Title: Human Capital, Age Structure and Economic Growth Jes
1Human Capital, Age Structure and Economic
Growth Jesús Crespo-Cuaresma and Wolfgang Lutz
World Population Program, International
Institute for Applied Systems Analysis (IIASA)
2Education Matters
- For individual income (Micro)
- For economic development (Macro)
- Whereas at the micro case ... it is established
beyond any reasonable doubt that there are
tangible and measurable returns to investment in
education, such evidence is not as consistent and
forthcoming in the macro literature
(Psacharopoulos and Patrinos 2002) - Findings are dependent on education indicators
chosen (mean years of schooling, for which age
groups, distribution by attainment level) and
quality (consistency across countries and time) - For health/mortality and fertility
- Indirect effects of education on institutions and
good governance
3Measuring Formal Education
- Education Flows Policy variable
- (Gross and Net Enrolment by Age, Repetition
Rates) - Education Stocks - Change very slowly due to
great momentum - Mean years of schooling
- Distribution by highest educational attainment
- Functional literacy (IALS, LAMP)
4(No Transcript)
5(No Transcript)
6(No Transcript)
7Purpose of the Reconstruction
- Assessments of the returns to education at the
aggregate (national) level require empirical
information about the educational status of the
adult population over some time period. -
- 2. This information needs to be consistent in
terms of the definition of educational categories
across countries and over time. - 3. Since the effects of educational attainment
can be expected to differ by age (e.g. the
education of 20-30 year olds being more important
for economic growth than that of 65-75 year
olds) as well as by sex, having full age detail
for men and women can be considered a great
asset. - 4. Only the explicit consideration of distinct
levels of educational attainment allows for the
analysis of the relative importance of primary
versus secondary or tertiary education (and
different mixes of the three) which should be key
to all national and international education
policy plans.
8Previous Work
- Official data from censuses (and some sample
surveys) as collected by UNESCO are only very
fragmentary and scattered over time and countries
and have the problem of changing definitions. - Barro and Lee (1993, 1993 and 2000) undertook the
ambitious effort to complement these data with
the somewhat more consistent time series of
national school enrollment data at different
levels using perpetual inventory methods. This
resulted in a widely used data set that gives
mean years of schooling of the entire adult
population 15 and 25 (by sex but without age
detail) for 107 countries for 1960 to 2000. - Similar independent efforts have since been made
by Kyriacou (1991), Lau, Jamison and Louat
(1991), Lau, Bhalla and Louat (1991), Nehru,
Swanson and Dubey (1995), De la Fuente and
Domenech (2001) and by Cohen and Soto (2001)
which in many cases result in quite different
estimates of mean years of schooling. - None of these reconstruction efforts gives the
desirable age detail combined with the
distribution over different educational
attainment groups and accounts for the fact that
mortality differs by education.
9Our method Demographic multi-state back
projections from 2000
- We need only one reliable data point for each
country (typically around the year 2000) which
gives the total population by sex, 5-year age
groups and the four attainment categories based
on ISCED no education, primary, secondary and
tertiary. - We use population age structures as estimated by
the UN Population Division in five year intervals
for all countries in the world since 1950. - Taking these UN estimates as a basis, our
reconstruction effort is reduced to estimating
the proportions in each of the four education
categories for each 5-year age group of men and
women.
10Our four education categories for 2000based on
ISCED, from censuses and surveys (mostly DHS)
- No education Never been to school
- Primary Some primary, complete primary,
incomplete lower secondary - Secondary Completed lower secondary to
incomplete first level of tertiary - Tertiary Completed first level of tertiary or
higher.
11(No Transcript)
12(No Transcript)
13(No Transcript)
14(No Transcript)
15Sample Table
16(No Transcript)
17(No Transcript)
18(No Transcript)
19(No Transcript)
20When moving back along cohort lines in 5-year
intervals we take advantage of the demographic
identityP(x,t,) P(x5,t5) Deaths /-
Migrants P(x,t,e) P(x5,t5,e) Deaths (,,e)
/- Migrants (,,e) /- EducTransitions (x to
x5, t to t5,e)Necessary Assumptions
- Education differentials in mortality and
migration - Dealing with the open interval in highest age
group - Age of transition to higher educational
categories
21Differential Mortality by Education
- We defined mortality differentials in terms of
life expectancy at age 15 (child mortality is
more a function of parents education). - We carried out numerous studies for countries for
which two reliable subsequent censuses (or public
use samples of them) were available to assess
differential mortality (combined with migration)
along cohort lines. - Despite all differentials among countries a
rather general pattern appeared The
differentials between the lower categories are
smaller than to the higher. - Our choice No education Primary 1 year
difference - Primary Secondary 2 years difference
- Secondary Tertiary 2 years difference
22Differential Mortality by Education
23Validation of Results(April October 2006)
- The first reconstruction results have been
checked against much available historical
evidence on educational attainment distributions,
in particular - UIS Attainment Data Set
- Earlier DHS, WFS or other surveys
- OECD and Eurostat education data base
- Numerous individual national statistical agencies
(in personal communication) - Whenever there was a significant discrepancy, we
tried to identify the reason Was it a problem
with our assumptions (mostly migration) or a
problem with the other data (mostly definition of
categories or representativeness of survey) and
made appropriate adjustments in our data, if
necessary.
24Exploiting the age dimension of human capital
1) How does the new data compare to the Barro-Lee
dataset in terms of correlation with growth?
(Sala-i-Martin, 1997)2) Do differences in
cohort education help us better explain
differences in income per capita? (Hall and
Jones, 1998)3) What is the role of age-specific
human capital in technology adoption and growth?
(Benhabib and Spiegel, 1994)
25Growth and education a robustness exercise
Are changes in educational attainment a robust
determinant of growth?A stylised growth
regressionHow does the sign, size and
significance of b depend on the set of
conditioning variables?
26Growth and education a robustness exercise
- IIASA/VID dataset versus Barro-Lee- 59
other variables in the pool of Z-variables-
Initial GDP per capita, primary school enrolment
and life expectancy as fixed variables
27Unweighted results
28Weighted results
29The contribution of human capital to income
differences
where f() is a piecewise linear
function based on average returns to schooling
worldwide.
30Income decomposition
31Human capital and technology adoption
32Human capital and technology adoption
33Human capital and technology adoption
34Conclusions
Exploiting the age structure of human capital-
we obtain variables that correlate robustly with
economic growth,- we are better able to explain
differences in income per capita across
countries,- we gain new insights to the nature
of the interaction between education and
technology adoption.
35Paths of ongoing and further research
- Exploiting the age structure of human capital in
the time dimension panel data analysis.-
Interaction between gender and education (If you
educate a man, you educate a person, if you
educate a woman you educate a family, and a whole
nation)- Economic growth projections using
age-structure human capital to improve
reliability of forecasts.