. Otherwise, wait
for incoming payments. - Strategic behavior leading to payment delay or
reordering of payments occurs only if the
liquidity posted is below the upper bound UB.
20JIT Optimal rule of delay
- Minimization of total settlement cost, which
consists of delay costs plus liquidity costs.
Gives an optimal time for payment execution tE
21 22Experiment Results
23IPSS Experiments
- Open liquidity vs. Just in time liquidity
(Optimal rule) - Under two payment submission strategies
- First in first out (FIFO)
- Order by size (smallest first)
24Liquidity/Delay JIT vs. OL
25Throughput in JIT vs. OL
Throughput Cumulative value () of payments
made at any time.
26Failure analysis
- IPSS allows to simulate the failure of a bank,
and to observe the effects. For example, under
JIT - Note that, because of the asymmetry of the UK
banking system, a failure of a bank would have a
very different effect, depending on the size of
the failed bank.
Scenario Failure big bank (K) Failure small bank (F)
Chaps IID Real 32,384 94.2 bn 2,634 1.0 bn
Equal size banks 11,732 21,1 bn 11,732 21,1 bn
27summary
- We developed a useful payments simulator
- - able to handle stochastic simulation
- - able to handle strategic behaviour.
- The experiments we ran suggested that
open-liquidity leads to less delay than
just-in-time. -
- Future work will covers adaptive learning by
banks to play the treasury management game and
their response to hybrid rules.