Market Structures Oligopoly and Repeated Games - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

1 / 80
About This Presentation
Title:

Market Structures Oligopoly and Repeated Games

Description:

We will use the discount factor, 0 1, to set all profits in terms of ... Each firm j attempts to maximize the discounted value of profits dt -1 jt, where ... – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:119
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 81
Provided by: debk6
Category:

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: Market Structures Oligopoly and Repeated Games


1
Topic 4 Part VI
Market Structures Oligopoly and Repeated Games
2
Infinitely Repeated Games and Cartel
  • Assume that a simultaneous-quantity-setting game
    is played repeatedly
  • The strategic situation is similar to the
    Prisoners Dilemma players will be better-off by
    producing the level of output (cartel quota) that
    maximizes the industrys profits, but they have
    incentives to deviate and unilaterally produce a
    level of output higher than their cartel quota

3
Infinitely Repeated Games and Cartel
  • A way of solving the instability of cartel can be
    to address the problem under the perspective of
    infinitely repeated games and apply a punishment
    strategy

4
Infinitely Repeated Games and Cartel
  • A punishment strategy that supports the cartel
    output as a SPNE is the grim-trigger strategy
    (Friedman, J., Review of Economic Studies,1971)
  • Each firm produces the cartel level of output
    as long as both produce the cartel output in the
    past. But if either ever deviates (i.e., by
    producing something other than the cartel
    output), each firm revert to producing the
    Cournot output forever (nice discussion in
    Kreps, A Course in Microeconomic Theory)

5
Verifying SPNE in Infinitely Repeated Games
  • Note that if firm i believes that firm j ( i ? j)
    will produce the Cournot level of output (as a
    punishment for the deviation of firm i) in a
    given period, then the optimal response of firm i
    is to produce the Cournot level of output as well
    (by definition of Cournot equilibrium)

6
Infinitely Repeated Games and Cartel
  • Note also that firm i will find it profitable to
    stick to the cartel output level only if the
    present value of its profits from cooperation are
    greater than the present value of its profits
    from deviation
  • Let ?di be the profits from deviating, ?ci be the
    Cournot profits and ?i be the cartel profits,
    for firm i

7
Infinitely Repeated Games and Cartel
  • We will use the discount factor, 0 lt ? lt 1, to
    set all profits in terms of the present period
  • Remember that the present value of x dollars
    received one period from today is ? x, two
    periods from today is ? 2x, etc.

8
Infinitely Repeated Games and Cartel
  • Remember also that the sum of the discounted
    payoff stream if an agent receives x dollars each
    period for an infinite number of periods is
  • x ? x ? 2x x (1 ? ? 2 )
  • x/ (1 - ?)

9
Infinitely Repeated Games and Cartel
  • Then, firm i will stick to the Cartel output if
  • ?i ? ?i ? 2 ?i ? ?di ? ?ci ? 2
    ?ci
  • ? ?di ? (?ci ? ?ci )
  • ? ?di ? ?ci (1 ? ? 2 )
  • i.e.,
  • ?i /(1 ?) ? ?di ? ?ci /(1 ?)

10
Infinitely Repeated Games
  • Hence,
  • ?i ? ?di (1 ?) ? ?ci
  • ?di ? - ? ?ci ? ?di - ?i
  • Therefore, if
  • ? ? ?di - ?i / ?di - ?ci

11
Infinitely Repeated Games
  • Hence, we find that if the parties are patiently
    enough (i.e., if they have a discount factor
    greater than some threshold) and value future
    cooperation more than immediate benefits, then
    cooperation (i.e., stick on the cartel output)
    will be supported as a SPNE of the infinitely
    repeated game

12
Verifying SPNE in Infinitely Repeated Games
  • For a detail analysis of why the threat
    represented by the punishment strategy allows to
    sustain the cartel solution as a SPNE in an
    infinitely repeated game, we will consider a
    simple 2X2 stage game and impose a strategy space
    on firms
  • Strategy 1 Produce the cartel quota (cooperative
    strategy)
  • Strategy 2 Produce the Cournot level of output
    (defect strategy)

