Title: Interest Rates and price determination
1Interest Rates and price determination
- Fin 288
- Futures Options and Swaps
2PV and FV in continuous time
- e 2.71828 y lnx x ey
- FV PV (1k)n for yearly compounding
- FV PV(1k/m)nm for m compounding periods per
year - As m increases this becomes
- FV PVern PVert let t n
- rearranging for PV PV FVe-rt
3Compounding periods
- The PV of 100 assuming 8 per year a various
compounding periods for 5 years.
of periods per year PV
2 44.63
4 45.29
12 45.05
52 44.96
continuous 44.93
4Some useful conversions
Given Rccontinuous compounding
rate Rmequivalent rate with m compounding
periods
5A General Valuation Model
- The basic components of valuing any asset are
- An estimate of the future cash flow stream from
owning the asset - The required rate of return for each period based
upon the riskiness of the asset - The value is then found by discounting each cash
flow by its respective discount rate and then
summing the PVs (Basically the PV of an Uneven
Cash Flow Stream)
6The formal model (Discrete Time)
- The value of any asset should then be equal to
7Components of the General Model
- Cash Flow at time t (CFt) the expected future
cash flow that the owner of the asset expects to
receive at time t. - The future cash flow may not be known with
certainty. - The Discount Rate The return that investors in
the market are requiring for owning the asset. - The discount rate should reflect the risks faced
by the investor. What risks are faced???
8The Discount Rate
- The required rate can be seen as an aggregation
of the different forces that impact the riskiness
of owning the asset - rRRIPDPMPLPEP
- RR The Real Rate of Interest (reward for saving
or investing instead of consuming) - IP The Inflation Premium
- DP Default Risk Premium
- MP Maturity Premium
- LP Liquidity Premium
- EP Exchange Rate Risk Premium
9The General Model
- Note
- The interest Rate and Cash Flows can change with
each period. - We will start with a basic bond, assuming that
the discount rate is constant across periods.
10Applying the general valuation formula to a bond
- What component of a bond represents the future
cash flows? - Coupon Payment The amount the holder of the bond
receives in interest at the end of each specified
period. - The Par Value The amount that will be repaid to
the purchaser at the end of the debt agreement.
11Basic Bond Mathematics
- Given
- r The interest rate per period or return paid on
assets of similar risk - CP The coupon payment
- MV The Par Value (or Maturity Value)
- n the number of periods until maturity
- The value of the bond is represented as
12Applying the formula
- Assume that we bought a 9 yearly coupon bond
with 20 years left to maturity and one year later
the required return decreased to 7. - What is the value of the bond?
- 19 N 7 I 90 PMT 1,000 FV PV1,206.71
13Why 1,206.71?
- New bonds of similar risk are only paying a 7
return. This implies a coupon rate of 7 and a
coupon payment of 70. - The old bond has a coupon payment of 90,
everyone will want to buy the old bond, (the
increased demand increases the price) - Why does it stop at 1,206.71?
- If you bought the bond for 1,206.71 and received
90 coupon payments for the next 19 years you
receive a 7 return.
14Quick Facts for Review
- If the level of interest rates in the economy
increases the bond price decreases and vice
versa. - If rgtCoupon rate the price of the bond is below
the par value - it sells at a discount. - If rltCoupon rate the price of the bond is above
the par value - it sells at a premium. - Keeping everything constant the value of the bond
will move toward par value as it gets closer to
maturity.
15The formal model (Continuous Time)
- The value of any asset should then be equal to
16 A Package of Zero Coupon Bonds
- You can think of a bond as a package of zero
coupon bonds. Each payment received represents a
zero coupon bond. - Since yields differ with maturity, this implies
that it does not make sense to use only one rate
(the YTM) to value the bond. - The value of the bond should be the same
regardless of which way it is valued.
17Stripped Coupons
- If the value of the individual coupons is
different from the entire bond it would be
possible to buy the bond and sell the coupons as
a security making a risk free profit. - To value the stripped coupons each would be
valued at a rate that matches its maturity, the
rate should also represent a zero coupon bond. - We can use the information in the market to
create a zero coupon yield curve.
