Title: Examining gender differences in asset accumulation in transition economies
1Examining gender differences in asset
accumulation in transition economies
- Agnes Quisumbing
- International Food Policy Research Institute
- Workshop on
- "Sharing the Growth Dividend Women in the ECA
Region - The World Bank
2Why study asset accumulation?
- Assets represent a resource that generates value
or returns over time. - Assets can be used to obtain access to other
markets, e.g. credit markets - Asset dynamics in response to shocks can help us
understand the evolution of poverty over time - Inequality in the distribution of assets may
result in differences in well-being over time
3Why study gender differences in asset
accumulation?
- If men and women have differential access or
control over assets, time path of returns could
be quite different for men and women - If women do not have assets that are acceptable
as collateral, they could be disadvantaged in
terms of access to credit markets - Asset dynamics of men and women could be quite
different if womens assets are first to be
disposed of in times of crises - Different patterns of asset holdings of men and
women, in addition to gender differences in
levels of asset ownership, could result in gender
gaps in well-being over time
4Some interesting complications of studying asset
accumulation in the ECA region
- Ownership of productive assets such as land and
machinery generally skewed towards men, while
human capital is more equally divided - Transition countries have implemented the
greatest land redistribution program in recent
history as well as the largest enterprise
privatization program - We know very little about whether
redistribution/privatization was equitable from a
gender perspective - We probably do not have gender-disaggregated
baseline information on asset ownership
post-privatization, not to mention
pre-privatization - A combination of retrospective data, plus
historical analysis of reform implementation, may
help establish this baseline
5Pre-transition property rights and production
organization (Swinnen 2001)
- Widespread collectivization of agriculture began
in 1928 in the FSU and in 1948 in Central
European countries and the Baltics - Objective was to pool peasant farms into
large-scale collective farms, and then to
nationalize the land and convert collectives into
even larger state farms or agro-industrial
complexes. - However collectivization was implemented
differently in each country, reflecting different
stages of state control, resulting in a mixture
of property rights regimes - We probably do not know anything about the gender
distribution of land rights pre-collectivization.
Is it feasible to get this data at the
individual level? Maybe not, given the time that
has elapsed. - Historical records might give information on
whether peasant farms were registered under the
husbands name alone, or jointly - Is this important to know? Judgment call.
6Post-communist agricultural privatization and
land reform
- Not surprisingly, land reforms differed quite
widely across countries, even if restitution of
farmland to former owners is the most important
process, in terms of TAL - Typically, reform laws specify that former owners
are restituted land in historical boundaries, if
possible, or receive property rights to a plot of
comparable size and quality - In practice, there have been differences in the
way collective and state farmland have been
restituted (see next slide), but again, it is not
clear whether restitution has been
gender-equitable, or simply restored former
ownership system
7Selected land reform procedures in Central and
Eastern European countries
Collective farmland Collective farmland State farmland State farmland
Procedure of TAL Procedure of TAL
Albania Distribution (physical) 76 Distribution (physical) 24
Bulgaria Restitution 72 Miscellaneous 9
Czech Rep Restitution 61 Sale (leasing) 25
Hungary Restitution distribution (phys) sale for compensation bonds 70 Sale for compensation bonds sale (leasing) 12
Poland ___ 4 Sale (leasing) 19
Russia Distribution in shares 40 Distribution in shares 58
Source Swinnen 2001
8Some possibilities at getting at this problem
through a household survey
- Ask households about what they received or owned
post-privatization, and ask about individual
ownership of each type of asset (as in
individuals within the household) - Ask households to complete an asset accumulation
record for important types of assets (land,
agricultural assets, business assets), with dates
that each asset was acquired or disposed of - Obtain information on mode of acquisition
- Obtain information on who within the household
had control of the asset (use individual ID) - Using this information, generate
gender-disaggregated time paths of asset
accumulation
9Caveats
- If you really want to get at intrahousehold asset
control, this is NOT the same as classifying the
household as male- or female-headed - Nevertheless, looking at incidence of female
headship in the ECA region might help identify
vulnerable households, and if there are major
differences in asset ownership in male vs.
female-headed households, this could be policy
relevant
10There is a precedent for this type of work, from
a very different setting
- IFPRIs work on the evolution of customary land
tenure systems towards individualized land rights
in Ghana and Sumatra faced very similar
questionshow to track evolution of land rights
from customary (collective?) control to
individual control - Study methodology involved two types of surveys
(1) extensive survey of communities, to find out
local norms regarding land rights and (2)
intensive survey of households to find out how
these land rights varied across households, and
within households - For the intensive survey, information on various
outcome indicators also collected and analyzed
11Customary land tenure and tree resource
management in Ghana and Sumatra
(Quisumbing and Otsuka, with Payongayong, Aidoo,
and Suyanto, 2001)
12Designing a module to look at land use Ghana
and Sumatra
- Ghana uterine matrilineal system men used to
grow tree crops women grew food crops but food
crops actually intercropped with cocoa, so women
contributed labor to keeping cocoa fields clean
while cocoa trees are young - Plots have their own plot managers and even field
managers (separate crop fields within plots) - The way land is acquired and from whom determines
property rights on land
- Sumatra Asian matrilineal system women
inherit paddy land men cultivate tree crop area
tree crops planted on land with very different
land rightsagroforestry land (almost private
property rights after trees planted) bush-fallow
land (becoming converted to private property) - The way land is used eventually determines
property rights (clearing and tree-planting on
formerly communal land, e.g. bush-fallow)
13Ghana land use module
- Emphasis in Ghana modules for each plot
- Mode of land acquisition
- Who acquired the land
- From whom
- Rights on the land
- Who is the plot manager
- Note it is not enough to ask whether the
household is male- or female-headed. Level of
gender disaggregation goes down to the plot level.
14Sumatra land use module
- Emphasis in Sumatra
- How land is used
- Mode of land acquisition
- Who acquired the land
- From whom
- Whether land can be inherited
- age to sons and daughters
- Again, it is not enough to ask whether the
household is male- or female-headed. Level of
gender disaggregation goes down to the plot
level.
15- Surely, if these data could be collected in Ghana
and Sumatra, they can be collected in ECA, which
has more highly developed statistical systems!
16What are the consequences of gender inequality in
asset ownership, post-privatization?
- We do not know.
- We cannot immediately conclude that gender
inequality in distribution of agricultural assets
is bad for women, unless we also know how human
capital assets are distributed (probably, more
equally) and what are the gender differences in
employment in agriculture, non-agriculture, and
in self-employment
17Examining the consequences of asset inequality
across different types of assets
- In the Philippines, sons inherit land and most
agricultural assets, and daughters obtain an
education. - Daughters more likely to work in nonagricultural
employment - Lifetime incomes are higher under this
distribution of physical and human capital, than
if both land and education were to be equalized
across sons and daughters - (Estudillo, Quisumbing, and Otsuka 2001)
18- Thus, it is important to look at a range of
assets, and the long-term incomes that can be
generated from this portfolio of assets, rather
than focus on one type of asset alone. - As per capita incomes increase, returns from
human capital may become more important than
returns from physical capital