What Should Monetary Policy Have Been After the Bubble - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

1 / 16
About This Presentation
Title:

What Should Monetary Policy Have Been After the Bubble

Description:

The Stock Market Since 1995 ... in stock market values since 2000 cannot be attributed to bad news about macro productivity... – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:27
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 17
Provided by: tri5349
Category:

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: What Should Monetary Policy Have Been After the Bubble


1
What Should Monetary Policy Have Been After the
Bubble?
  • October 2004
  • J. Bradford DeLong
  • U.C. Berkeley
  • PRELIMINARY AND INCOMPLETE

2
The Stock Market Since 1995
  • The steep decline in stock market values since
    2000 cannot be attributed to bad news about macro
    productivity
  • It cannot be attributed to bad news about macro
    long-run real interest rates
  • It did carry with it information about the likely
    willingness of businesses to keep on investing at
    their late-1990s pace

3
Alan Greenspans Reaction
  • The FOMCs reaction to the crash of the NASDAQ
    (and to 911) was a very rapid reduction in the
    Federal Funds rate.
  • A reduction that essentially left the FOMC out of
    ammunition (save for open-mouth operations) by
    the middle of 2003.
  • A reduction that has only recently been moderated.

4
Four Views of the FOMCs Actions
  • The production view the FOMC went a bit too far
  • The unemployment rate view the FOMC was prudent
  • The payroll employment view the FOMC was not
    aggressive enough
  • Let me briefly run through these
  • But I want to concentrate on a fourth view
  • The housing bubble view

5
The Inflation View
  • Inflation was high enough at the end of the
    decade for the Federal Reserve to welcome the end
    of the boom
  • Inflation was low enough in 2002 for the FOMC to
    begin to fear deflation
  • The inflation view suggests that if the FOMC
    moved too far, it did not take many extra steps

6
The Real Production View
  • There was a sharp growth slowdown, but barely a
    recession.
  • The past two years have seen American real GDP
    grow at a healthy pace.
  • If you believe that the bubble was leading to
    overinvestment because it was transmitting
    false price information, then perhaps the FOMC
    moved too far

7
The U.S. Recovery Productivity
  • Productivity growth averaged 1.2 per year from
    1973-1995.
  • Productivity growth averaged 2.3 per year from
    1995-2001.
  • Productivity growth has averaged 4.2 per year
    since the start of 2001.
  • This extraordinary burst of productivity growth
    accounts for why employment yardsticks give
    different assessments of monetary policy than do
    output yardsticks

8
The Unemployment Rate View
  • If you believe the decline in the labor force
    share of the adult population is a structural
    phenomenon, then the FOMC looks just right
  • The unemployment rate did not rise very far
  • And it has come down significantly since early
    2003

9
The Employment View
  • Payroll employment still well below business
    cycle peak.
  • Assume (for no good reason) last peak was 1.5
    million above full employment population
    growth since leaves the U.S. today some 4.9
    million below full employment.
  • Implication the FOMCs monetary policy was in
    some sense not loose enough in the early 1990s

10
The Housing Price View
  • OFHEOs house price indexes continue to rise
    through the recession and recovery
  • Stock market decline a business phenomenon only
  • Caveat housing is a long-duration, only partly
    reproducible asset
  • If not reproducible, duration of 40?
  • Argument that the FOMCs loose monetary policy
    has set off a housing bubble (or a housing plus
    bond market bubble)

11
The View Illustrated I Dean Baker
  • Survivors of the recent stock market crash should
    rightly be worried that a sharp drop in housing
    prices could deliver a second major blow to their
    retirement dreams. The fact that there has been
    an unprecedented run-up in home prices over the
    last eight years creates the possibility for an
    unprecedented decline in the years ahead - just
    as the spurt in the NASDAQ at the end of the
    nineties created the basis for its plunge after
    March of 2000.
  • The basic facts are striking. According to the
    government's House Price Index (HPI), the
    increase in the sale price of an average house
    has exceeded the overall rate of inflation by
    more than 40 percentage points over the last
    eight years.
  • The fact that people are borrowing against their
    homes at a rapid rate (more than 750 billion in
    2003) is more evidence of an unsustainable
    bubble. The ratio of mortgage debt to home equity
    is at record highs but the nation's
    demographics (with the baby boomers approaching
    retirement) suggest that many homeowners should
    have largely paid off their mortgages.
  • The market is responding to the housing bubble
    exactly as economic theory would predict. New
    homes are being built at record rate, far faster
    than can be supported by population and income
    growth. At the moment, this has mostly affected
    the rental market, leading to record vacancy
    rates and falling rental prices.
  • The end result will be a loss of 2 to 3
    trillion in housing wealth, and a downturn that
    is even worse than the fallout from the stock
    market crash.

