Title: Wholesale Bargaining: Models and Antitrust Implications
1Wholesale Bargaining Models and Antitrust
Implications
- Joshua Gans
- Melbourne Business School
- University of Melbourne
2Background Papers
- Joint work with Catherine de Fontenay
- RAND Journal of Economics, 2005
- Review of Network Economics, 2005
- IJIO, 2004
- Bilateral Bargaining with Externalities
- Applications
- Concentration Measures and Vertical Market
Structure (JLE forthcoming) - Markets for Competitive Advantage (w/ Michael
Ryall) - Network Bargaining (Martin Byford)
3Wholesale Markets
- Posted prices
- Spengler (JPE) double marginalisation
- Salinger (QJE) successive Cournot oligopoly
- Take it or leave it offers
- Hart and Tirole (1990)
- OBrien and Shaffer (1992)
- McAfee and Schwartz (1994)
- Segal (1999)
- Marx and Shaffer (2004)
- Bargaining
- Inderst and Wey (2003)
- OBrien and Shaffer (2004)
- Segal and Whinston (2001)
- Stole and Zwiebel (1996)
- Grossman-Hart-Moore
- MacDonald and Ryall (2004)
- Brandenberger and Stuart (2006)
4Antitrust Issues Traditional Views
- How do we analyse competition between sellers
into a wholesale market? - Same as any horizontal market
- Versus countervailing power from buyers
- How do we analyse vertical restrictions?
- Perfect efficient contracting vertical practices
only chosen for efficiency reasons - Versus firms with market power who can use
practices to extract rents
5New Results
- Changes in competition (e.g., concentration) in
upstream markets have a different impact on final
consumers than changes in downstream markets - Vertical practices can have anti-competitive
effects and result in a redistribution of rents - Can use quantitative bargaining models to analyse
trade-offs
6Outline
- Our Bargaining Model and Result
- Treatment of Upstream Competition
- Analysis of Vertical Integration
- Future Directions
7The Research Goal for Strategy
Surplus Generated
- Environmental Characteristics
- Consumer demand
- Resource availability
- Production technology
- Bargaining power
Payoffs to owners of factors of production
Surplus Division
Given environmental characteristics, what are the
expected payoffs to factor owners? That is, what
determines appropriability.
8Cooperative Bargaining Theory
- The Benefits
- Relates environmental characteristics to surplus
division - Easy to compute
- E.g., Myerson-Shapley value is weighted sum of
coalitional values
- The Problems
- Presumption that coalitions operate to maximise
surplus - Requires observable and verifiable actions
- Coalitional externalities are usually assumed
away - If considered, impact on division only (Myerson)
9Non-Cooperative Bargaining Theory
- Benefit Robust predictions in the bilateral case
- Nash bargaining
- Rubinstein and Binmore-Rubinstein-Wolinsky
- Problem Bilateral case in isolation cannot deal
with - externalities
- coalitional formation
D1
U1
10We need a theory that can deal with this
- Competitive Externalities
- Ds and Us may be competing firms
- Cant negotiate
- Bilateral Contracts
- Ds and Us cannot necessarily observe supply terms
of others - Connectedness does not necessarily imply surplus
maximisation
D1
D2
UA
UB
while being tractable and intuitive.
11Our Approach
- Bilaterality
- Assumes that there are no actions that can be
observed beyond a negotiating pair - Potential for inefficient outcomes
- Non-cooperative bargaining
- Does not presume surplus maximisation
- Looks for an equilibrium set of agreements
12Our Results
- In a non-cooperative model of a sequence of
bilateral negotiations - There exists a Perfect Bayesian Equilibrium
whereby - Coalitional surplus is generated by a Nash
equilibrium outcome in pairwise surplus
maximisation - Division is based on the weighted sum of
coalitional surpluses - We produce a cooperative division of a
non-cooperative surplus - Strict generalisation of cooperative bargaining
solutions - Collapses to known values as externalities are
removed - Non-cooperative justification for cooperative
outcomes
13Some Notation
- Actions
- qij is the input quantity purchased by Di from Uj
- tij is the transfer from Di to Uj
- (A1) Can only observe actions and transfers you
are a party to (e.g., UB and D2 cannot observe
q11 or t11) - Primitive Payoffs
- Di p(qiAqiB, q-iAq-iB)ti1ti2
- Uj t1j t2j c(q1jq2j)
- Usual concavity assumptions on p(.) and c(.)
D1
D2
UA
UB
14Network State
- Network
- Bilateral links form a graph of relationships
denoted by K - Initial state K (1A,1B,2A,2B)
- If a pair suffer a breakdown (e.g., D1 and UA),
the new network is created - New state K (1B,2A,2B)
- (A2) The network state (K) is publicly observed
15Possible Contracts
- Bilaterality
- As terms of other pairs are unobserved by at
least one member of a pair, supply terms cannot
be made contingent upon other supply contract
terms - Network Observability
- As the network state is publicly observed supply
terms can be made contingent on the network state - Example
- q11(1A,1B,2A,2B) 3 and t11(1A,1B,2A,2B) 2 and
q11(1A, 2A,2B) 4 and t11(1A, 2A,2B) 5 and
so on.