18Zero Coupon (spot) Rates
- The n year spot interest rate is the rate that
would be earned today on an investment lasting n
years - Assumes that no interest or coupon payments are
made. - The Forward Rate will be the rate between two
points in time in the future implied by the zero
coupon yield curve
19Spot Rate Yield Curve
- The spot rate yield curve will be the value of
the pot rate at different maturities. - Often this is calculated for treasury securities
based on the assumption that treasuries are
risk free
20Theoretical Spot Rate Curves
- Two main issues
- Given a series of Treasury securities, how do you
construct the curve? - Linear Extrapolation
- Bootstrapping
- Other
- What Treasuries should be used to construct it?
- On the run Treasuries
- On the run Treasuries and selected off the run
Treasuries - All Treasury Coupon Securities and Bills
- Treasury Coupon Strips
21Observed Yields
- For on-the-run treasury securities you can
observe the current yield. - For the coupon bearing bonds the yield used
reflects the yield that would make it trade at
par. The resulting on the run curve is the par
coupon curve. - However, you may have missing maturities for the
on the run issues. Then you will need to
estimate the missing maturities.
22Example
- Maturity Yield
- 1 mo 1.7
- 3 mo 1.69
- 6 mo 1.67
- 1 yr 1.74
- 5 yr 3.22
- 10 yr 4.14
- 20 yr 5.06
- The yield for each of the semiannual periods
between 1 yr and 5 yr would be found from
extrapolation.
23- 5 yr yield 3.22 1 yr yield 1.74
- 8 semi annual periods
24Bootstrapping
- To avoid the missing maturities it is possible to
estimate the zero spot rate from the current
yields, and prices using bootstrapping. - Bootstrapping successively calculates the next
zero coupon from those already calculated.
25Treasury Bills vs. Notes and Bonds
- Treasury bills are issued for maturities of one
year or less. They are pure discount instruments
(there is no coupon payment). - Everything over two years is issued as a coupon
bond.
26Bootstrapping example
- Assume we have the following on the run treasury
bills and bonds - Assume that all coupon bearing bonds (greater
than 1 year) are selling at par (constructing a
par value yield curve) - Maturity YTM Maturity YTM
- 0.5 4 2.5 5.0
- 1.0 4.2 3.0 5.2
- 1.5 4.45 3.5 5.4
- 2.0 4.75 4.0 5.55
27Bootstrapping continued
- Since the 6 month and one year bills are zero
coupon instruments we will use them to estimate
the zero coupon 1.5 year rate. - The 1.5 year note would make a semiannual coupon
payment of 100(.0445)/22.225 - Therefore the cash flows from the bond would be
- t0.52.225 t12.225 t1.5102.225
28Bootstrapping continued
- A package of stripped securities should sell for
the same price (100 par value) as the 1.5 year
bond to eliminate arbitrage. - The correct semi annual interest rates to use
come from the annualized zero coupon bonds - r0.5 4/2 2 r1.0 4.2/2 2.1
29Bootstrapping continued
- r0.5 4/2 2 r1.0 4.2/2 2.1
- The price of the package of zero coupons should
equal the price of the theoretical 1.5 year zero
coupon -
30Bootstrapping continued
31Bootstrapping continued
- The semi annual rate is therefore 2.2293 and the
annual yield would be 4.4586 - Similarly the 2 year yield could be found
- the coupon is 4.75 implying coupon payments of
2.375 and cash flows of - t0.52.375 t1.02.375 t1.52.375
t2.0102.375
32Bootstrapping continued
33Bootstrapping continued
- What is the 2.5 year par value zero coupon rate?
The coupon is 5
34Bootstrapping part 2 continuous time
- Now assume you know the following information
concerning 100 par value bonds - Time Annual Coupon Bond Price
- .25 0 97.50
- .50 0 94.90
- 1.0 0 90.00
- 1.5 8 96.00
- 2.0 12 101.6
35The zero spot rates
- If you purchase the 3 month bond today for 97.50,
you receive 100 in 3 months. - This implies a 2.50/97.5 .0256 return over the
three months. - The yearly continuous compounding return would
then be - 4ln(1.0256) .1013
36Zero Coupon Rates
- Similarly the 6 month rate would be .1047 and the
one year rate would be .1054
37Bootstrapping
- The 1.5 year bond makes 8 yearly coupon payments
each year of 4 each 6 months. - Given the current price and the zero coupon
rates the 1.5 year rate can be found
38Bootstrapping
- You can then solve for the 2 year rate using the
1.5 year rate and the information from the 2 year
bond.
