Regulation, Competition, and Essential Facilities - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

1 / 30
About This Presentation
Title:

Regulation, Competition, and Essential Facilities

Description:

Postal services. 1990s: mandate review; opening of some markets to competition. Electricity ... Industry Canada ... input (NXX codes, subscriber listings, local ... – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:94
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 31
Provided by: Rode5
Category:

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: Regulation, Competition, and Essential Facilities


1
Regulation, Competition, and Essential Facilities
  • The Competition Bureaus Approach

Presentation to ECON 371, Queens University Matt
Kellison, Senior Competition Law
Officer Competition Bureau November 14, 2008
2
Points for Discussion
  • How the Bureau looks at regulated industries
  • The interface between competition law and
    regulation
  • A brief history of Bureau intervention
  • Case study unbundling and essential facilities
  • Disclaimer all views are my own

3
What does the Competition Bureau do?
  • Independent law enforcement agency responsible
    for the Competition Act
  • Mergers
  • Cartels
  • Abuse of Dominance
  • False and misleading advertising
  • Competition policy advocate within government
  • Statutory authority to intervene before federal
    and provincial boards, tribunals, commissions,
    etc.

4
Philosophy
  • Market forces should be relied upon to the
    maximum extent possible to protect consumer
    interests
  • When market forces are insufficient,
    regulation/intervention should be designed to
    meet necessary objectives in the most direct and
    minimally-intrusive way possible
  • When is this a problem? Usually in industries
    with persistent market power, such as natural
    monopolies (air, rail, post, communications)

5
Market Power
  • The Bureau uses competition law tools to define
    relevant markets and assess market power (the
    ability of a firm to price above competitive
    levels)
  • The Bureaus advocacy usually involves the
    following
  • Market power exists! We need regulation!
  • Some market power still exists, but regulation
    should be modified! (postal services,
    electricity)
  • Market power no longer exists! Time to forbear!
    (telecom)
  • Theres no market power! Dont regulate! (the
    Internet?)

6
Market Power in Competition Law vs. Regulation
  • When enforcing the Act, the Bureau is concerned
    with market power in two cases
  • A firm is engaging in anti-competitive behaviour
    to maintain or enhance its market power (abuse of
    dominance)
  • Two firms are merging with the result that market
    power is likely to be created
  • The first situation involves retrospective
    analysis what did/would the market look like
    without the conduct? Was it significantly more
    competitive but for?
  • The second involves prospective analysis what
    will happen if the firms get together?

7
Market Power in Competition Law vs. Regulation
  • Regulatory concerns with market power are
    typically prospective what will happen if
    regulation is added/removed?
  • When the Bureau advocates, we usually provide
    input on appropriate markets before assessing
    market power
  • Given market power, the Bureau then focuses on
    the appropriate instrument of intervention in
    most cases, this is something short of full price
    regulation

8
Exercise vs. Abuse of Market Power
  • Competition advocacy is primarily done by the
    Civil Matters Branch of the Bureau, which also
    enforces the abuse of dominance provisions
  • Market power, in and of itself, does not offend
    the abuse provisions of the Act (only its
    creation or artificial preservation)
  • When regulators act in the public interest,
    however, they are concerned with the mere
    existence/exercise of market power
  • This, combined with a more prospective approach,
    usually involves a modification of what the
    Bureau would do in an enforcement context

9
Past Bureau Interventions
  • Airlines
  • 1980s fare deregulation, privatization of Air
    Canada
  • 1990s open skies agreement with the US
  • 2000s further liberalization end of foreign
    ownership?
  • Postal services
  • 1990s mandate review opening of some markets to
    competition
  • Electricity
  • 1990s deregulation and some competitive entry in
    retail services
  • Rail
  • The Bureau has been most active, however, in
    telecommunications

10
Regulatory Framework
  • Industry Canada
  • Responsible for both the Telecommunications Act
    (administered by the CRTC) and the Competition
    Act (administered by the Bureau)
  • Directly responsible for government telecom
    policy, CRTC appeals, and spectrum allocation
  • CRTC
  • Oversees regulated telecom markets access,
    service quality, wholesale and retail price
    regulation, universal service funding, dialing
    parity, number portability, etc.
  • Quasi-judicial can impose regulation and
    adjudicate
  • Competition Bureau
  • Enforces competition law in unregulated markets
    advocates

