Communication and Prices in Economic Mechanisms - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

About This Presentation
Title:

Communication and Prices in Economic Mechanisms

Description:

Communication and Prices in Economic Mechanisms Ilya Segal Four lectures Communication costs in economics Communication and prices in social choice Market design ... – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:69
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 82
Provided by: Institute82
Learn more at: https://web.stanford.edu
Category:

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: Communication and Prices in Economic Mechanisms


1
Communication and Prices in Economic Mechanisms
  • Ilya Segal

2
Four lectures
  1. Communication costs in economics
  2. Communication and prices in social choice
  3. Market design applications
  4. Communication cost of incentives

3
Communication costs in economics
4
Market Design Problems
  • Find allocations satisfying social goals when
    agents have private knowledge (e.g. of own
    preferences)
  • Combinatorial auctions FCC spectrum, landing
    slots,
  • Matching candidates to jobs, internships,
  • Kidney exchange
  • Incentives?
  • can be verified with a Direct Revelation
    Mechanism (e.g., Vickrey-Clarke-Groves)
  • But full revelation is costly and is avoided in
    most real-life mechanisms
  • Instead sequential mechanisms e.g., iterative
    auctions, interviews, - to grope for equilibrium

5
Hayeks (1945) Critique of Lange-Lerner socialism
  • Knowledge of particular circumstances of time
    and place too enormous to transmit to a central
    planner
  • Ultimate decisions must be left to the people
    familiar with these circumstances
  • Information needed to coordinate individual
    actions can be summarized in prices
  • Nobody has yet succeeded in designing an
    alternative system

6
Costs of Revelation
  • Communication costs
  • E.g., combinatorial auctions 2L bundle values
  • Measured in bits (communication complexity) or
    real numbers (message space dimension)
  • Cost of agents evaluating own preferences
  • E.g., job interviews, flyouts,
  • More deviations when commitment is imperfect
    (short-term contracts, cheap talk)
  • E.g., revealed info may be exploited by
    auctioneer or competitors in the future

7
Communication
  • N set of agents, X set of outcomes
  • Agent i privately observes his type Ri 2 Ri
  • State R (R1, , RN) 2 R1 RN R
  • Want to implement choice rule F R ? X
  • F(R) optimal outcomes in state R
  • Sequential communication may save over
    simultaneous
  • Communication Protocol
  • 1. Extensive-form message game
  • 2. Outcomes assigned to terminal nodes
  • 3. Agents strategies (type-contingent)
  • Do not require incentive-compatibility (e.g.,
    agents could be computers)

8
Communication
Agent 2s type
Agent 1s type
  • State space partitioned into product sets
  • In every state R must implement an outcome in
    F(R)
  • Characterizing such protocols is hard

9
Verification (Nondeterminism)
  • Omniscient oracle knows state R but must prove to
    an outsider that x 2 F(R)

  • Announces message m 2 M
  • Each agent accepts or rejects m based on his own
    type
  • Acceptance by all agents verifies x 2 F(R)
  • Verification in each state R

Agent 2s type
x
Agent 1s type

10
Verification Formalism
  • Protocol ? ?M, µ, h ?
  • M is a message space
  • µ R ? M is a message correspondence s.t.
    Privacy Preservation
  • µ(R) \i µi(Ri) ?R
  • h M ? X is outcome function
  • ? verifies F if ? ? h(µ(R)) ½ F(R) ?R
  • ? fully verifies F if h(µ(R)) F(R) ?R

11
Why Verification?
  • Any deterministic protocol can be verified by
    oracle sending messages in agents stead (i.e., M
    terminal nodes of the protocol)
  • ? verification costs communication costs
  • Economic example Walrasian equilibrium message
    (allocation, prices)
  • Steady state of a communication process (e.g.,
    tatonnement, auctions, deferred acceptance
    algorithms)?