39Forward Rates
- Using the theoretical spot curve it is possible
to determine a measure of the markets expected
future short term rate. - Assume you are choosing between buying a 6month
zero coupon bond and then reinvesting the money
in another 6 month zero coupon bond OR buying a
one year zero coupon bond. - Today you know the rates on the 6 month and 1
year bonds, but you are uncertain about the
future six month rate.
40Forward Rates
- The forward rate is the rate on the future six
month bond that would make you indifferent
between the two options. - Let z1 the 6 month zero coupon rate
- z2 the 1 year zero coupon rate (semiannual)
- f the rate forward rate from 6 mos to 1 year.
41Returns
- Return on investing twice for six months
- (1z1)(1f)
- Return on the one year bond
- (1z2)2
- If you are indifferent between the two, they must
provide the same return - (1z1)(1f) (1z2)2
- or
- f ((1z2)2/(1z1))-1
42Forward Rates
- Forward rates do not generally do a good job of
actually predicting the future rate, but they do
allow the investor to hedge - If their expectation of the future rate is less
than the forward rate they are better off
investing for the entire year and lock in the 6
month forward rate over the last 6 months now.
43Forward rate - continuous time
- Assume you know the following zero coupon rates
continuous rates - 1 year 3 2 years 4
- The one year return on 100 is
- 100e.03 103.04545
- The total value after two years is
- 100e.04(2) 108.33
44Forward rate
- The forward rate (f) is the rate that would make
the investment from time 1 to time 2 have the
same return as the two year return or - (100e.03)ef 108.33
- 103.04545ef 108.33
- ef1.05127
- ln(ef)fln(1.05127)
- f .05
45Continuous compounding
- Notice that in the previous example the two year
rate was the average of the one year rate and the
forward rate. - This occurs because we are looking at time 1 to
time 2 and continuous compounding allows for a
nice generalization.
46Generalization Forward Rates
- Given
- R1 and R2 The zero rate for maturity t1 and t2
- T1 and T2 The number of periods t1 and t2
- Rf The forward rate between the periods 1 and 2
47Treasury Yield Curve
- The most commonly investigated and used term
structure is the treasury yield curve. (will
want to look at zero rates) - Treasuries are used since they are
- Considered free of default, and therefore differ
only in maturity - The benchmark used to set base rates
- Extremely liquid
48Yield Curves Over the Last Year
49US Treas Rates Jan 1990 Dec 2003
50Three Explanations of the Yield Curve
- The Expectations Theories
- Segmented Markets Theory
- Preferred Habitat Theory
51Pure Expectations Theory
- Long term rates are a representation of the short
term interest rates investors expect to receive
in the future. In other words the forward rates
reflect the future expected rate. - Assumes that bonds of different maturities are
perfect substitutes - In other words, the expected return from holding
a one year bond today and a one year bond next
year is the same as buying a two year bond today.
(the same process that was used to calculate our
forward rates)
52Pure Expectations
- Given a two period model in continuous time we
just showed that the 2 period rate will be equal
to the average of the 1 period rate and the
forward rate.
53Expectations Hypothesis R2 (RfR1)/2
- When the yield curve is upward sloping (R2gtR1) it
is expected that short term rates will be
increasing (the average future short term rate
is above the current short term rate). - Likewise when the yield curve is downward sloping
the average of the future short term rates is
below the current rate. (Fact 2) - As short term rates increase the long term rate
will also increase and a decrease in short term
rates will decrease long term rates. (Fact 1) - This however does not explain Fact 3 that the
yield curve usually slopes up.
54Problems with Pure Expectations
- The pure expectations theory ignores the fact
that there is reinvestment rate risk and
different price risk for the two maturities. - Consider an investor considering a 5 year horizon
with three alternatives - buying a bond with a 5 year maturity
- buying a bond with a 10 year maturity and holding
it 5 years - buying a bond with a 20 year maturity and holding
it 5 years.
55Price Risk
- The return on the bond with a 5 year maturity is
known with certainty the other two are not. - The longer the maturity the greater the price risk
56Reinvestment rate risk
- Now assume the investor is considering a short
term investment then reinvesting for the
remainder of the five years or investing for five
years. - Again the 5 year return is known with certainty,
but the others are not.