13
An lllustration A Simple 2X2 Stage-Game
Firm 2
F I R M 1
14
Verifying SPNE in Infinitely Repeated Games
  • This simple game resembles the Prisoner Dilemma
    the cooperative solution (cartel solution)
    maximizes the joint payoffs but each firm
    receives a higher payoff playing the Cournot
    solution (for any strategy chosen by the other
    player)
  • In this simple example, the cooperative solution
    of the stage game is (defect, defect)

15
Verifying SPNE in Infinitely Repeated Games
  • The grim-trigger strategy specify
  • that firms select (cooperate, cooperate) each
    period as long as this profile was always played
    in the past by both firms
  • otherwise, firms are to play (defect, defect)
    forever

16
Verifying SPNE in Infinitely Repeated Games
  • We need to understand whether the firms have the
    incentive to play (cooperate, cooperate) each
    period under the threat that they will revert to
    (defect, defect) forever if one or both of them
    cheat

17
Verifying SPNE in Infinitely Repeated Games
  • Consider the incentives of firm i (i 1, 2) from
    the perspective of period 1
  • Suppose the other firm, firm j, behaves according
    to the grim-trigger strategy

18
Verifying SPNE in Infinitely Repeated Games
  • Player i has two options
  • It can follow the prescription of the
    grim-trigger strategy, which means cooperating if
    firm j does
  • In this case, firm i obtains a payoff of ? each
    period, for a discounted total of ?i/(1 d)

19
Verifying SPNE in Infinitely Repeated Games
  • Firm i could defect in the first period, which
    yields an immediate payoff of ?d (because firm j
    cooperates in the first period). However, firm
    is defection induces firm j to defect in each
    period thereafter. So the best that firm I can do
    is to keep defecting and get ?ic each period,
    starting in the second period
  • Thus, by defecting in period 1, firm i obtains
    the payoff ?id d ?ic/(1 d)

20
Verifying SPNE in Infinitely Repeated Games
  • If
  • ?i/(1 d) ? ?id d ?ic/(1 d)
  • or
  • ? ? ?di - ?i / ?di - ?ci ,
  • then player i earns a higher payoff by
    perpetually cooperating against the grim-trigger
    than by defecting in the first period

21
Verifying SPNE in Infinitely Repeated Games
  • So far, we see that the players have no incentive
    to cheat in the first period as long as
  • ? ? ?di - ?i / ?di - ?ci
  • The same analysis establishes that the players
    have no incentive to deviate from the
    grim-trigger in ANY period

22
Verifying SPNE in Infinitely Repeated Games
  • For example, suppose the players have cooperated
    through period (t 1)
  • Then, because the game is infinitely repeated,
    the continuation game from period t looks just
    like the game from period 1

23
Verifying SPNE in Infinitely Repeated Games
  • Hence, the analysis starting in period t is
    exactly the same as the analysis at period 1
  • Discounting the payoffs to period t, we see that
    cooperating from period t yields each firm
  • ?i/(1 d) and defecting against the
    grim-trigger leads to the payoff ?id d ?ic/(1
    d)

24
Verifying SPNE in Infinitely Repeated Games
  • Thus, neither player has an incentive to defect
    in period t if ? ? ?di - ?i / ?di - ?ci
  • Then, the analysis performed is enough to
    establish whether cooperation can be supported in
    a SPNE

25
Verifying SPNE in Infinitely Repeated Games
  • For the simple simultaneous-quantity-setting game
    proposed, the cartel equilibrium can be sustained
    by the reputation mechanism if and only if the
    discount factor
  • ? ? ?di - ?i / ?di - ?ci

26
SPNE of the Infinitely Repeated 2 X 2 Game
  • Firm j will not have incentive to deviate from
    cooperation iff
  • (a2/8b) (1/1 d) ? 5a2/36b d/(1 d) (a2/9b)
  • d ? 1/2

27
SPNE of the Infinitely Repeated Game
  • Consider now a general case, where firms are not
    restricted to play the two specified strategies
  • Evaluate under which conditions cooperation can
    be sustained as a SPNE

28
SPNE of the Infinitely Repeated Game
  • We will first need to obtain the optimal
    deviation for firm j
  • The maximum gain from deviation for firm j can
    be obtained by playing the best response to the
    other firms output equal to the quota (i.e.,
    evaluating the reaction function for firm j at
    firm is output equal to the quota)
  • Then, we get ?di
  • Finally, applying the same line of reasoning, we
    get that the condition on d can be expressed as
  • ? ? ?di- ?i / ?di - ?ci

