Title: Uncertainty and Consumer Behavior
1Chapter 5
- Uncertainty and Consumer Behavior
2Topics to be Discussed
- Describing Risk
- Preferences Toward Risk
- Reducing Risk
- The Demand for Risky Assets
3Introduction
- Choice with certainty is reasonably
straightforward. - How do we make choices when certain variables
such as income and prices are uncertain (making
choices with risk)?
4Describing Risk
- To measure risk we must know
- All of the possible outcomes.
- The probability or likelihood that each outcome
will occur (its probability).
5Describing Risk
- Interpreting Probability
- Objective Interpretation
- Based on the observed frequency of past events
- Subjective Interpretation
- Based on perception that an outcome will occur
6Interpreting Probability
- Subjective Probability
- Different information or different abilities to
process the same information can influence the
subjective probability - Based on judgment or experience
7Describing Risk
- With an interpretation of probability must
determine 2 measures to help describe and compare
risky choices - Expected value
- Variability
8Describing Risk
- Expected Value
- The weighted average of the payoffs or values
resulting from all possible outcomes. - Expected value measures the central tendency the
payoff or value expected on average.
9Expected Value An Example
- Investment in offshore drilling exploration
- Two outcomes are possible
- Success the stock price increases from 30 to
40/share - Failure the stock price falls from 30 to
20/share
10Expected Value An Example
- Objective Probability
- 100 explorations, 25 successes and 75 failures
- Probability (Pr) of success 1/4 and the
probability of failure 3/4
11Expected Value An Example
12Expected Value
- In general, for n possible outcomes
- Possible outcomes having payoffs X1, X2, Xn
- Probabilities of each outcome is given by Pr1,
Pr2, Prn
13Describing Risk
- Variability
- The extent to which possible outcomes of an
uncertain even may differ - How much variation exists in the possible choice
14Variability An Example
- Suppose you are choosing between two part-time
sales jobs that have the same expected income
(1,500) - The first job is based entirely on commission.
- The second is a salaried position.
15Variability An Example
- There are two equally likely outcomes in the
first job--2,000 for a good sales job and 1,000
for a modestly successful one. - The second pays 1,510 most of the time (.99
probability), but you will earn 510 if the
company goes out of business (.01 probability).
16Variability An Example
Outcome 1 Outcome 1 Outcome 2 Outcome 2
Prob. Income Prob. Income
Job 1 Commission .5 2000 .5 1000
Job 2 Fixed Salary .99 1510 .01 510
17Variability An Example
- Income from Possible Sales Job
- Job 1 Expected Income
Job 2 Expected Income
18Variability
- While the expected values are the same, the
variability is not. - Greater variability from expected values signals
greater risk. - Variability comes from deviations in payoffs
- Difference between expected payoff and actual
payoff
19Variability An Example
Deviations from Expected Income () Deviations from Expected Income () Deviations from Expected Income () Deviations from Expected Income () Deviations from Expected Income ()
Outcome 1 Deviation Outcome 2 Deviation
Job 1 2000 500 1000 -500
Job 2 1510 10 510 -900
20Variability
- Average deviations are always zero so we must
adjust for negative numbers - We can measure variability with standard
deviation - The square root of the average of the squares of
the deviations of the payoffs associated with
each outcome from their expected value.
21Variability
- Standard deviation is a measure of risk
- Measures how variable your payoff will be
- More variability means more risk
- Individuals generally prefer less variability
less risk
22Variability
- The standard deviation is written
23Standard Deviation Example 1
Deviations from Expected Income () Deviations from Expected Income () Deviations from Expected Income () Deviations from Expected Income () Deviations from Expected Income ()
Outcome 1 Deviation Outcome 2 Deviation
Job 1 2000 500 1000 -500
Job 2 1510 10 510 -900
24Standard Deviation Example 1
- Standard deviations of the two jobs are
25Standard Deviation Example 1
- Job 1 has a larger standard deviation and
therefore it is the riskier alternative - The standard deviation also can be used when
there are many outcomes instead of only two.