57Local expectations
- Local expectations theory says that returns of
different maturities will be the same over a very
short term horizon, for example three months.
58Return to maturity expectations hypothesis
- This theory claims that the return achieved by
buying short term and rolling over to a longer
horizon will match the zero coupon return on the
longer horizon bond. This eliminates the
reinvestment risk.
59Liquidity Theory
- This explanation claims that the since there is a
price risk associated with the long term bonds,
investor must be offered a premium. Therefore
the long term rate reflects both an expectations
component and a liquidity premium. - This tends to imply that the yield curve will be
upward sloping as long as the premium is large
enough to outweigh an possible expected decrease.
60Segmented Markets Theory
- Interest Rates for each maturity are determined
by the supply and demand for bonds at each
maturity. - Different maturity bonds are not perfect
substitutes for each other. - Implies that investors are not willing to accept
a premium to switch from their market to a
different maturity. - Therefore the shape of the yield curve depends
upon the asset liability constraints and goals of
the market participants.
61Preferred Habitat Theory
- Like the liquidity theory this idea assumes that
there is an expectations component and a risk
premium. - In other words the bonds are substitutes, but
savers might have a preference for one maturity
over another (they are not perfect substitutes). - If there are demand and supply imbalances then
investors might be willing to switch to a
different maturity.
62Preferred Habitat Theory
- The long term rate should include a premium
associated with them. To attract savers who
prefer a shorter maturity, the long term bond
will need to pay an additional amount or term
(liquidity) premium. - Thus according to the theory a rise in short term
rates still causes a rise in the average of the
future short term rates. Therefore the long and
short rates move together (Fact 1).
63Preferred Habitat Theory
- The explanation of Fact 2 from the expectations
hypothesis still works. In the case of a
downward sloping yield curve, the term premium
(interest rate risk) must not be large enough to
compensate for the currently high short term
rates (Current high inflation with an expectation
of a decrease in inflation). Since the demand
for the short term bonds will increase, the yield
on them should fall in the future.
64Preferred Habitat Theory
- Fact three is explained since it will be unusual
for the term premium to be so small that the
yield curve slopes down.
65Price Determination in Forward and Futures Markets
- Fin 288
- Futures Options and Swaps
66Determining the delivery price
- The delivery price will be determined by the
participants expectations about the future price
and their willingness to enter into the contract.
(Todays spot price most likely does not equal
the delivery price). - What else should be considered?
- They should both also consider the time value of
money
67Theoretical Pricing of Futures Contracts
- The theoretical price Is based upon the
elimination of arbitrage opportunities. - Start with a simple example
- Assume transaction costs are zero
- Assume that storage costs are zero
- You have a choice today of purchasing or selling
a given asset or entering into a contract to buy
or sell it in the future.
68Theoretical Price
- Assume you want to own the asset at a given point
in time in the future, You can enter into a long
futures position or buy the asset today and hold
on to it. - If you enter into the futures contract you can
invest your cash today and earn interest ( r)
69Basic Relationship
- The Forward Price (F) should equal the spot price
(S) plus any interest that could be received on
an amount of cash equal to the spot price or - Note The book uses continuous compounding to
illustrate the same result
70Eliminating Arbitrage
- If the forward price is greater than the spot
plus interest an arbitrage opportunity exists. - Borrow to buy the underlying asset in the spot
market and take a short position in the futures
contract. (for now we will use forward and
futures price as if they are the same thing)
71Numerical Example
- Consider an asset that is currently selling at
30 The asset has a two year futures price of
35. The risk free rate is 5
At Time 0 Borrow 30 (will need to repay
30(1.05)233.075 Buy asset for 30 Take Short
Futures Position
At Time 2 Deliver Asset in Futures Receive
35 Payoff loan with 33.075 Profit 35-33.075
1.925
72Example cont
- Increased demand for short contracts, the of
participants willing to sell in two years will be
greater than the number willing to buy. - Those willing to sell will compete by lowering
their price therefore the futures price
declines...
73Eliminating Arbitrage Part 2
- What if the futures price is less than the spot
price plus interest? - Short Sell the underlying asset and take a long
position in the futures market
74Numerical example
- What if the futures price is 31 instead of 35?