29
SPNE of the Infinitely Repeated Game
  • Given that
  • yj a/4b (cartel quota)
  • yi fi(yj) (a byj)/2b
  • (reaction function for firm i)
  • p(Y) a - bY (inverse market demand)

30
SPNE of the Infinitely Repeated Game
  • Then, the optimal deviation for firm i (when firm
    j
  • remains producing the quota) is
  • yi d fi(yj) (a byj)/2b a b(a/4b)/2b
    3a/8b
  • So, Y yi d yj 5a/8b and p(Y) 3a/8
  • Hence, ?di 9a2/64b

31
SPNE of the Infinitely Repeated Game
  • To sustain cooperation as a SPNE we need
  • (a2/8b) (1/1 d) ? 9a2/64b d/(1 d) (a2/9b)
  • d ? 9/17

32
Infinitely Repeated Games
  • As in the case of the Prisoners Dilemma, there
    are a multiplicity of other equilibria in this
    model (Folk Theorem)

33
Bertrand Model of Price Competition
  • Model Setup
  • Two firms, firm 1 and firm 2 (duopoly)
  • Demand function x(p)

34
Bertrand Model of Price Competition
  • Both firms have NO capacity constraint (i.e.,
    that prevents to produce more than some maximal
    amount). Then, a price announcement represents a
    commitment to provide any quantity demanded
  • Both firms have same cost c gt 0 per unit produced

35
Bertrand Model of Price Competition
  • Competition takes place as follows the two firms
    simultaneously name their prices p1 and p2
  • Sales for firm j are give by
  • x(pj) if pj lt pk
  • xj(pj, pk) ½ x(pj) if pj pk
  • 0 if pj gtpk

36
Bertrand Model of Price Competition
  • The firms produce to order. So, they incur
    production costs only form an output level equal
    to their actual sales
  • Given prices pj and pk, firm js profits are
    equal to (pj c) xj(pj, pk)

37
Bertrand Model of Price Competition
  • The Bertrand model constitutes a well-defined
    one-shot simultaneous-move game
  • We can apply the Nash equilibrium concept. We
    will restrict to pure-strategy N.E.
  • There is a unique Nash equilibrium (p1, p2) in
    the Bertrand duopoly model. In this equilibrium,
    both firms set their prices equal to cost p1
    p2 c

38
Bertrand Model of Price Competition
  • Proof
  • (1) We will prove first that p1 p2 c is a
    N.E.
  • At these prices, both firms earn zero profits.
  • Neither firm can gain by raising its price
    because it will then make no sales (and still
    earn zero profits)
  • By lowering its price below c a firm increases
    its sales but incurs losses

39
Bertrand Model of Price Competition
  • (2) Now, we need to prove uniqueness (i.e.,
    there are no other N.E.)
  • Suppose that the lower of the two prices named is
    less than c. In this case, the firm naming this
    price incurs losses. But by raising its price
    above c, the worse it can do is earn zero. Thus,
    these price choices could not constitute a N.E.

40
Bertrand Model of Price Competition
  • Now suppose that one firms price is equal to c
    and that the others is strictly greater than c
  • pj c, pk gt c
  • In this case, firm j is selling to the entire
    market
  • but making zero profits. By raising its price a
  • little, say to pj c (pk c)/2, firm j would
    still
  • make all the sales in the market, but a strictly
  • positive profits. Thus, these price choices could
  • not constitute a N.E.

41
Bertrand Model of Price Competition
  • Finally, suppose that both prices are strictly
    greater than c
  • pj gt c, pk gt c
  • Without loss of generality, assume pj ? pk
  • In this case, firm k can be earning at most ½(pj
    c) x(pj)
  • But setting its price equal to pj - ?, for ? gt 0,
    that is, by undercutting
  • firm js price, firm k will get the entire market
    and earn
  • (pj - ? - c)x(pj - ?)
  • Since (pj - ? - c) x(pj - ?) gt ½(pj c) x(pj),
    for small-enough ? gt 0,
  • firm k can strictly increase its profits by doing
    so. Thus, these price
  • choices are not a N.E.