26Standard Deviation Example 2
- Job 1 is a job in which the income ranges from
1000 to 2000 in increments of 100 that are all
equally likely. - Job 2 is a job in which the income ranges from
1300 to 1700 in increments of 100 that, also,
are all equally likely.
27Outcome Probabilities - Two Jobs
Job 1 has greater spread greater standard
deviation and greater risk than Job 2.
Probability
0.2
0.1
Income
1000
1500
2000
28Decision Making Example 1
- What if the outcome probabilities of two jobs
have unequal probability of outcomes - Job 1 greater spread standard deviation
- Peaked distribution extreme payoffs are less
likely that those in the middle of the
distribution - You will choose job 2 again
29Unequal Probability Outcomes
The distribution of payoffs associated with Job 1
has a greater spread and standard deviation than
those with Job 2.
Probability
0.2
0.1
Income
1000
1500
2000
30Decision Making Example 2
- Suppose we add 100 to each payoff in Job 1 which
makes the expected payoff 1600. - Job 1 expected income 1,600 and a standard
deviation of 500. - Job 2 expected income of 1,500 and a standard
deviation of 99.50
31Decision Making Example 2
- Which job should be chosen?
- Depends on the individual
- Some may be willing to take risk with higher
expected income - Some will prefer less risk even with lower
expected income
32Risk and Crime Deterrence
- Attitudes toward risk affect willingness to break
the law - Suppose a city wants to deter people from double
parking. - Monetary fines may be better than jail time
33Risk and Crime Deterrence
- Costs of apprehending criminals are not zero,
therefore - Fines must be higher than the costs to society
- Probability of apprehension is actually less than
one
34Risk and Crime Deterrence - Example
- Assumptions
- Double-parking saves a person 5 in terms of time
spent searching for a parking space. - The driver is risk neutral.
- Cost of apprehension is zero.
35Risk and Crime Deterrence - Example
- A fine greater than 5.00 would deter the driver
from double parking. - Benefit of double parking (5) is less than the
cost (6.00) equals a net benefit that is
negative. - If the value of double parking is greater than
5.00, then the person would still break the law
36Risk and Crime Deterrence - Example
- The same deterrence effect is obtained by either
- A 50 fine with a .1 probability of being caught
results in an expected penalty of 5 - or
- A 500 fine with a .01 probability of being
caught results in an expected penalty of 5.
37Risk and Crime Deterrence - Example
- Enforcement costs are reduced with high fine and
low probability - Most effective if drivers dont like to take risks
38Preferences Toward Risk
- Can expand evaluation of risky alternative by
considering utility that is obtained by risk - A consumer gets utility from income
- Payoff measured in terms of utility
39Preferences Toward Risk - Example
- A person is earning 15,000 and receiving 13.5
units of utility from the job. - She is considering a new, but risky job.
- 0.50 chance of 30,000
- 0.50 chance of 10,000
40Preferences Toward Risk - Example
- Utility at 30,000 is 18
- Utility at 10,000 is 10
- Must compare utility from the risky job with
current utility of 13.5 - To evaluate the new job, we must calculate the
expected utility of the risky job
41Preferences Toward Risk
- The expected utility of the risky option is the
sum of the utilities associated with all her
possible incomes weighted by the probability that
each income will occur.
E(u) (Prob. of Utility 1) (Utility 1)
(Prob. of Utility 2)(Utility 2)
42Preferences Toward Risk Example
- The expected is
- E(u) (1/2)u(10,000) (1/2)u(30,000)
- 0.5(10) 0.5(18)
- 14
- E(u) of new job is 14 which is greater than the
current utility of 13.5 and therefore preferred.
43Preferences Toward Risk
- People differ in their preference toward risk
- People can be risk averse, risk neutral, or risk
loving.
