Title: Estimating Well-Being in Developing Countries
1Estimating Well-Being in Developing Countries
2Well-Being
- (1) What is well-being?
- (2) Why should economists be interested in
well-being? - (3) Estimating well-being equations
- (4) Empirical Findings
-
3Well-Being
- (1) What is well-being?
-
- Aristotle sees happiness and living well as
the same thing and that living well consists of
doing something. - Well-Being and Ill-Being Jeremy Bentham in
19th Century. - World Health Organisation Quality of Life
Concerned with measuring physical health,
psychological health, social relationships, and
the environment. -
- What people have or do not have (material)
what people do or cannot do with it (relational)
what people think or feel (subjective).
Wellbeing in Developing Countries WeD (2009). -
4Well-Being
- We focus on subjective well-being (SWB).
- However, SWB will be closely correlated with
material and relational factors. - If have a house and car then better-off in
yourself (SWB) and when compared to others
(relational). - It is the relative position of an individual
that is arguably most interesting in both the
theoretical and empirical literature. -
5Well-Being
- Issue of who to compare your well-being to.
- (i) keeping up with the Jones neighbour or
village effect. - (ii) peer group fellow worker, average worker,
race, gender, age, caste - (iii) different time periods yesterday, last
year. - (iv) different generations parents
- (v) some pre-determined social norm
sociology.
6Well-Being
- (2) Why should economists be interested in
well-being? - Well-being and satisfaction are similar concepts
hence can directly test utility. - It is assumed in micro-foundations of
neo-classical theory that utility is formed based
on consumption of goods which in itself is
determined by the budget constraint (income).
A
SatisfactionUtility
B
7Well-Being
- However Easterlin (1974) found that over time
happiness did not increase with income
Easterlin paradox -
- If increasing income does not increase
satisfaction or utility then why be obsessed with
this?
GDP per capita
Average Satisfaction and GDP per capita
Satisfaction with life
Time
8Well-Being
- Richard Layard and others (e.g. Frey and
Stutzer, 2002), argue that it is relative income
that explains why happiness does not increase
significantly beyond - (i) a certain level of GDP per capita (Macro)
- (ii) a certain individual absolute income level
(Micro) - So if your income increases but so does everyone
elses then your relative position is the same. - Indeed, if your income increases but at a slower
rate than the average income increase then your
relative position worsens income inequality is
becoming more skewed towards the very highest
decile in the US and UK..is this why were not
more satisfied?
9Well-Being
- Lucas et al (2004) argue that while income,
health and family are correlated with life
satisfaction that they do not explain much of the
variance in satisfaction. - Personality variables account for a much larger
share of subjective satisfaction use of twin
studies indicates that 80 of the variance in
satisfaction is something that comes from within. - Genetic.
- Any exogenous shocks thus have an impact on
short-term variation in satisfaction, but in the
long-run individuals return to some set-point.
10Well-Being
Older people tend to report higher levels of life
satisfaction Why?
Negative Shock e.g. unemployment, death, tragic
news
10
Set Point
SWB
Positive Shock e.g. inheritance, lottery win,
house prices
0
Years
11Well-Being
- Cross-Country Comparisons
- Many studies compare countries (e.g. Stevenson
and Wolfers, 2008) and suggest that GDP per
capita is significant in subjective happiness. - Other factors that are important include health
and unemployment rates. - However variations in happiness between
countries can be criticised. - Does someone who scores 8 in Sweden really have
the same level of happiness as someone who scores
8 in India? reference group.
12Well-Being
- (3) Estimating well-being equations.
- Using the Likert scale for happiness or life
satisfaction as the dependent variable. - Economists can test a number of hypotheses.
- (1) Are income, wealth, assets positively
correlated with happiness? - In cross-country studies use GDP per capita as
measure of income. - In national study use income per adult
equivalence for household level income, use the
squared term too to see if happiness increases
with income at a decreasing rate. - Same method for information on assets and wealth
may need to create an index or use factor
analysis to get a single measure of household
assets/wealth e.g. pots and pans, knives,
agricultural tools.
