Title: Regulation, Competition, and Essential Facilities
1Regulation, Competition, and Essential Facilities
- The Competition Bureaus Approach
Presentation to ECON 371, Queens University Matt
Kellison, Senior Competition Law
Officer Competition Bureau November 14, 2008
2Points for Discussion
- How the Bureau looks at regulated industries
- The interface between competition law and
regulation - A brief history of Bureau intervention
- Case study unbundling and essential facilities
- Disclaimer all views are my own
3What does the Competition Bureau do?
- Independent law enforcement agency responsible
for the Competition Act - Mergers
- Cartels
- Abuse of Dominance
- False and misleading advertising
- Competition policy advocate within government
- Statutory authority to intervene before federal
and provincial boards, tribunals, commissions,
etc.
4Philosophy
- Market forces should be relied upon to the
maximum extent possible to protect consumer
interests - When market forces are insufficient,
regulation/intervention should be designed to
meet necessary objectives in the most direct and
minimally-intrusive way possible - When is this a problem? Usually in industries
with persistent market power, such as natural
monopolies (air, rail, post, communications)
5Market Power
- The Bureau uses competition law tools to define
relevant markets and assess market power (the
ability of a firm to price above competitive
levels) - The Bureaus advocacy usually involves the
following - Market power exists! We need regulation!
- Some market power still exists, but regulation
should be modified! (postal services,
electricity) - Market power no longer exists! Time to forbear!
(telecom) - Theres no market power! Dont regulate! (the
Internet?)
6Market Power in Competition Law vs. Regulation
- When enforcing the Act, the Bureau is concerned
with market power in two cases - A firm is engaging in anti-competitive behaviour
to maintain or enhance its market power (abuse of
dominance) - Two firms are merging with the result that market
power is likely to be created - The first situation involves retrospective
analysis what did/would the market look like
without the conduct? Was it significantly more
competitive but for? - The second involves prospective analysis what
will happen if the firms get together?
7Market Power in Competition Law vs. Regulation
- Regulatory concerns with market power are
typically prospective what will happen if
regulation is added/removed? - When the Bureau advocates, we usually provide
input on appropriate markets before assessing
market power - Given market power, the Bureau then focuses on
the appropriate instrument of intervention in
most cases, this is something short of full price
regulation
8Exercise vs. Abuse of Market Power
- Competition advocacy is primarily done by the
Civil Matters Branch of the Bureau, which also
enforces the abuse of dominance provisions - Market power, in and of itself, does not offend
the abuse provisions of the Act (only its
creation or artificial preservation) - When regulators act in the public interest,
however, they are concerned with the mere
existence/exercise of market power - This, combined with a more prospective approach,
usually involves a modification of what the
Bureau would do in an enforcement context
9Past Bureau Interventions
- Airlines
- 1980s fare deregulation, privatization of Air
Canada - 1990s open skies agreement with the US
- 2000s further liberalization end of foreign
ownership? - Postal services
- 1990s mandate review opening of some markets to
competition - Electricity
- 1990s deregulation and some competitive entry in
retail services - Rail
- The Bureau has been most active, however, in
telecommunications
10Regulatory Framework
- Industry Canada
- Responsible for both the Telecommunications Act
(administered by the CRTC) and the Competition
Act (administered by the Bureau) - Directly responsible for government telecom
policy, CRTC appeals, and spectrum allocation - CRTC
- Oversees regulated telecom markets access,
service quality, wholesale and retail price
regulation, universal service funding, dialing
parity, number portability, etc. - Quasi-judicial can impose regulation and
adjudicate - Competition Bureau
- Enforces competition law in unregulated markets
advocates
11Forbearance
- The objectives of the Telecommunications Act
include fostering increased reliance on market
forces - Under s. 34, the CRTC shall forbear from
regulation when competition is sufficient to
protect the interests of users it may also
forbear if refraining from regulation would
otherwise be consistent with any of its other
objectives - The Bureau and CRTC have an interface agreement
to deal with jurisdictional issues once the CRTC
no longer regulates (or regulates partially)
12Opening Up Telecom Markets
- Before the 1980s, almost all services were
provided by interconnected local monopolies
(ILECs) - 1980s entry in wireless deregulated terminal
equipment - 1992 entry in long distance
- 1994 review of regulatory framework (price caps,
rate rebalancing, forbearance criteria) - 1997 first spectrum auction forbearance from
long-distance regulation local competition
(access and interconnection) - 1998 price cap regulation replaces rate of
return regulation - 1999 exemption from regulation of new
media/Internet
13 - 2001 expansion and rate adjustment of wholesale
access regime for local competition - 2002 price caps revision
- 2005 CRTC decides to regulate ILEC VoIP
offerings (later overturned by government) - The Bureau participated in most of the
proceedings leading up to these decisions,
generally focusing on a maximum reliance on
market forces, as well as market-based pricing
and tax mechanisms to address social policy
issues - The Bureau has also consistently petitioned the
government remove foreign ownership restrictions
in telecom
14Recent developments local forbearance
- March 2006 TPRP Final Report recommends a
reliance on market forces (not regulation) to the
maximum extent possible, which the Minister of
Industry issues as a Policy Direction to the CRTC
in June - April 2006 CRTC issues its decision on
regulatory forbearance for local exchange
services, requiring 25 market share loss and
certain quality of service requirements - The Bureau had recommended a test based on
competing facilities-based providers and
underlying competitive conditions in most
residential markets, a cable entrant with equal
or lower costs and some evidence of rivalry would
be sufficient
15 - April 2007 the Governor-in-Council varies the
CRTCs decision, citing the Policy Direction
forbearance can now be granted based on
competitive presence (two facilities-based
providers plus wireless) or the Bureaus test - In practice, these two tests will usually come to
the same result - Summer 2007 widespread retail forbearance
begins in local residential and business markets
based on competitive presence. To date,
approximately 70 of these markets have been
deregulated - Now long distance, wireless, Internet, and local
service are no longer (or have never been
regulated). Whats left? Wholesale access
16Wholesale Access
- In 1997, the CRTCs local competition decision
established a wholesale access regime where
competitors could rely to the ILEC to provision
essential facilities and services - The essential facility doctrine was established
in s. 2 case law in the US, although never
recognized by the Supreme Court - The CRTC initially defined an essential facility
as one that was monopoly controlled,
non-duplicable, and which competitors required as
an input (NXX codes, subscriber listings, local
loops)
17Why Wholesale?