44Preferences Toward Risk
- Risk Averse
- A person who prefers a certain given income to a
risky income with the same expected value. - The person has a diminishing marginal utility of
income - Most common attitude towards risk
- Ex Market for insurance
45Risk Averse - Example
- A person can have a 20,000 job with 100
probability and receive a utility level of 16. - The person could have a job with a 0.5 chance of
earning 30,000 and a 0.5 chance of earning
10,000.
46Risk Averse Example
- Expected Income of risky job
- E(I) (0.5)(30,000) (0.5)(10,000)
- E(I) 20,000
- Expected Utility of Risky job
- E(u) (0.5)(10) (0.5)(18)
- E(u) 14
47Risk Averse Example
- Expected income from both jobs is the same risk
averse may choose current job - Expected utility is greater for certain job
- Would keep certain job
- Risk averse persons losses (decreased utility)
are more important than risky gains
48Risk Averse
- Can see risk averse choices graphically
- Risky job has expected income 20,000 with
expected utility 14 - Point F
- Certain job has expected income 20,000 with
utility 16 - Point D
49Risk Averse Utility Function
Utility
The consumer is risk averse because she would
prefer a certain income of 20,000 to an
uncertain expected income 20,000
Income (1,000)
50Preferences Toward Risk
- A person is said to be risk neutral if they show
no preference between a certain income, and an
uncertain income with the same expected value. - Constant marginal utility of income
51Risk Neutral
- Expected value for risky option is the same as
utility for certain outcome - E(I) (0.5)(10,000) (0.5)(30,000)
- 20,000
- E(u) (0.5)(6) (0.5)(18) 12
- This is the same as the certain income of 20,000
with utility of 12
52Risk Neutral
Utility
The consumer is risk neutral and is
indifferent between certain events and uncertain
events with the same expected income.
Income (1,000)
0
10
20
30
53Preferences Toward Risk
- A person is said to be risk loving if they show a
preference toward an uncertain income over a
certain income with the same expected value. - Examples Gambling, some criminal activity
- Increasing marginal utility of income
54Risk Loving
- Expected value for risky option point F
- E(I) (0.5)(10,000) (0.5)(30,000)
- 20,000
- E(u) (0.5)(3) (0.5)(18) 10.5
- Certain income is 20,000 with utility of 8
point C - Risky alternative is preferred
55Risk Loving
Utility
The consumer is risk loving because she would
prefer the gamble to a certain income.
Income (1,000)
10
20
30
0
56Preferences Toward Risk
- The risk premium is the maximum amount of money
that a risk-averse person would pay to avoid
taking a risk. - The risk premium depends on the risky
alternatives the person faces.
57Risk Premium Example
- From the previous example
- A person has a .5 probability of earning 30,000
and a .5 probability of earning 10,000 - The expected income is 20,000 with expected
utility of 14.
58Risk Premium Example
- Point F shows the risky scenario the utility of
14 can also be obtained with certain income of
16,000 - This person would be willing to pay up to 4000
(20 16) to avoid the risk of uncertain income. - Can show this graphically by drawing a straight
line between the two points line CF
59Risk Premium Example
Here, the risk premium is 4,000 because a
certain income of 16,000 gives the person the
same expected utility as the uncertain income
with expected value of 20,000.
Utility
Income (1,000)
0
10
16
20
60Risk Aversion and Income
- Variability in potential payoffs increases the
risk premium. - Example
- A job has a .5 probability of paying 40,000
(utility of 20) and a .5 chance of paying 0
(utility of 0).
61Risk Aversion and Income
- Example (cont.)
- The expected income is still 20,000, but the
expected utility falls to 10. - E(u) (0.5)u(0) (0.5)u(40,000)
- 0 .5(20) 10
- The certain income of 20,000 has utility of 16
- If person must take new job, their utility will
fall by 6
62Risk Aversion and Income
- Example (cont.)
- They can get 10 units of utility by taking a
certain job paying 10,000 - The risk premium, therefore, is 10,000 (i.e.
they would be willing to give up 10,000 of the
20,000 and have the same E(u) as the risky job.