13Well-Being
- Endogeneity Issues
- It could well be that someone of a happier
disposition will earn more in the labour market
(Ruut Veenhoven). - This could be picking up social network effects
and being more sociable. It could also be
picking up unobservable characteristics of
individuals not traditionally found in earnings
functions, e.g. optimism, positive attitude, work
ethic?
14Well-Being
- (2) Employment and Satisfaction
- Well known in the labour economics literature
that the unemployed are scarred we would expect
that the unemployed would, ceteris paribus,
report lower levels of satisfaction than the
employed. - As well as this basic test the applied
literature has used the satisfaction data to test
whether the searching and non-searching
unemployed report different satisfaction rates. - This tests the neo-classical hypothesis that via
maximising utility the non-searching unemployed
are voluntarily unemployed as they choose not to
search. - If it is found that the non-searching are as
satisfied as the searching unemployed or even
less satisfied then this is consistent with the
discouraged worker hypothesis.
15Well-Being
- (3) Satisfaction and Relative Consumption
-
- Evidence from Hinks and Davies for Malawi
(2008), Copestake et al (2009) for Peru indicates
that even amongst very poor communities, as
average consumption increases so satisfaction
declines. - Suggests that relative economic position in the
community is important to satisfaction. - This can be tested further by calculating
whether your household consumption (or income) is
above the community average or not. - Studies on job satisfaction have found that
relative earnings are important findings tend
to confirm that as the average earnings of
someone with your skill set increases then,
ceteris paribus, job satisfaction declines.
16Well-Being
- Other Hypotheses of interest-
- Satisfaction and Crime Powdthavee (2008),
Hinks and Davies (2010). - Satisfaction and Race or Gender Hinks Gruen
(2007), Hinks and Davies (2008). - Satisfaction and Social Networks Hinks and
Davies (2008), Polygamy, Religion and
Satisfaction. -
17Well-Being
- (4) Empirical Evidence
- (i) Well-Being, Income and Relative Income
- Evidence is conclusive with a positive
relationship within country well-being or
happiness and income level. For both developing
and developed countries. - E.g. Powdthavee (2005), Hinks and Gruen (2007),
Hinks and Davies (2008, 2010) work using
cross-sectional data sets for developing
countries.
18Well-Being
- (ii) The Case of Employment Status and
Well-Being - Lucas et al (2004, pp.11) find that (i)
satisfaction begins to decline before the worker
is unemployed (ii) life satisfaction is reduced
massively when unemployed and (iii) satisfaction
increases but not back to pre-unemployment level.
19Well-Being
- Case Study of South Africa Kingdon and Knight
(2006). - First issue is that of endogeneity are the
unhappiest people more likely to be unemployed? - Evidence from longitudinal studies by
psychologists is that this reverse causality is
doubtful Veenhoven suggests that happier
people are more likely to be employed first than
unhappier people. - Happiness is on a 5-point scale, 0 is very
dissatisfied and 5 is very satisfied. - Only collected for head of households so not
individual level. - The searching unemployment rate (No. of
searching unemployed in HH/No. of broad labour
force participants). - The non-searching unemployment rate (No of
non-searching unemployed in HH/No. of broad
labour force participants).
20(No Transcript)
21Well-Being
- No significant difference in life satisfaction
between the searching and non-searching
unemployed. - Implication is to reject the hypothesis that the
non-searching unemployed are happier than the
searching and accept that worker discouragement
is at work in South Africa. - Given the strict rate of unemployment is high
(still officially 24 in 2nd quarter of 2009)
this is perhaps unsurprising but importantly adds
to the evidence against voluntary unemployment.