- If the problem is downstream market power, why
use an upstream instrument? Why not just
regulate at retail? - More dynamic competition?
- Stepping stone theory
- What are the pitfalls?
- Getting the right set of facilities
- Setting the right price
- Preserving an efficient make-or-buy decision
- When local competition developed slowly, the CRTC
broadened the set of facilities and lowered the
price. . .
18Costs and Benefits
- Obviously facilities-based competition is better
if you can get it, but has wholesale access
helped us get there, or technology? - How great are the benefits of competition from
mandated access, and in which markets (e.g.
residential, large business)? What have the
costs been? Is there investment? - What are the costs of over-mandating access?
(Type I error) What about under-mandating
access? (Type II error) Does this mean access
should be ex ante or ex post?
19Some Numbers
- Wholesale access has met with limited success.
There has been - little growth in CLECs using resale or leased
lines. - Source CRTC Monitoring Reports, 2004-2008,
Table 5.2.4 and Figure 5.2.2 (figures are in
thousands of lines).
20 - CLECs using their own facilities (largely cable
companies) have - become a significant competitive presence.
- Source CRTC Monitoring Reports, 2004-2008,
Tables 5.4.2 and 4.2.5.
21Residential and Business
- The gains by facilities-based CLECs are strongest
in residential. - The share of facilities-based CLECs in business
is more modest. - Source CRTC Monitoring Reports, Tables 4.2.5
and 5.4.2.
22Impact on Prices
- Average (local access) revenue of CLECs was
significantly - lower than ILECs. Comeptition did result in some
reduction - in avg. revenue per line (i.e., average price
paid by consumers) - Source CRTC Monitoring Reports, 2004-2008,
Tables 5.2.3 and 5.2.4. Bracketed figures show
percentage change in absolute value.
23Essential Facilities Proceeding
- September 2006 Bureau publishes the draft TAB
with its approach to access to facilities under
the Act, focusing on a firms ability to maintain
or enhance dominance in retail markets by denying
access - December 2006 CRTC uses the Bureaus approach
as a proposed definition for an essential
facility in its review of mandated wholesale
access Bureau recommends the scope of access be
narrowed as it has been ineffective in generating
retail competition
24Enforcement vs. Regulation
- The Bureau modified its TAB test slightly to
reflect a regulatory context as opposed to
enforcement (exercise of market power, not abuse) - The Bureaus TAB test focuses on the effect of a
denial of access versus access at the monopoly
price the CRTC is concerned with whether
granting access at a regulated price will
generate effective downstream competition
25The Bureaus Test (1)
- (i) The firm controlling the facility in question
is vertically integrated and dominant in two
markets the upstream (wholesale) market, and
the downstream (retail) market where the facility
is used as an input. A necessary condition for
upstream dominance is that the facility is that
it is not practical or feasible for competitors
to duplicate the facility - In practice it is downstream dominance that is
most important as a screen (and upstream demand
is derived) - Strong vs. weak interpretation of duplicable?
26The Bureaus Test (2)
- (ii) Withdrawing mandated access to the facility
is likely to result in competitors exiting from,
or contracting in, the downstream market - (iii) Such exit or contraction is likely to
result in a substantial lessening of competition
in the downstream market - These conditions can be applied retrospectively
(withdrawing access) or prospectively (mandating
access). In both cases, access must be the
primary barrier preventing material competition
from emerging
27Further Considerations
- Should we only mandate services with clear
benefits now (call termination, support
structures, listings) and mandate the rest later? - How should access be priced?
- What if retail markets have already been forborne
on the basis of wholesale access?
28The Decision
- March 2008 - CRTC narrows the scope of access
somewhat but retains a wide regime in an attempt
to maintain competition beyond two players in
markets that are now deregulated (two is not
enough?) - Definition must be required by competitors in a
downstream market must not be practical or
feasible to duplicate must be controlled by a
firm with upstream market power such that
withdrawal will lead to an SLC downstream - CRTC does not require downstream market power
because many of those markets have been forborne
29Concerns?
- No relevant market definition (for product or
geographic) - How is the test applied? (CRTC buckets focus on
duplicability, but on a national basis) - ADSL duplicated, so it is mandated
non-essential? - Loops based on upstream, not downstream market
power - Business services (DS-0, DS-1, DS-3) where have
these been duplicated? - Will the markets look different for the next
review?
30(No Transcript)