Leave the spot price at 30 and r at 5
At time 0 Short sell the asset and receive
30 Place the 30 in the bank receive
30(1.05)33.075 Take out a long position in the
Forward Market
At time 1 Receive 33.075 Buy the asset in futures
market for 31 Profit 33.075-31 2.075
75Eliminating Arbitrage
- Now there is an excess of participants willing to
take a long position but few willing to take a
short position. - To facilitate trading the futures price will
increase. As the price increases it is more
attractive to participants willing to take a
short position.
76Eliminating Arbitrage
- In both cases the futures price moves toward a
point where arbitrage does not exist - When the futures price is 33.075 neither strategy
is possible and arbitrage is eliminated
77Short Sales
- What if it is not possible to short sell the
asset? - That is not a problem as long as there are enough
people that hold the asset that are willing to
sell in the futures market.
78Paying a known cash income
- The above analysis can be extended to the case
where the underlying asset pays a known cash
income (a treasury bond for example) - We are going to assume that the cash payment is
due at the same time as the expiration of the
forward contract.
79Cash Income Example
- Suppose that you can purchase a treasury bond
that makes its coupon payments yearly. If you
purchase the bond it will pay a coupon payment of
35 in one year. The bond has a forward price of
950. The risk free rate is 5.
80Know cash income
- We want to consider the coupon as a cash flow
just like the forward price. - Let the spot price be 930
- (F Coupon Payment) gt S(1r)T
- 985 95035 gt 930(1.05) 976.50
- What arbitrage opportunity exists?
81Similar to before
- Borrow to buy the underlying asset in the spot
market and take a short position in the futures
contract.
At time 0 Borrow 930 Buy bond for 930 Enter
into short position
At time 1 Receive coupon payment 35 Sell bond
in Fut Market 950 Receive total 985 Repay loan
976.50 Profit 3.50
82Opposite Case
- What if current price is 940?
At time 0 Short sell bond receive 940 Invest
940 at 5 Enter into Long Position in Fut
At Time 1 Receive 940(1.05) 987 Buy bond in
Fut Market 950 Close short sale pay coupon
35 Profit 2
83No Arbitrage
- Again the futures price is moving toward a point
where there will not be an arbitrage opportunity. - (F Coupon Payment) S(1r)T
- Rearranging
- F S(1r)T - Coupon Payment
- F S (1r)T - CP(1r)T/(1r)T
- F(S CP/(1r)T)(1r)T
- where CP/(1r)T is the PV of the coupon payment
84Extension
- If cash payments come at other points in time,
all you need is a generalization of the
relationship above. - Let I represent the PV of all coupon payments to
be received during the forward contract. - F (SI)(1r)T
85Accounting for payments
- Consider the 1 year forward contract on a bond
that matures in 5 years. Assume that the bond
makes semiannual coupon payments of 40 and has a
spot price of 900. - The 6 month rate is 9 and the 1 year rate is 10
- PV of coupon 1 40/(1.09)0.5 38.31
- PV of coupon 2 40/1.10 36.36
86Assume futures price is 930
- F930 gt (900-39.31-36.36)(1.1)907.86
At time 0 Borrow 900 today Borrow 38.31 _at_9 for
6 mos Borrow 861.69 _at_ 10 for 1yr Enter into
short Futures position
At time 1 year Sell Bond for 930 Receive coup
pay 40 Total 970 Repay loan 861.69(1.1)
947.859 Profit 22.14
At time 6 mos Receive the 40 coupon
payment Repay 6 mo loan
87Extensions
- If the futures price was less than the spot minus
the PV of the coupons carried forward an argument
similar to the earlier ones could have also been
made - A final case is if the income stream pays a known
dividend income.
88Dividend income
- Assume that the asset pays a return of q in the
future based on the current price of the asset. - The equilibrium is then
- F S(1r)T/(1q)T
89Storage Costs?
- If the asset has a storage cost (more important
for commodities than financial assets), it can be
viewed as a negative cash income, the no
arbitrage condition would be - F (SU)(1r)T
- Where U represents the present value of all costs.
90Generalization
- Thank of the net amount of any of the possible
costs, income received, and interest as the cost
of carrying the spot position to the future. It
is the cost of holding the spot position instead
of the future position. - The equilibrium condition is then simply
- F (SC)(1rc)T
- C is any cash income / costs and
- rc is net interest expense