42
Bertrand Model of Price Competition
  • The three types of price configurations we just
    ruled out constitute all the possible price
    configurations other than p1 p2 c
  • So, we proved uniqueness

43
Bertrand Model and Repeated Interaction
  • One unrealistic assumption of this model is that
    it is a one-shot game
  • In this model, a firm never had to consider the
    reaction of its competitors to its price choice
  • In this model, a firm undercut its rival by a
    penny and steal all the rivals customers

44
Bertrand Model and Repeated Interaction
  • In practice, however, a firm may well worry that
    if it does undercut its rival, the rival will
    respond by cutting its own price, ultimately
    leading to only a short-run gain in sales but a
    long-run reduction in the price level in the
    market
  • Now we consider a Bertrand repeated game

45
Bertrand Model and Repeated Interaction
  • Model Setup
  • Two identical firms
  • They compete form sales repeatedly
  • Competition in each period t is described by the
    Bertrand model

46
Bertrand Model and Repeated Interaction
  • The two firms know all the prices that have been
    chosen (by both firms) previously
  • There is a discount factor 0 lt d lt 1
  • Each firm j attempts to maximize the discounted
    value of profits ? dt -1 ?jt, where ?jt, is firm
    js profits in period t
  • Dynamic game repeated play of the same static
    simultaneous-move game

47
Bertrand Model and Repeated Interaction
  • In this repeated Bertrand game, firm js strategy
    specifies what price pjt it will charge in each
    period t as a function of the history of all past
    price choices by the two firms,
  • t 1
  • Ht-1 p1?, p2 ?
  • ? 1

48
Bertrand Model and Repeated Interaction
  • Strategies of this form allow for a range of
    behavior
  • For example, a firms strategy could call for
    retaliation if the firms rival ever lowers its
    price below some threshold price
  • This retaliation could be brief, calling for the
    firm to lower its price for only a few periods
    after the rival crosses the line, or it could
    be unrelenting

49
Bertrand Model and Repeated Interaction
  • The retaliation could be tailored to the amount
    by which the firms rival undercut it, or it
    could be severe no matter how minor the rivals
    transgression
  • The firm could respond with increasingly
    cooperative behavior in return for its rival
    acting cooperatively in the past
  • The other option is that firms strategy could
    also make the firms behavior in any period t
    independent of past history

50
Bertrand Model and Cooperation Finite Repetitions
  • Consider first the case when firms compete only a
    finite number of times T (finitely repeated game)
  • Can the set of behavior just described sustain
    cooperation as a SPNE? NO
  • The unique SPNE of the finitely repeated Bertrand
    game involves T repetitions of the static
    Bertrand equilibrium in which prices equal cost

51
Bertrand Model and Cooperation Finite Repetitions
  • This is a consequence of backward induction
  • In the last period T, we must be at the Bertrand
    solution, and therefore profits are zero in that
    period regardless of what has happened earlier
  • But then in period T 1, we are, strategically
    speaking, at the last period, and the Bertrand
    solution must arise again
  • And so on, until we get to the first period

52
Bertrand Model and Cooperation Finite Repetitions
  • Hence, backward induction rules out the
    possibility of more cooperative behavior in the
    finitely repeated Bertrand game

53
Bertrand Model and Cooperation Infinite
Repetitions
  • Now we will extend the horizon to an infinite
    number of periods (infinitely repeated game)
  • Consider the following strategies for firms
  • j 1,2
  • pm if all elements of Ht -1 equal
    (pm, pm) or t 1
  • pjt(Ht 1)
  • c otherwise

54
Bertrand Model and Cooperation Infinite
Repetitions
  • This means that, firm js strategy calls for it
    to initially play the monopoly price pm in period
    1
  • Then, in each period t gt 1, firm j plays pm if in
    every previous period both firms have charged
    price pm, and otherwise, charges a price equal to
    its cost

55
Bertrand Model and Cooperation Infinite
Repetitions
  • This type of grim-trigger strategy is also called
    Nash reversion strategy firms cooperate until
    someone deviates and, any deviation triggers a
    permanent retaliation in which both firms
    thereafter set their prices equal to cost, to
    one-period Nash strategy

56
Bertrand Model and Cooperation Infinite
Repetitions
  • If both firms follow these strategies, then both
    firms will end up charging the monopoly price in
    every period they start by charging pm, and
    therefore no deviation from pm will ever be
    triggered