11
Forbearance
  • The objectives of the Telecommunications Act
    include fostering increased reliance on market
    forces
  • Under s. 34, the CRTC shall forbear from
    regulation when competition is sufficient to
    protect the interests of users it may also
    forbear if refraining from regulation would
    otherwise be consistent with any of its other
    objectives
  • The Bureau and CRTC have an interface agreement
    to deal with jurisdictional issues once the CRTC
    no longer regulates (or regulates partially)

12
Opening Up Telecom Markets
  • Before the 1980s, almost all services were
    provided by interconnected local monopolies
    (ILECs)
  • 1980s entry in wireless deregulated terminal
    equipment
  • 1992 entry in long distance
  • 1994 review of regulatory framework (price caps,
    rate rebalancing, forbearance criteria)
  • 1997 first spectrum auction forbearance from
    long-distance regulation local competition
    (access and interconnection)
  • 1998 price cap regulation replaces rate of
    return regulation
  • 1999 exemption from regulation of new
    media/Internet

13
  • 2001 expansion and rate adjustment of wholesale
    access regime for local competition
  • 2002 price caps revision
  • 2005 CRTC decides to regulate ILEC VoIP
    offerings (later overturned by government)
  • The Bureau participated in most of the
    proceedings leading up to these decisions,
    generally focusing on a maximum reliance on
    market forces, as well as market-based pricing
    and tax mechanisms to address social policy
    issues
  • The Bureau has also consistently petitioned the
    government remove foreign ownership restrictions
    in telecom

14
Recent developments local forbearance
  • March 2006 TPRP Final Report recommends a
    reliance on market forces (not regulation) to the
    maximum extent possible, which the Minister of
    Industry issues as a Policy Direction to the CRTC
    in June
  • April 2006 CRTC issues its decision on
    regulatory forbearance for local exchange
    services, requiring 25 market share loss and
    certain quality of service requirements
  • The Bureau had recommended a test based on
    competing facilities-based providers and
    underlying competitive conditions in most
    residential markets, a cable entrant with equal
    or lower costs and some evidence of rivalry would
    be sufficient

15
  • April 2007 the Governor-in-Council varies the
    CRTCs decision, citing the Policy Direction
    forbearance can now be granted based on
    competitive presence (two facilities-based
    providers plus wireless) or the Bureaus test
  • In practice, these two tests will usually come to
    the same result
  • Summer 2007 widespread retail forbearance
    begins in local residential and business markets
    based on competitive presence. To date,
    approximately 70 of these markets have been
    deregulated
  • Now long distance, wireless, Internet, and local
    service are no longer (or have never been
    regulated). Whats left? Wholesale access

16
Wholesale Access
  • In 1997, the CRTCs local competition decision
    established a wholesale access regime where
    competitors could rely to the ILEC to provision
    essential facilities and services
  • The essential facility doctrine was established
    in s. 2 case law in the US, although never
    recognized by the Supreme Court
  • The CRTC initially defined an essential facility
    as one that was monopoly controlled,
    non-duplicable, and which competitors required as
    an input (NXX codes, subscriber listings, local
    loops)

17
Why Wholesale?
  • If the problem is downstream market power, why
    use an upstream instrument? Why not just
    regulate at retail?
  • More dynamic competition?
  • Stepping stone theory
  • What are the pitfalls?
  • Getting the right set of facilities
  • Setting the right price
  • Preserving an efficient make-or-buy decision
  • When local competition developed slowly, the CRTC
    broadened the set of facilities and lowered the
    price. . .

18
Costs and Benefits
  • Obviously facilities-based competition is better
    if you can get it, but has wholesale access
    helped us get there, or technology?
  • How great are the benefits of competition from
    mandated access, and in which markets (e.g.
    residential, large business)? What have the
    costs been? Is there investment?
  • What are the costs of over-mandating access?
    (Type I error) What about under-mandating
    access? (Type II error) Does this mean access
    should be ex ante or ex post?

