Title: C15 Lecture 2: Intergenerational Mobility
1C15 Lecture 2 Intergenerational Mobility
2Issues
- Defining intergenerational mobility
- Measuring intergenerational mobility in economic
and social status - Estimates of the extent of intergenerational
mobility - International comparison and changes over time
3A Model of Intergenerational Mobility
- Solon (1999) HoLE
- Parental lifetime earnings in generation (t-1)
is Yt-1 allocated into consumption C and
investment in children I - Yt-1 Ct-1 It-1
- Investment then yields a return r to children in
their own generation, t - Yt (1r)It-1 Et
- where E is other determinants of earnings.
4A Model of Intergenerational Mobility (Continued)
- Suppose parent maximises U (1-?)logCt-1
?logYt then will choose investment according to - It-1 ?Yt-1 (1-?)/(1r)Et
- Substitution for It-1 in the child earnings
function gives - Yt ?Yt-1 ut
- If cov(Yt-1, Et) 0 then ß ( ?(1r)) is the
correlation between child and parent earnings. A
larger ? implies reduced mobility in that child
and parent earnings are more strongly correlated
across generations.
5Implications
- Simple model reveals
- Several mechanisms may underpin intergenerational
mobility - Very much an empirical question how big is the
intergenerational correlation - Unpacking the transmission mechanisms may be a
complex process - Despite its simplicity careful specification of
empirical models is required - Data requirements to estimate mobility are
stringent
6Intergenerational Mobility and Inequality
- Atkinson (1981) JPKE
- Childhood consumption c1Yt-1
- Adulthood consumption c2Yt
- Lifetime welfare Wt log(c1Yt-1) ?log(c2Yt)
- Variance of lifetime welfare is
- Var(Wt) Var(logYt-1) 2?Cov(logYt-1,logYt)
?2Var(logYt)
7Intergenerational Mobility and Inequality
(Continued)
- If the intergenerational income transmission is
logYt ? logYt-1 ut and assume Var(logYt)
Var(logYt-1) Var(logY) then - Var(W) Var(logY)1 2?? ?2
- which implies a higher ß (i.e. less mobility) to
be associated with higher inequality.
8Intergenerational Mobility and Inequality
(Continued)
-
- Compared to ? 0 ?
- d 0.5 d 1
- ? 0.2 16 20
- ? 0.4 24 40
- ? 0.6 48 60
9Measurement of the Extent of Intergenerational
Mobility
- 2 main approaches
- 1). Regression Based Approach
- yichild a ß yiparent uichild
- where y is log(Y) and u an error term.
- ? is intergenerational elasticity
- ß 0 ? complete mobility as child earnings are
independent of those of their parents. - ß 1 ? complete immobility as child earnings
are fully determined by the parental earnings. - (could have ß lt 0 reversal)
10Measurement (Continued)
- 2). Transition matrix approach
- Split child and parent Y distributions into
equal sized quantiles and look at transitions
across generations. -
- e.g. quartiles split into 4, deciles into 10
etc. -
11Measurement (Continued)- Quartile Transition
Matrices
A. Complete Mobility Parents Quartile Parents Quartile Parents Quartile Parents Quartile Parents Quartile
Childs Quartile Top 2nd 3rd Bottom
Childs Quartile Top .25 .25 .25 .25
Childs Quartile 2nd .25 .25 .25 .25
Childs Quartile 3rd .25 .25 .25 .25
Childs Quartile Bottom .25 .25 .25 .25
B. Complete Immobility Parents Quartile Parents Quartile Parents Quartile Parents Quartile Parents Quartile
Childs Quartile Top 2nd 3rd Bottom
Childs Quartile Top 1 0 0 0
Childs Quartile 2nd 0 1 0 0
Childs Quartile 3rd 0 0 1 0
Childs Quartile Bottom 0 0 0 1
12Measurement (Continued) Issues
- 1). Types of data
- Cross-section Retrospective Tracing
Longitudinal - 2) Measurement
- What is Y? Transitory vs permanent?
- 3). Interpretation
- How big? Equality of opportunity
13Measurement (Continued) What is Y?
- yichild a ß yiparent uichild
- For economists Y typically earnings or income
(and sometimes education). - But wide range of other studies in other
disciplines e.g. original Galton 1886 study of
height (at UCL) or big literature in sociology
on social class origins and destinations.
14Measurement (Continued) Transitory Versus
Permanent
- yichild a ß yiparent uichild
- Issue is y should reflect lifetime earnings, but
will be measured with error in most cases due to
transitory fluctuations in measured earnings. - Recorded y is yit, yis (s parents generation
t childs generation) - yitchild yichild vitchild yisparent
yiparent visparent
15Measurement (Continued) Transitory Versus
Permanent
- In practice look at
- yitchild a ß yisparent uitchild
- In this formulation ß will be biased downwards
if transitory components are present. - It will be downward biased by a factor of Var(y)
/ Var(y) Var(visparent). - So if there is no measurement error and
Var(visparent) 0 there is no bias. - Further aggravated if look at specific samples.