63Risk Aversion and Income
- The greater the variability, the more the person
would be willing to pay to avoid the risk and the
larger the risk premium.
64Risk Aversion Indifference Curves
- Can describe a persons risk aversion using
indifference curves that relate expected income
to variability of income (standard deviation) - Since risk is undesirable, greater risk requires
greater expected income to make the person
equally well off - Indifference curves are therefore upward sloping
65Risk Aversion and Indifference Curves
Expected Income
Highly Risk AverseAn increase in
standard deviation requires a large increase in
income to maintain satisfaction.
Standard Deviation of Income
66Risk Aversion and Indifference Curves
Expected Income
Slightly Risk Averse A large increase in
standard deviation requires only a small
increase in income to maintain satisfaction.
Standard Deviation of Income
67Reducing Risk
- Consumers are generally risk averse and therefore
want to reduce risk - Three ways consumers attempt to reduce risk are
- Diversification
- Insurance
- Obtaining more information
68Reducing Risk
- Diversification
- Reducing risk by allocating resources to a
variety of activities whose outcomes are not
closely related. - Example
- Suppose a firm has a choice of selling air
conditioners, heaters, or both. - The probability of it being hot or cold is 0.5.
- How does a firm decide what to sell?
69Income from Sales of Appliances
Hot Weather Cold Weather
Air conditioner sales 30,000 12,000
Heater sales 12,000 30,000
70Diversification Example
- If the firms sells only heaters or air
conditioners their income will be either 12,000
or 30,000. - Their expected income would be
- 1/2(12,000) 1/2(30,000) 21,000
71Diversification Example
- If the firm divides their time evenly between
appliances their air conditioning and heating
sales would be half their original values. - If it were hot, their expected income would be
15,000 from air conditioners and 6,000 from
heaters, or 21,000. - If it were cold, their expected income would be
6,000 from air conditioners and 15,000 from
heaters, or 21,000.
72Diversification Example
- With diversification, expected income is 21,000
with no risk. - Better off diversifying to minimize risk
- Firms can reduce risk by diversifying among a
variety of activities that are not closely related
73Reducing Risk The Stock Market
- If invest all money in one stock, then take on a
lot of risk - If that stock loses value, you lose all your
investment value - Can spread risk out by investing in may different
stocks or investments - Ex Mutual funds
74Reducing Risk Insurance
- Risk averse are willing to pay to avoid risk.
- If the cost of insurance equals the expected
loss, risk averse people will buy enough
insurance to recover fully from a potential
financial loss.
75The Decision to Insure
76Reducing Risk Insurance
- For risk averse consumer, guarantee of same
income regardless of outcome has higher utility
than facing the probability of risk. - Expected utility with insurance is higher than
without
77The Law of Large Numbers
- Insurance companies know that although single
events are random and largely unpredictable, the
average outcome of many similar events can be
predicted. - When insurance companies sell many policies, they
face relatively little risk
78Reducing Risk Actuarially Fair
- Insurance company can be sure total premiums paid
will equal total money paid out - Companies set the premiums so money received will
be enough to pay expected losses.
79Reducing Risk Actuarially Fair
- Some events with very little knowledge of
probability of occurrence such as floods and
earthquakes are no longer insured privately - Cannot calculate true expected values and
expected loses - Governments have had to create insurance for
these types of events - Ex National Flood Insurance Program
80The Value of Information
- Risk often exists because we dont know all the
information surrounding a decision - Because of this, information is valuable and
people are willing to pay for it
81The Value of Information
- The value of complete information
- The difference between the expected value of a
choice with complete information and the expected
value when information is incomplete.
82The Value of Information Example
- Per capita milk consumption has fallen over the
years - The milk producers engaged in market research to
develop new sales strategies to encourage the
consumption of milk.
83The Value of Information Example
- Findings
- Milk demand is seasonal with the greatest demand
in the spring - Price elasticity of demand is negative and small
- Income elasticity is positive and large
84The Value of Information Example
- Milk advertising increases sales most in the
spring. - Allocating advertising based on this information
in New York increased profits by 9 or 14
million. - The cost of the information was relatively low,
while the value was substantial (increased
profits).