57
Bertrand Model and Cooperation Infinite
Repetitions
  • The strategies described constitute a SPNE of the
    infinitely repeated Bertrand duopoly game if and
    only if d ? ½
  • Proof
  • (1) First lets state that a set of strategies is
    a SPNE of an infinite-horizon game iff it
    specifies NE play in every subgame

58
Bertrand Model and Cooperation Infinite
Repetitions
  • (2) Note that although each subgame of this
    repeated game has a distinct history of play
    leading to it, all these subgames have an
    identical structure each is an infinitely
    repeated Bertrand duopoly game exactly like the
    game as a whole
  • (3) Then, to establish that the specified
    strategies constitute a SPNE, we need to show
    that after any previous history of play, these
    strategies for the remainder of the game
    constitute a NE of an infinitely repeated
    Bertrand game

59
Bertrand Model and Cooperation Infinite
Repetitions
  • (4) Given the specified strategies, we need to be
    concerned about only two types of previous
    histories
  • those in which there has been a previous
    deviation (a price not equal to pm), and
  • those in which there has not been a previous
    deviation

60
Bertrand Model and Cooperation Infinite
Repetitions
  • (5) Consider first a subgame arising after a
    deviation has occurred
  • The strategies call for each firm to set its
    price equal to c in every future period
    regardless of its rivals behavior
  • The pair of strategies is a N.E. of an
    infinitely repeated Bertrand game because each
    firm j can earn at most zero when its opponent
    always sets its price equal to c, and it earns
    exactly this amount by itself setting its price
    equal to c in every remaining period

61
Bertrand Model and Cooperation Infinite
Repetitions
  • (6) Now consider a subgame starting in, say,
    period t after no previous deviation has occurred
  • Each firm j knows that its rivals strategy calls
    for it to charge pm until it encounters a
    deviation from pm and to charge c thereafter
  • Is it in firm js interest to use this strategy
    itself given that its rival does? That is, do
    these strategies constitute a N.E. of this
    subgame? It depends on the PV of deviation
    versus PV of keeping pm

62
Bertrand Model and Cooperation Infinite
Repetitions
  • Suppose that firm j contemplates deviating from
    price pm in period ? ? t of the subgame if no
    deviation has occurred prior to period ?
  • We know that once a deviation has occurred within
    this subgame, firm j can do no better than to
    play c in every period given that its rival will
    do so. Hence, to check whether these strategies
    form a N.E. in this subgame, we need only check
    whether firm j will wish to deviate from pm if no
    such deviation has yet occurred

63
Bertrand Model and Cooperation Infinite
Repetitions
  • From period t through period ? -1, firm j will
    earn ½(pm c) x(pm) in each period, exactly as
    it does if it never deviates
  • Starting in period ?, however, its payoffs will
    differ from those that would arise if it does not
    deviate
  • In periods after it deviates (periods ? 1, ?
    2, ), firm js rival charges a price of c
    regardless of the form of firm js deviation in
    period ?, and so firm j can earn at most zero in
    each of these periods

64
Bertrand Model and Cooperation Infinite
Repetitions
  • In period ?, firm j optimally deviates in a
    manner that maximizes its payoff in that period
    (note that the payoffs firm j receives in later
    periods are the same for any deviation from pm
    that it makes)
  • It will therefore charge pm - ? for some
    arbitrary small ? gt 0, make all sales in the
    market, and earn a one-period payoff of (pm c -
    ?) x(pm - ?)

65
Bertrand Model and Cooperation Infinite
Repetitions
  • Thus, its overall discounted payoff from period ?
    onward, discounted to period ?, can be
    arbitrarily close to (pm c) x(pm)

66
Bertrand Model and Cooperation Infinite
Repetitions
  • On the other hand, if firm j never deviates, it
    earns a discounted payoff from period ? onward,
    discounted to period ?, of ½(pm c) x(pm)/(1
    d)
  • Hence, for any t and ? ? t, firm j will prefer
    no deviation to deviation in period ? iff
  • ½(pm c) x(pm)/(1 d) ? (pm c) x(pm),
  • d ? 1/2

