BLACK-SCHOLES OPTION PRICING MODEL - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

About This Presentation
Title:

BLACK-SCHOLES OPTION PRICING MODEL

Description:

BLACK-SCHOLES OPTION PRICING MODEL Chapters 7 and 8 BOPM and the B-S OPM The BOPM for large n is a practical, realistic model. As n gets large, the BOPM converges to ... – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:475
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 37
Provided by: XavierUn3
Learn more at: http://janroman.dhis.org
Category:

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: BLACK-SCHOLES OPTION PRICING MODEL


1
BLACK-SCHOLESOPTION PRICING MODEL
  • Chapters 7 and 8

2
BOPM and the B-S OPM
  • The BOPM for large n is a practical, realistic
    model.
  • As n gets large, the BOPM converges to the B-S
    OPM.
  • That is, for large n the equilibrium value of a
    call derived from the BOPM is approximately the
    same as that obtained by the B-S OPM.
  • The math used in the B-S OPM is complex but the
    model is simpler to use than the BOPM.

3
B-S OPM Formula
  • B-S Equation

4
Terms
  • T time to expiration, expressed as a proportion
    of the year.
  • R continuously compounded annual RF rate.
  • R ln(1Rs), Rs simple annual rate.
  • annualized standard deviation of the
  • logarithmic return.
  • N(d) cumulative normal probabilities.

5
N(d) term
  • N(d) is the probability that deviations less than
    d will occur in the standard normal distribution.
    The probability can be looked up in standard
    normal probability table (see JG, p.217) or by
    using the following

6
N(d) term
7
B-S Features
  • Model specifies the correct relations between the
    call price and the explanatory variables

8
Arbitrage Portfolio
  • The B-S equation is equal to the value of the
    replicating portfolio

9
Arbitrage Portfolio
  • The replicating portfolio in our example consist
    of buying .4066 shares of stock, partially
    financed by borrowing 15.42

10
Arbitrage Portfolio
  • If the price of the call were 3.00, then an
    arbitrageur should go short in the overpriced
    call and long in the replicating portfolio,
    buying .4066 shares of stock at 45 and borrowing
    15.42.
  • Since the B-S is a continuous model, the
    arbitrageur would need to adjust the position
    frequently (every day) until it was profitable to
    close. For an example, see JG 222-223.

11
Dividend Adjustments Pseudo-American Model
  • The B-S model can be adjusted for dividends using
    the pseudo-American model. The model selects the
    maximum of two B-S-determined values

12
Dividend Adjustments Continuous
Dividend-Adjustment Model
  • The B-S model can be adjusted for dividends using
    the continuous dividend-adjustment model.
  • In this model, you substitute the following
    dividend-adjusted stock price for the current
    stock price in the B-S formula

13
Black-Scholes Put Model
14
B-S Put Models Features
  • The model specifies the correct relations between
    the put price and the explanatory variables
  • Note Unlike the call model, the put model is
    unbound.

15
Arbitrage Portfolio
  • The B-S put equation is equal to the value of the
    replicating portfolio

16
Arbitrage Portfolio
  • The replicating portfolio in our example consist
    of selling .5934 shares of stock short at 45 and
    investing 33.83 in a RF security

17
Dividend Adjustments
  • B-S put model can be adjusted for dividends by
    using the continuous dividend-adjustment model
    where is substituted for So. A
    pseudo-American model can also be used. This
    model for puts is similar to calls, selecting
    the maximum of two B-S-determined values

18
Barone-Adesi and Whaley Model
  • The pseudo-American model estimates the value of
    an American put in reference to an ex-dividend
    date. When dividends are not paid (and as a
    result, we do not have a specific reference date)
    the model cannot be applied.
  • This is not a problem with applying the pseudo
    model to calls, since the advantage of early
    exercise applies only when an ex-dividend date
    exist.
  • As we saw with the BOPM for puts, early exercise
    can sometimes be profitable, even when there is
    not a dividend.
  • A model that addresses this problem and can be
    used to price American puts, as well as calls, is
    the Barone-Adesi Whaley (BAW) model. See JG
    246-248.

19
Estimating the B-S Model Implied Variance
  • The only variable to estimate in the B-S OPM (or
    equivalently, the BOPM with large n) is the
    variance. This can be estimated using historical
    averages or an implied variance technique.
  • The implied variance is the variance which makes
    the OPM call value equal to the market value. The
    software program provided each student calculates
    the implied variance.