85Demand for Risky Assets
- Most individuals are risk averse and yet choose
to invest money in assets that carry some risk. - Why do they do this?
- How do they decide how much risk to bear?
- Must examine the demand for risky assets
86The Demand for Risky Assets
- Assets
- Something that provides a flow of money or
services to its owner. - Ex homes, savings accounts, rental property,
shares of stock - The flow of money or services can be explicit
(dividends) or implicit (capital gain).
87The Demand for Risky Assets
- Capital Gain
- An increase in the value of an asset.
- Capital loss
- A decrease in the value of an asset.
88Risky Riskless Assets
- Risky Asset
- Provides an uncertain flow of money or services
to its owner. - Examples
- apartment rent, capital gains, corporate bonds,
stock prices - Dont know with certainty what will happen to the
value of a stock.
89Risky and Riskless Assets
- Riskless Asset
- Provides a flow of money or services that is
known with certainty. - Examples
- short-term government bonds, short-term
certificates of deposit
90The Demand for Risky Assets
- People hold assets because of the monetary flows
provided - To compare assets, must consider the monetary
flow relative to the assets price (value) - Return on an Asset
- The total monetary flow of an asset, including
capital gains or losses, as a fraction of its
price.
91The Demand for Risky Assets
- Individuals hope to have an asset that has
returns larger than the rate of inflation - Want to have greater purchasing power
- Real Return of an Asset (inflation adjusted)
- The simple (or nominal) return less the rate of
inflation.
92The Demand for Risky Assets
- Since returns are not known with certainty,
investors often make decisions based on expected
returns - Expected Return
- Return that an asset should earn on average
- In the end, the actual return could be higher or
lower than the expected return
93Investments Risk and Return (1926-1999)
94The Demand for Risky Assets
- The higher the return, the greater the risk.
- Investors will choose lower return investments in
order to reduce risk - A risk-averse investor must balance risk relative
to return - Must study the trade-off between return and risk
95Trade-offs Risk and ReturnsExample
- An investor is choosing between T-Bills and
stocks - T-bills riskless
- Stocks risky
- Investor can choose only T-bills, only stocks, or
some combination of both
96Trade-offs Risk and ReturnsExample
- Rf risk free return on T-bill
- Expected return equals actual return on a
riskless asset - Rm the expected return on stocks
- rm the actual returns on stock
- Assume Rm gt Rf or no risk averse investor would
buy the stocks
97Trade-offs Risk and ReturnsExample
- How do we determine the allocation of funds
between the two choices - b fraction of funds placed in stocks
- (1-b) fraction of funds placed in T-bills
- Expected return on portfolio is weighted average
of expected return on the two assets
98Trade-offs Risk and ReturnsExample
- Assume, Rm 12, Rf 4, and b 1/2
99Trade-offs Risk and ReturnsExample
- How risky is the portfolio?
- As stated before, one measure of risk is standard
deviation - Standard deviation of the risky asset, ?m
- Standard deviation of risky portfolio, ?p
- Can show that
100Trade-offs Risk and ReturnsExample
- We still need to figure out how the allocation
between the investment choices - A type of budget line can be constructed
describing the trade-off between risk and
expected return
101Trade-offs Risk and ReturnsExample
- Expected return on the portfolio, rp increases as
the standard deviation, ?p of that return
increases
102Trade-offs Risk and ReturnsExample
- The slope of the line is called the price of risk
- Tells how much extra risk an investor must incur
to enjoy a higher expected return
103Choosing Between Risk Return
- If all funds are invested in T-bills (b0),
expected return is Rf - If all funds are invested in stocks (b1),
expected return is Rm but with standard deviation
of ?m - Funds may be invested between the assets with
expected return between Rf and Rm, with standard
deviation between ?m and 0
104Choosing Between Risk Return
- We can draw indifference curves showing
combinations of risk and return that leave an
investor equally satisfied - Comparing the pay-offs and risk between the two
investment choices and the preferences of the
investor, the optimal portfolio choice can be
determined - Investor wants to maximize utility within the
affordable options
105Choosing Between Risk Return
Expected Return,Rp
U2 is the optimal choice since it gives the
highest return for a given risk and is still
affordable
106Choosing Between Risk Return
- Different investors have different attitudes
toward risk - If we consider a very risk averse investor (A)
- Portfolio will contain mostly T-bills and less in
stock with return slightly larger than Rf - If we consider a riskier investor (B)
- Portfolio will contain mostly stock and less
T-bills with a higher return Rb but with higher
standard deviation
107The Choices of Two Different Investors
Expected Return,Rp
Given the same budget line, investor A chooses
low return- low risk,
while investor B chooses high return-high risk.