16Extensive Form
- Fix an order of pairs (in this case 4)
- Precise order will not matter for equilibrium we
focus on - Each pair negotiates in turn
- Randomly select Di or Uj
- That agent, say Di, makes an offer qij(K),
tij(K) for all possible K including Di and Uj. - If Uj accepts, the offer is fixed and move to
next pair - If Uj rejects,
- With probability, 1-s, negotiations end and
bargaining recommences over the new network K
ij. - Otherwise negotiations continue with Uj making an
offer to Di. - Binmore-Rubinstein-Wolinsky bilateral game
embedded in a sequence of interrelated
negotiations - Examine outcomes as s goes to 1.
17Beliefs
- Game of incomplete information
- Need to impose some structure on out of
equilibrium beliefs - Issue in vertical contracting (McAfee and
Schwartz Segal) in that one party knows what
contracts have been signed with others and
offer/acceptance choices may signal those
outcomes - Simple approach impose passive beliefs
- Let be the set of
equilibrium agreements - When i receives an offer from j of
or - i does not revise its beliefs about any other
outcome of the game
18Equilibrium Outcomes Actions
- Bilateral Efficiency
- A set of actions satisfied bilateral efficiency
if for all ij in K, - Suppose that all agents hold passive beliefs.
Then, as s approaches 1, in any Perfect Bayesian
equilibrium, each qij(K) is bilaterally efficient
(given K).
19Equilibrium Outcomes Actions
- Suppose that all agents hold passive beliefs.
Then, as s approaches 1, in any Perfect Bayesian
equilibrium, each qij(K) is bilaterally efficient
(given K). - Intuition
- Negotiation order 1A,1B,2A,2B and suppose that
1A and 1B have agreed to the equilibrium actions - If 2A agree to the equilibrium action, 2B
negotiate and as this is the last negotiation, it
is equivalent to a BRW case so they choose the
bilaterally efficient outcome - If 2A agree to something else, D2 will know this
but UB wont - UB will base offers and acceptances on assumption
that 2A have agreed to the equilibrium outcome
(given passive beliefs) - D2 will base offers and acceptances on the actual
2A agreement. Indeed, D2 will be able to offer
(and have accepted) something different to the
equilibrium outcome - Given this, will 2A agree to something else?
- D2 will anticipate the changed outcome in
negotiations with UB - Under passive beliefs, UA will not anticipate
this changed outcome (so its offers dont change) - D2 will make an offer based on
- By the envelope theorem on q2B, this involves a
bilaterally efficient choice of q2A.
20Equilibrium Outcomes Payoffs
- Result As s approaches 1, there exists a perfect
Bayesian outcome where agents receive - This is each agents Myerson-Shapley value over
the bilaterally efficient surplus in each
network.
21Remarks
- Stole and Zwiebel adopt a similar approach in
proving their non-cooperative game yields a
Shapley value - Make mistake do not specify belief structure
- Our most general statement shows that the
solution concept is a graph-restricted Myerson
value in partition function space. - The symmetry in the buyer-seller network case
masks some additional difficulties in the general
case - There is some indeterminacy in the complete graph
case - The cooperative game solution concept has never
been stated before - Nor has it been related to component balance and
fair allocation - So our proof does cooperative game theory before
getting to the steps before
22Ultimate Solution
- where
- N is the set of agents
- P is a partition over the set of agents with
cardinality p - PN is the set of all partitions of N
- L is the initial network (i.e., initial set of
bilateral links) - LP is the initial network with links severed
between partitions defined by P.
23Additional Results
- (No component externalities) Suppose that
primitive payoffs are independent of actions
taken by agents not linked the agent - Obtain the Myerson value over a bilaterally
efficient surplus. - (No non-pecuniary externalities) Suppose that the
primitive payoffs are independent of the actions
the agent cannot observe - Obtain the Myerson value.
- If agreements are non-binding and subject to
renegotiation, the results hold.
24Computability
m buyers
Bilaterally efficient surplus with m-s buyers
supplied by both suppliers
S1
S2
Bilaterally efficient surplus if s buyers are
supplied only by S1 and h are supplied only by S2
25Upstream Competition
- Why upstream competition should be treated
differently when there is wholesale bargaining?