20
Estimating the B-S Model Implied Variance
  • For at-the-money options, the implied variance
    can be estimated using the following formula

21
B-S Empirical Study
  • Black-Scholes Study (1972) Black and Scholes
    conducted an efficient market study in which they
    simulated arbitrage positions formed when calls
    were mispriced (C not to Cm).
  • They found some abnormal returns before
    commission costs, but found they disappeared
    after commission costs.
  • Galai found similar results.

22
MacBeth-Merville Studies
  • MacBeth and Merville compared the prices obtained
    from the B-S OPM to observed market prices. They
    found
  • the B-S model tended to underprice in-the-money
    calls and overprice out-of-the money calls.
  • the B-S model was good at pricing on-the-money
    calls with some time to expiration.

23
Bhattacharya Studies
  • Bhattacharya (1980) examined arbitrage portfolios
    formed when calls were mispriced, but assumed the
    positions were closed at the OPM values and not
    market prices.
  • Found B-S OPM was correctly specified.

24
General Conclusion
  • Empirical studies provide general support for the
    B-S OPM as a valid pricing model, especially for
    near-the-money options.
  • The overall consensus is that the B-S OPM is a
    useful model.
  • Today, the OPM may be the most widely used model
    in the field of finance.

25
Uses of the B-S Model
  • Identification of mispriced options
  • Generating profit tables and graphs for different
    time periods, not just expiration.
  • Evaluation of time spreads.
  • Estimating option characteristics
  • Expected Return, Variance, and Beta
  • Options Price sensitivity to changes in S, T, R,
    and variability.

26
Expected Return and Risk
  • Recall, the value of a call is equal to the value
    of the RP. The expected return, standard
    deviation, and beta on a call can therefore be
    defined as the expected return, standard
    deviation, and beta on a portfolio consisting of
    the stock and risk-free security (short)

27
Expected Return and Risk
  • In term of the OPM, the total investment in the
    RP is equal to the call price, the investment in
    the stock is equal HoSo, and the investment in
    the RF security is -B. Thus

28
Expected Return and Riskfor Puts
29
Delta, Gamma, and Theta
  • Delta is a measure of an options price
    sensitivity to a small change in the stock price.
  • Delta is N(d1) for calls and ranges from 0 to 1.
  • Delta is N(d1) - 1 for puts and ranges from -1 to
    0.
  • Delta for the call in the example is .4066
  • Delta for the put in the example is .5934.
  • Delta changes with time and stock prices changes.

30
Delta, Gamma, and Theta
  • Theta is the change in the price of an option
    with respect to a change in the time to
    expiration.
  • Theta is a measure of the options time decay.
  • Theta is usually defined as the negative of the
    partial of the option price with respect to T.
  • Interpretation An option with a theta of 7 would
    find for a 1 decrease in the time to expiration
    (2.5 days), the option would lose 7 in value.
  • For formulas for estimating theta, see JG
    258-259.

31
Delta, Gamma, and Theta
  • Gamma measures the change in the options delta
    for a small change in the price of the stock. It
    is the second derivative of the option with
    respect to a change in the stock price.
  • For formulas for estimating gamma, see JG
    258-259.

32
Position Delta, Gamma, and Theta
  • The description of call and put options in terms
    of their delta, gamma, and theta values can be
    extended to option positions.
  • For example, consider an investor who purchases
    n1 calls at C1 and n2 calls on another call
    option on the same stock at a price of C2.
  • The value of the portfolio (V) is

33
Position Delta, Gamma, and Theta
  • The call prices are a function of S, T,
    variability, and Rf. Taking the partial
    derivative of V with respect to S yields the
    position delta

34
Position Delta, Gamma, and Theta
  • The position delta measure the change in the
    positions value in response to a small change in
    the stock price.
  • By setting the position delta equal to zero and
    solving for n1 in terms of n2 a neutral position
    delta can be constructed with a value invariant
    to small changes in the stock price.

35
Position Delta, Gamma, and Theta
  • The position theta is obtained by taking the
    partial derivative of V with respect to T

36
Position Delta, Gamma, and Theta
  • The position gamma is obtained by taking the
    derivative of the position delta respect to S
  • Strategy For a neutral position delta with a
    positive position gamma, the value of the
    position will decrease for small changes in the
    stock price and increase for large increases or
    decreases in the stock price.
  • StrategyFor a neutral position delta with a
    negative position gamma, the value of the
    position will increase for small changes in the
    stock price and decrease for large increases or
    decreases in the stock price.
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)
About PowerShow.com