12
Measuring communication costs
  • Discrete number of bits (communication
    complexity)
  • E.g., oracle needs log2M bits to encode message
  • Continuous number of real numbers
  • How many reals are needed to encode a message
    from M dimension of M?
  • Agents costs of evaluating own types
  • E.g., number of job interviews, dates, sorting
  • Privacy reducing revelation of agents types
    E.g., revealed info may be exploited in the future

13
Measuring Dimension Problem
  • Intuition dimension of M number of real
    numbers needed to describe points in M
  • Problem - Peano space-filling curve 0,1 ?
    0,1n
  • Inverse Peano function describes 0,1n with one
    number
  • Note Peano function is continuous (its inverse
    is not)

14
Questions
  • How to define the dimension of a space?
  • Which transformations preserve this dimension?
  • Two classes of approaches
  • Topological dimensions
  • Metric dimensions

15
Topological dimension - inductive
  • We say that space is 3-dimensional because the
    walls of a prison are 2-dimensional
  • M is topological space (defined open sets)
  • ind(?) - 1
  • ind M ? k if every point in M lies in an open
    set whose boundary has ind ? k 1
  • ind M min. integer k s.t.ind M ? k

16
Preservation of topological dimension
  • Proposition If f X ? Y is a continuous 1-to-1
    function then ind Y ? ind X
  • Proof idea f(X) has fewer open sets than X
    harder to imprison points
  • Could have ind Y gt ind X if f -1 is not
    continuous (e.g., Peano function)

17
Metric dimension (ball covering)
  • M is a metric space (has distances)
  • NM(?) min. number of ?-balls needed to cover M
  • E.g. N 0,1n (?) A ? (1/?)n
  • In general, dim M limsup??0 ln NM(?)/ln (1/?)
  • To cover unbounded S could allow to vary ball
    size (Hausdorff dimension)
  • dim M ? ind M
  • M irrational numbers in 0,1 ? dim M 1, ind
    M 0
  • dim M may be fractal
  • e.g., dim (Chinas coastline) 1.16

18
Interpretation of metric dimension Approximation
with bits
  • NM (?) min. number of messages needed to
    approximate points from M within ? (discretize)
  • log2NM (?) min. number of bits needed to encode
    such messages
  • Thus can approximate points from M within ? using
    dim M ? log2(1/?) bits as ??0
  • Thus dim M relates to communication complexity of
    approximating M with bits
  • But dim M may not represent the hardness of
    approximation for a fixed ? gt 0, or for ??0
    slowly as other parameters grow (will have
    example)

19
Preservation of metric dimension
  • Proposition If f X ? M is a 1-to-1 function and
    f -1 is Lipschitz
  • (i.e., ?A gt0 dist(x, x?) ? A?dist(f (x), f
    (x?)) ?x,x?)
  • then dim M ? dim X
  • Proof f does not shrink distances except by a
    factor
  • Continuity of f -1 not enough (e.g. let f be
    inverse Peano)

20
Fooling set dimension bounds
  • Rf ? R is a fooling set if ?R,R? ? Rf, R?R? ?
    ?(R)? ?(R?) ?
  • Proposition Suppose Rf is a fooling set.
  • (a) If ? has a (local) continuous selection, ind
    M ? ind Rf.
  • (b) If ? has a (local) selection whose inverse is
    Lipschitz continuous, then dim M ? dim Rf.

21
So, which dimension is better?
  • Use topological dimension, restrict ? to have a
    continuous selection?
  • Mount-Reiter, Walker, etc.
  • Rules out discrete messages (e.g., indivisible
    allocations)
  • Use metric dimension, restrict ? to have a
    selection whose inverse is Lipschitz continuous?
  • Hurwicz 1977, Nisan-Segal
  • Interpretation small errors in message
    transmission should not yield large mistakes
  • Need not rule out any mechanisms - can define a
    right metric on any M to have Lipschitz
    continuity
  • Allows fast discrete approximations