262 x 2 Structure (NI)
27Model Structure Notation
- 2 upstream 2 downstream assets each with an
associated manager (necessary for the asset to be
productive) integration changes ownership but
not need to use manager - Uj can produce input quantities, q1j q2j to D1
and D2 at cost, cj(q1j, q2j) quasi-convex - D1 earns (gross) profits of p1(q1A,q1Bq2A,q2B)
concave in (q1A,q1B) and non-increasing in
(q2A,q2B). - Industry profit outcomes
28Upstream Merger
29Incentives to Merge
- Upstream firms jointly gain
- One third of the profits from a UB Monopoly
- Intuition the possibility that a breakdown could
generate this was used by downstream firms as
leverage on the other upstream firm - Downstream firms jointly lose this
- Face higher transfers
30Impact on Efficiency
- Bilateral negotiations for upstream supply under
upstream competition - Bilateral negotiations for upstream supply under
upstream monopoly - No difference in outcomes so no impact on
efficiency
31Upstream Competition
- Changes to upstream competition have a different
impact to changes in downstream competition - Fragmentation amongst downstream firms drives
impact on consumers, input and output choices. It
constrains upstream market power. - Extreme permit upstream mergers when there is no
vertical integration - Leads to additional upstream investment (maybe
over-investment) - May lead to reduced downstream entry
32Vertical Integration
- What is the competitive impact of vertical
integration?
33Effect of Integration
BI
FI
34Will D1 and UA profit from VI?
UC
UM
FI
BI
35Comparisons
- FI versus BI
- UC versus UM
- As downstream products become more
differentiated, strategic VI is more likely under
upstream competition than upstream monopoly
36Impact on Efficiency
- Bilateral negotiations for upstream supply under
NI - Bilateral negotiations for upstream supply under
VI - Incentive to raise rivals costs
37VI and Foreclosure
- Upstream competition
- With homogenous inputs (and some symmetry), VI
does not change efficiency - Upstream monopoly
- VI leads to industry profit maximisation (with
symmetry and substitutability) D2 is not
supplied any inputs - Under FI, D2 still receives a payoff of
- Technical foreclosure but downstream firm still
valuable in disciplining internal negotiations
38An Outsourcing Issue
- Outsourcing (make vs buy) decision
- Typically assumes new function or no sunk
assets in the industry - Major outsourcing decisions typically involve
existing assets that must be divested or scrapped - Dilemma
- If outsource to existing firm, vulnerable to lack
of upstream competition in the future (lack of
long-term contracts). - If create new independent supplier, assets
divested may not be worth as much. - Examples GE to Matsushita vs Samsung Motorola
to BenQ.
39Outsourcing Dilemma
UA
UB
UA-UB
or
?
D1
D2
D1
D2
Create UA or sell assets to UB? Integration
implies common ownership of assets Assume that D1
and D2 do not compete and fixed gain from
outsourcing, D
40Results
- D1 chooses to outsource to UB over an independent
firm if - Established outsourcing reduces D1s profits by
- But increases total upstream profits (UA and UB)
by - Always occurs
- Choose the option that harms D2 the most that is
where the rents are coming from
41Summary
- Outsourcing and upstream competition
- Standard view more likely to outsource when
upstream markets are competitive - Here outsourcing incentives stronger if can
preserve or establish upstream market power - Outsourcing and competitive advantage
- Standard view outsourcing gives comp adv
- Here outsourcing more desirable if harms other
downstream firms but no comp adv as supply on
equal terms
42Quantitative Evaluation
- How can mergers impacting on vertical market
structure be evaluated?
43Wholesale Bargaining
- N firms indexed by i
- Each may operate in an upstream and/or downstream
segment - si downstream share
- si upstream share
- Perfect substitutes (downstream)
- Market demand P(Q)
- Costs upstream (Ci(.)), downstream (ci(.))
44Lerner Index for Vertical Chain
- Negotiations between i and j
45Vertical HHI
- The average Lerner index is
- If there is a preference for internal supply,
46Properties
- Ranges between 0 (perfect competition) and 10,000
(downstream monopoly) - Collapses to HHI (Downstream) when all downstream
firms are net buyers of inputs or non-integrated - If there is integration then VHHI gt HHI
- Upstream concentration not relevant
- Non-integrated upstream mergers do not change
VHHI - Only look upstream if merger involves a net
supplier
47Some Examples
- Example 1
- 4 equal sized upstream firms and 10 equal sized
downstream ones - Up HHI 2500 Down-HHI 1000 VHHI
- Vertical merger leaves HHIs unchanged (no
concern) but raises VHHI to 1150 (potential
concern) - Example 2
- 8 downstream firms with 10 share and a 9th with
20 share - If vertical merger involves large firm then HHI
does not change but VHHI goes from 1300 to 1400
(no concern) despite higher concentration.
48Approach 2 Successive Oligopoly
- Firms post unit prices in wholesale market
- With linear demand and costs (and homogenous
inputs) - Like bilateral bargaining but with additional
distortions (that can be removed by vertical
integration)
49Application Exxon-Mobil in California
50Concentration Measures
51Future Directions
- Other Vertical Practices
- Exclusive dealing
- Negotiations over linear prices
- Quantitative Analysis
- Construct simulation model of bargaining
- Empirical tests of vertical market structure
concentration measures and pricing