22Well-Being
- An abridged version of an estimated happiness
equation taken from Hinks and Davies (2008). - Analysis of some findings
- (i) Find that larger consumption raises life
satisfaction. In developing countries there is
still a great need to increase economic growth to
raise income levels. - (ii) If relatively better off in terms of
consumption then more satisfied. The importance
of relative position is confirmed. - (iii) The perceptions of your neighbours wealth
positively predicts more satisfaction for you.
Capturing some of the log consumption variable as
this coefficient decreases in size. - (iv) Wealthier households (assets) are more
satisfied - (vi) The salaried employed and self-employed are
more satisfied than farmers.
23Dependent Variable Overall, how satisfied
(content, happy) are you with your life?.
Responses from 1 (very unsatisfied) to 5 (very
satisfied)
Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4 Model 5
ln(Per Capita Consumption) 0.338 0.173 0.184 0.138 0.072
(13.905) (6.115) (7.044) (4.811) (2.322)
ln(Mean Community Consumption) -0.193
(-5.267)
Relative Household Consumption 1 0.152 0.174 0.164
(4.910) (5.586) (5.212)
Relative Household Consumption 2 0.061
(5.671)
Neighbours' Subjective Wealth 0.108 0.101
(8.627) (7.996)
Asset Score 0.096
(5.564)
Salaried Employment Dummy 0.144 0.136 0.135 0.124 0.091
(4.442) (4.234) (4.199) (3.848) (2.737)
Self-Employed Dummy 0.151 0.145 0.146 0.137 0.130
(4.417) (4.244) (4.266) (4.002) (3.797)
N 11264 11264 11264 11248 11205
Pseudo R-Squared 0.068 0.068 0.068 0.070 0.071
Chi2 1802.312 1793.891 1812.681 1850.342 1869.723
24Some Useful Websites for Economics of Wellbeing,
Quality of Life and Happiness
- (1) World Health Organisation Quality of Life,
- http//www.who.int/substance_abuse/research_tools
/whoqolbref/en/ - (2) Wellbeing in Developing Countries WeD,
- http//www.welldev.org.uk/
- (3) World Values Survey
- http//www.worldvaluessurvey.org
- (4) World data base of Happiness Ruut
Veenhoven - http//worlddatabaseofhappiness.eur.nl/
- (5) International Society for Quality of Life
Studies - http//www.isqols.org/
25References
- Easterlin, R., (1974), Does Economic Growth
Improve the Human Lot?, in Nations and
Households in Economic Growth Essays in Honor of
Moses Abramovitz, ed. by P. A. David, and M. W.
Reder. New York Academic Press. - Stevenson, B, and Wolfers, J., (2008), Economic
Growth and Subjective Well-Being Reassessing the
Easterlin Paradox, NBER Working Paper Series,
No. 14282 - Layard. R., (2005), Happiness Lessons from a
new science, Penguin, London. - Frey, B., and Stutzer, A., (2002), Happiness and
Economics How the Economy and Institutions
Affect Human Well-Being, Princeton University
Press, NJ. - Lucas, R., Clark, A., Georgellis, Y., and
Diener, E., (2004), Unemployment Alters the Set
Point for Life Satisfaction, Psychological
Science, 15(1) 8-13. - Powdthavee, N. (2005). Unhappiness and crime
Evidence from South Africa. Economica, 72,
531547.), - Hinks, T., Gruen, C. (2007). What is the
structure of South African happiness equations?
Evidence from quality of life surveys. Social
Indicators Research, 82(2), 311336. - Hinks, T., Davies, S. (2008). Life satisfaction
in Malawi. Journal of International Development,
20, 888904. - Davies, S., and Hinks, T., (2010), Crime and
Happiness amongst heads of households in Malawi,
Journal of Happiness Studies, 11 457-476. - Copestake, J., Guillen-Royo, M., Chou, W. J.,
Hinks, T., Velazco, J., (2009). The relationship
between economic and subjective wellbeing
indicators in Peru. Applied Research in Quality
of Life, 4 (2), pp. 155-177.