67
Bertrand Model and Cooperation Infinite
Repetitions
  • Thus, the specified strategies constitute a SPNE
    iff d ? ½
  • This means that the perfectly competitive outcome
    of the static Bertrand game may be avoided if the
    firms foresee infinitely repeated interactions

68
Bertrand Model and Cooperation Infinite
Repetitions
  • The reason is that, in contemplating deviation,
    each firm takes into account not only the
    one-period gain it earns from undercutting its
    rival but also the profits forgone by triggering
    retaliation
  • The size of the discount factor d is important
    here because it affects the relative weights put
    on the future losses versus the present gains
    from a deviation

69
Bertrand Model and Cooperation Infinite
Repetitions
  • The monopoly price is sustainable iff the present
    value of these future losses is large enough
    relative to the possible current gain from
    deviation to keep the firms from going for
    short-run profits

70
Bertrand Model and Cooperation Infinite
Repetitions
  • Although the specified strategies constitute a
    SPNE when d ? ½, they are not the only SPNE of
    the infinitely repeated Bertrand model

71
Bertrand Model and Cooperation Infinite
Repetitions
  • (1) In the infinitely repeated Bertrand duopoly
    game, when d ? ½ repeated choice of any price
  • p ?c, pm can be supported as a SPNE outcome
    path using Nash reversion strategies

72
Bertrand Model and Cooperation Infinite
Repetitions
  • Proof of (1)
  • We have already proved that repeated choice of
  • price pm can be sustained as a SPNE outcome
  • when d ? ½. The proof for any price p ? c, pm)
  • follows exactly the same lines. We need only to
  • change price pm in the specified strategies to
  • p ? c, pm)

73
Bertrand Model and Cooperation Infinite
Repetitions
  • A general result in the theory of repeated
    games, known as the Folk Theorem, tell us that
  • In an infinitely repeated game, any feasible
    discounted payoffs that give each player, on a
    per-period basis, more than the lowest payoff
    that he could guarantee himself in a single play
    of the simultaneous-move component game can be
    sustained as the payoffs of a SPNE if players
    discount the future to a sufficiently small
    degree

74
Bertrand Model and Cooperation Infinite
Repetitions
  • Hence, although infinitely repeated games allow
    for cooperative behavior, they also allow for an
    extremely wide range of possible behavior
  • Historical focal points in the industry can solve
    the multiplicity of equilibria
  • Self-enforcing agreements (secret collusion
    because it is prohibited by law) can make the
    cooperative equilibrium more likely to occur

75
Bertrand Model and Cooperation Infinite
Repetitions under Many Firms
  • We will now investigate how the number of firms
    in a market affect its competitiveness
  • We will show that with J firms, repeated choice
    of any price p ? (c, pm can be sustained as a
    stationary SPNE outcome path of the infinitely
    repeated Bertrand game using Nash reversion
    strategies iff d ? (J - 1)/J

76
Bertrand Model and Cooperation Infinite
Repetitions under Many Firms
  • We will see that there is a relationship between
    having more firms and the difficulty of
    sustaining collusion

77
Bertrand Model and Cooperation Infinite
Repetitions under Many Firms
  • Proof
  • Let ? gt 0 be the firms equilibrium joint
    profits, which in equilibrium are split among
    firms
  • The best deviation for a firm is to undercut the
    rivals by a small ?, in which case it can steal
    all the demand and obtain almost as much as ? in
    every period

78
Bertrand Model and Cooperation Infinite
Repetitions under Many Firms
  • (3) Given the Nash reversion strategies, in the
    following punishing phase, the deviator will get
    zero forever after
  • Therefore deviation will imply a payoff equal to
    ?
  • (4) If the firm does not deviate, its payoff is
  • (1/1 d) (?/J)

79
Bertrand Model and Cooperation Infinite
Repetitions under Many Firms
  • (5) Therefore, deviation is not profitable iff
  • (1/1 d) (?/J) ? ?
  • d ? (J - 1)/J
  • Note that (J 1)/J is increasing in J. Then, as
  • increases, d has to increase in order for
    collusion
  • to be still sustainable

80
Bertrand Model and Cooperation Infinite
Repetitions under Many Firms
  • Hence, as the number of firms increases, it is
  • harder to sustain a collusive outcome
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)
About PowerShow.com