19
Some Numbers
  • Wholesale access has met with limited success.
    There has been
  • little growth in CLECs using resale or leased
    lines.
  • Source CRTC Monitoring Reports, 2004-2008,
    Table 5.2.4 and Figure 5.2.2 (figures are in
    thousands of lines).

20
  • CLECs using their own facilities (largely cable
    companies) have
  • become a significant competitive presence.
  • Source CRTC Monitoring Reports, 2004-2008,
    Tables 5.4.2 and 4.2.5.

21
Residential and Business
  • The gains by facilities-based CLECs are strongest
    in residential.
  • The share of facilities-based CLECs in business
    is more modest.
  • Source CRTC Monitoring Reports, Tables 4.2.5
    and 5.4.2.

22
Impact on Prices
  • Average (local access) revenue of CLECs was
    significantly
  • lower than ILECs. Comeptition did result in some
    reduction
  • in avg. revenue per line (i.e., average price
    paid by consumers)
  • Source CRTC Monitoring Reports, 2004-2008,
    Tables 5.2.3 and 5.2.4. Bracketed figures show
    percentage change in absolute value.

23
Essential Facilities Proceeding
  • September 2006 Bureau publishes the draft TAB
    with its approach to access to facilities under
    the Act, focusing on a firms ability to maintain
    or enhance dominance in retail markets by denying
    access
  • December 2006 CRTC uses the Bureaus approach
    as a proposed definition for an essential
    facility in its review of mandated wholesale
    access Bureau recommends the scope of access be
    narrowed as it has been ineffective in generating
    retail competition

24
Enforcement vs. Regulation
  • The Bureau modified its TAB test slightly to
    reflect a regulatory context as opposed to
    enforcement (exercise of market power, not abuse)
  • The Bureaus TAB test focuses on the effect of a
    denial of access versus access at the monopoly
    price the CRTC is concerned with whether
    granting access at a regulated price will
    generate effective downstream competition

25
The Bureaus Test (1)
  • (i) The firm controlling the facility in question
    is vertically integrated and dominant in two
    markets the upstream (wholesale) market, and
    the downstream (retail) market where the facility
    is used as an input. A necessary condition for
    upstream dominance is that the facility is that
    it is not practical or feasible for competitors
    to duplicate the facility
  • In practice it is downstream dominance that is
    most important as a screen (and upstream demand
    is derived)
  • Strong vs. weak interpretation of duplicable?

26
The Bureaus Test (2)
  • (ii) Withdrawing mandated access to the facility
    is likely to result in competitors exiting from,
    or contracting in, the downstream market
  • (iii) Such exit or contraction is likely to
    result in a substantial lessening of competition
    in the downstream market
  • These conditions can be applied retrospectively
    (withdrawing access) or prospectively (mandating
    access). In both cases, access must be the
    primary barrier preventing material competition
    from emerging

27
Further Considerations
  • Should we only mandate services with clear
    benefits now (call termination, support
    structures, listings) and mandate the rest later?
  • How should access be priced?
  • What if retail markets have already been forborne
    on the basis of wholesale access?

28
The Decision
  • March 2008 - CRTC narrows the scope of access
    somewhat but retains a wide regime in an attempt
    to maintain competition beyond two players in
    markets that are now deregulated (two is not
    enough?)
  • Definition must be required by competitors in a
    downstream market must not be practical or
    feasible to duplicate must be controlled by a
    firm with upstream market power such that
    withdrawal will lead to an SLC downstream
  • CRTC does not require downstream market power
    because many of those markets have been forborne

29
Concerns?
  • No relevant market definition (for product or
    geographic)
  • How is the test applied? (CRTC buckets focus on
    duplicability, but on a national basis)
  • ADSL duplicated, so it is mandated
    non-essential?
  • Loops based on upstream, not downstream market
    power
  • Business services (DS-0, DS-1, DS-3) where have
    these been duplicated?
  • Will the markets look different for the next
    review?

30
(No Transcript)
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)
About PowerShow.com