Sample homogeneity makes downward bias worse.
16Estimates of the extent of intergenerational
mobility
- Early literature (US) intergenerational
correlation of log earnings about 0.2. Becker
and Tomes (1986) Journal of Labor Economics
Aside from families victimised by
discrimination, regression to the mean in
earnings in the United States and other rich
countries appears to be rapid.
17Estimates (Continued)
- Much of this work based on specific samples and
often on cross-section (and sometimes
retrospective) data. So scope for downward bias. - Confirmed by Solon (1992) and Zimmerman (1992)
American Economic Review papers.
18Estimates (Continued)
- Solon (1992) uses longitudinal data from the US
Panel Survey of Income Dynamics to set up sample
of 348 father-son pairs (fathers earnings in late
1960s, sons in early 1980s). - One solution to possible downward bias is
offered by these data time average (T periods)
multiple earnings measures - Bias reduced
- ßV(y) / (V(y) V(visparent)/T
19Estimates (Continued)
- This is illustrated in Tables 2 and 3 of Solons
paper. - Zimmerman (1992) uses a different data source,
but with very similar findings 876 father-son
pairs from US National Longitudinal Study. Table
2 summarises results around 0.4 for time
averaged specifications. Table 15 transition
matrix.
20Estimates (Continued) Solon (1992), Table 2
21Estimates (Continued) Solon (1992), Table 3
22Estimates (Continued) Zimmerman (1992), Table 2
23Estimates (Continued) Zimmerman (1992), Table
15
24International Comparisons
- There are clear differences in intergenerational
correlations across countries.
Country Study Elasticity
Finland Jantti Osterbacka(1996) Osterbacka (2001) 0.22 0.13
Sweden Bjorklund and Jantti (1997) Bjorklund and Chadwick (2002) 0.28 0.25
Germany Wiegand (1997) 0.34
US Solon (1992) Zimmerman (1992) 0.43 0.45
UK Atkinson et al (1983) Dearden, Machin and Reed (1997) 0.42 0.42-0.57
25Changes Over Time
- Most work looks at point in time comparison (not
so surprising given data requirements). - Given links between inequality and the
intergenerational elastcicity, movements over
time may also be of interest. - Blanden, Goodman, Gregg and Machin (2004) look at
changes over time in UK.
26Changes Over Time (Continued)
- Based upon data from the 1958 and 1970 British
birth cohorts, the extent of intergenerational
mobility in economic status has reduced
substantially over time.
27Earnings and Parental Income Across Generations
Regression Coefficient Adjusted For Inequality Change Regression Coefficient Adjusted For Inequality Change Cross-Cohort Change Sample sizes
NCDS BCS
Sons .166 (.020) .260 (.024) .095 (.031) NCDS 2246 BCS 2053
Daughters .168 (.022) .227 (.022) .059 (.031) NCDS 1908 BCS 2017
28Mechanisms
- A very simple and stylized theoretical model
shows a stronger link between parent and child
incomes when there is higher inequality and
greater links between parental income and
education - Wt ?tHt vt
- Ht ?tWt-1 ?t
- Therefore Wt ?t?t Wt-1 ut
29Rising Wage and Educational Inequality Lead to
Falling Mobility
- Two factors thus combine to form the
intergenerational mobility parameter - - higher ?t (more wage inequality) implies lower
mobility - - higher ?t (closer links between education and
parental earnings/income) implies lower mobility
as increased educational inequality reinforces
cross-generation persistence
30Education as a Transmission Mechanism
- Seems to operate via increased educational
inequality. Strong increase in sensitivity of
education to family income. - Increased educational inequality has acted to
reinforce and raise immobility in economic status
across generations
31Changes in HE Participation
- Marked differences by social class.
32Degree Acquisition and Family Income
Degree Acquisition by Age 23 Degree Acquisition by Age 23 Degree Acquisition by Age 23 Degree Acquisition by Age 23
Lowest 20 percent Middle 60 percent Highest 20 percent Educational Inequality
NCDS 1981 .06 .08 .20 .14 (.01)
BCS 1993 .07 .15 .37 .30 (.02)
BHPS 1999 .09 .23 .46 .37 (.05)
Change 1981-1993 .01 .07 .17 .15 (.02)
Change 1993-1999 .02 .08 .09 .07 (.06)
Change 1981-1999 .03 .15 .26 .23 (.06)
33Implications
- Cross-generation mobility in economic status
falls across cohorts for children going through
the education system in the 1970s and 1980s. - Part of this is due to an increased sensitivity
of education to parental income (this continues
to rise into the 1990s as well). - To the extent that increased educational
inequality drives reduced cross-generation
mobility, policies to do with widening
participation in HE are important.