108Investing in the Stock Market
- In 1990s many people began investing in the
stock market for the first time - Percent of US families who had directly or
indirectly invested in the stock market - 1989 32
- 1998 49
- Percent with share of wealth in stock market
- 1989 26
- 1998 54
109Investing in the Stock Market
- Why were stock market investments increasing
during the 90s? - Ease of online trading
- Significant increase in stock prices during late
90s - Employers shifting to self-directed retirement
plans - Publicity for do it yourself investing
110Behavioral Economics
- Sometimes individuals behavior contradict basic
assumptions of consumer choice - More information about human behavior might lead
to better understanding - This is the objective of behavioral economics
- Improving understanding of consumer choice by
incorporating more realistic and detailed
assumptions regarding human behavior
111Behavioral Economics
- There are a number of examples of consumer choice
contradictions - You take at trip and stop at a restaurant that
you will most likely never stop at again. You
still think it fair to leave a 15 tip rewarding
the good service. - You choose to buy a lottery ticket even though
the expected value is less than the price of the
ticket
112Behavioral Economics
- Reference Points
- Economists assumes that consumers place a unique
value on the goods/services purchased - Psychologists have found that perceived value can
depend on circumstances - You are able to buy a ticket to the sold out Cher
concert for the published price of 125. You
find out you can sell the ticket for 500 but you
choose not to, even though you would never have
paid more than 250 for the ticket.
113Behavioral Economics
- Reference Points
- The point from which an individual makes a
consumption decision - From the example, owning the Cher ticket is the
reference point - Individuals dislike losing things they own
- They value items more when they own them than
when they do not - Losses are valued more than gains
- Utility loss from selling the ticket is greater
than original utility gain from purchasing it
114Behavioral Economics
- Experimental Economics
- Students were divided into two groups
- Group one was given a mug with market value of
5.00 - Group two received nothing
- Students with mugs were asked how much they would
take to sell the mug back - Lowest price for mugs, on average, was 7.00
115Behavioral Economics
- Experimental Economics (cont.)
- Group without mugs was asked minimum amount of
cash they would except in lieu of the mug - On average willing to accept 3.50 instead of
getting the mug - Group one had reference point of owning the mug
- Group two had reference point of no mug
116Behavioral Economics
- Fairness
- Individuals often make choice because they think
they are fair and appropriate - Charitable giving, tipping in restaurants
- Some consumers will go out of their way to punish
a store they think is unfair in their pricing - Manager might offer higher than market wages to
make for happier working environment or more
productive worker
117Behavioral Economics
- The Laws of Probability
- Individuals dont always evaluate uncertain
events according to the laws of probability - Individuals also dont always maximize expected
utility - Law of small numbers
- Overstate probability of an event when faced with
little information - Ex overstate likelihood they will win the
lottery
118Behavioral Economics
- Theory up to now has explained much but not all
of consumer choice - Although not all of consumer decisions can be
explained by theory up to this point, it helps
understand much of it - Behavioral economics is a developing field to
help explain and elaborate on situations not well
explained by the basic consumer model