12
The View Illustrated II Michael Mussa
  • The very low level of policy interest rates is an
    imbalance (relative to normal conditions) that
    reflects exceptionally easy monetary policies to
    combat economic weakness. This policy imbalance
    poses an important challenge for the future
    conduct of monetary policy.
  • Situations of low policy interest rates and low
    inflation tend to be associated with high
    valuations of equities, real estate, and
    long-term bonds, which can become fertile ground
    for large, unsustainable increases in asset
    prices.
  • If monetary policy is tightened too much too soon
    (perhaps because of worries about unsustainable
    increases in asset prices), the result can be an
    unnecessary asset market crunch and economic
    slowdown, and monetary policy may have relatively
    little room to ease in order to counteract this
    outcome.
  • If monetary policy remains too easy for too long
    (perhaps because subdued general price inflation
    gives no clear signal of the need for monetary
    tightening), then large asset price anomalies may
    develop before corrective action is taken.
  • The monetary authority would then confront the
    grim choice of trying to keep an unsustainable
    asset price bubble alive or trying to combat the
    collapse of such a bubble without a great deal of
    room for monetary easing.
  • Interest rate spreads for emerging market
    borrowers have contracted substantially and flows
    of new credit have increased. The boom in
    emerging market credit has not yet reached the
    frenzy of the first half of 1997, but it is
    headed in that direction. By 2005 or 2006,
    however, either upward movements in industrial
    country interest rates or deterioration of market
    perceptions of the economic and financial
    stability of some emerging market countries could
    trigger another round of crises.

13
The View Illustrated III Pam Woodall
  • MOST American economists will tell you that the
    Federal Reserve did a brilliant job in preventing
    a deeper and longer recession after the
    stockmarket bubble burst
  • The gap between income and spending has been
    financed by saving less and by borrowing. Thanks
    to low interest rates the price of assets,
    especially homes, has risen steeply, which has
    made households feel richer and encouraged them
    to spend
  • The Fed and others like to explain that there is
    no need to fret about the recent build-up of debt
    because it has been matched by big gains in the
    value of household assets such as shares and
    homes. The snag is that rising home prices do
    not increase real wealth for society as a whole.
    For a given housing stock, when prices rise, the
    capital gain to home-owners is offset by the
    increased future living costs of non-home-owners
  • Moreover, the prices of assets can fall. Debts,
    on the other hand, are fixed in value. The
    housing stock has been turned into a gigantic
    cash machine. In the long run, the only way to
    create genuine wealth is to consume less than
    your income (ie, save), and invest in real
    income-creating assets. But America and some
    other economies have been enjoying a very
    different sort of wealth creation central banks
    are, in effect, printing wealth by running lax
    monetary policies. Illusory paper wealth is
    boosting consumption at the expense of saving.
    America's net national saving rate, the share of
    income that Americans are putting aside for their
    future, has fallen to a record low, just when
    they should be saving more to prepare for an
    ageing society
  • Households expectations of continuing big gains
    in the price of houses and shares are highly
    unlikely to be met. The average ratio of house
    prices to incomes is already at a record level
    (see chart 13), yet people are buying homes in
    the unrealistic hope of large future price rises.
    That is the definition of a bubble. When two
    American economists, Robert Shiller and Karl
    Case, surveyed home-buyers in Los Angeles,
    Boston, San Francisco and Milwaukee last year,
    the respondents said they expected the value of
    their homes to rise at an annual average rate of
    12-16 over the next ten years
  • In recent months adjustable-rate mortgages have
    accounted for half of all new mortgages in
    America
  • The longer that home prices go on rising, the
    steeper their eventual decline will be

14
The View Summarized
  • The FOMCs rapid interest rate reductions did
    indeed keep the stock market decline from having
    much larger macroeconomic effects
  • Lower interest rates supported equity values and
    prevented credit-channel problem from reducing
    production.
  • Lower interest rates on the money side made
    durable investments--especially in residential
    construction--more attractive.
  • Lower interest rates that boosted home values
    induced waves of refinancing and expanded
    consumer spending.
  • The FOMCs twist of the intertemporal relative
    price structure did indeed keep the collapse of
    the NASDAQ bubble from causing an economic
    depression.
  • But the FOMCs twist of the intertemporal
    relative price structure has now created a bigger
    problem it has created a housing (and a bond
    market?) bubble
  • Lower interest rates induced price runups
  • Price runups attracted positive-feedback traders.
  • High positive-feedback trading pushed prices up
    even more.
  • Eventually this housing (and bond?) bubble will
    pop--and when it does, we will be in
    significantly worse shape than we would have been
    had the FOMC taken preemptive action in 1998-2000
    to prevent the stock market bubble from gathering
    force.

15
The View Modeled?
  • This view has many strong adherents among people
    writing about the economy--and making
    investments--outside of economics departments.
  • Mussa (2004) is the closest thing I can find
    within the academic economics community.
  • This view is not one we find easy to model
  • Widespread irrationality
  • Lack of the short interest that should push
    prices to reflect consensus or average
    expectations
  • Lots of 50 bills left on the sidewalk
  • I think we need to figure out how to model things
    like this if we are to participate in the
    discussion
  • If we dont succeed in modeling it, we cannot
    even say that it is (as I think it is) an
    unlikely scenario.

16
What Would a Model Look Like?
  • Bernanke-Gertler credit channel
  • Two major assets
  • Business equities (which serve as effective
    collateral to keep the credit channel from
    gumming up business loans on the
    business-investment side)
  • Consumer houses (which serve as effective
    collateral to keep the credit channel from
    gumming up consumer loans on the
    consumption-spending side)
  • Two asset markets linked because valuations are
    both affected by monetary policy
  • A bad shock to business equity values calls forth
    interest rate reductions to keep credit-channel
    problems from developing on the
    business-investment side
  • But then induces a behavioral-finance
    phenomenon--a lot of households buying bigger
    houses and then leveraging themselves up as
    housing prices rise
  • Followed (someday) by a pop of the bubble and
    credit-channel problems on the consumption-spendin
    g side
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)
About PowerShow.com