22
Lecture 2 Communication and Prices in Social
Choice
23
Hayeks (1945) Critique of socialism
  • Knowledge of particular circumstances of time
    and place too enormous to transmit to a central
    planner
  • Ultimate decisions must be left to the people
    familiar with these circumstances
  • Information needed to coordinate individual
    actions can be summarized in prices
  • Nobody has yet succeeded in designing an
    alternative system

24
Is it necessary to use prices?
  • Fundamental Welfare Thms Supporting prices (1)
    are sufficient for efficiency and (2) can be
    constructed with full information about the
    economy
  • But then can compute efficient allocation
    directly
  • Hurwicz, Mount-Reiter In a convex economy with
    distributed preference information, Walrasian
    equilibrium is dimensionally minimal among
    regular mechanisms verifying efficiency
  • Did not rule out mechanisms that dont use prices
  • Inapplicable to market design
  • Nonconvexities, discrete decisions
  • Other goals approximation, group stability,
    fairness,
  • Other communication costs bits, evaluations,

25
Informativeness Partial Order
  • Message m is less informative than message m' if
    m' accepted ? m accepted.
  • m is a minimally informative message verifying
    outcome x if any less informative message
    verifying x is equivalent to m.
  • Such messages minimize communication costs
  • Size of M - number of bits or reals to encode a
    message
  • Preference evaluation costs, privacy loss, etc.

x
m'
26
Allocate an Object between 2 Agents
  • Messages verifying 2
  • Minimally informative messages verifying 2

2
m
1
  • Equivalent to announcing supporting equilibrium
    price p
  • Each p must be used (in a diagonal state) ? need
    infinitely many messages (continuum)

27
General Results
  • Characterize social choice problems (social goals
    and preference domains) for which it is necessary
    to find supporting prices
  • Algorithm deriving the form of prices (budget
    sets) that verify solutions to a given problem
    with minimal information
  • Price space yields communication cost
  • Selected applications
  • Pareto efficiency in convex economies
  • Exact or approximate surplus-maximization
  • Stable many-to-one matchings
  • Extra communication cost of incentives

28
Social Choice Problem
  • N set of agents, X set of outcomes
  • Agent is type is a preference relation Ri over
    X
  • State R (R1, , RN) 2 R1 RN R
  • Choice rule F R ? X
  • F(R) optimal outcomes in state R
  • Protocol verifies F if ?R 2 R ?x 2 F(R)
    ?m 2 M that is acceptable in state R and
    verifies x

?
fully
29
Verification by budget equilibria
x
  • Oracles message
  • Proposed outcome x ? X
  • Budget set Bi ? X for each agent i
  • Agent i accepts iff x is his optimal choice from
    Bi
  • i.e., Bi ? L(x, Ri) ?y 2 X x Ri y
  • Acceptance by all agents (equilibrium) must
    verify x

30
Verification by budget equilibria
x
  • Full verification ?R 2 R ?x 2 F(R)
  • ? budget equilibrium (B,x) verifying x in state
    R
  • E.g., Fundamental Welfare Theorems Any Pareto
    efficient allocation in a convex economy can be
    verified with a Walrasian equilibrium
  • Extend to other social choice problems?

31
Verification by budget equilibria
x
  • Larger budget sets ? more informative equilibrium
  • Definition F is monotonic if ?R?R ?x?F(R)
  • ?R'?R, L(x, Ri) ? L(x, Ri') ?i ? x?F(R').
  • Theorem F is fully verified with a budget
    equilibrium protocol ? F is monotonic.
  • Williams (1986), Greenberg (1990), Miyagawa
    (2002)

32
Necessity of budget equilibria?
x
  • Knowing R, could compute an optimal outcome
    directly, without using supporting budget sets
  • Can we construct budget equilibrium not just with
    full info, but from any verifying communication?

33
Necessity of budget equilibria?
x
ÅR2m L( x, R2)
ÅR2m L( x, R1)
Definition F has the Budget Revelation Property
if for any message verifying x there exists a
less informative budget equilibrium (B,x)
verifying x. Theorem F satisfies BRP ? F is
Intersection-Monotonic (stronger than
monotonicity).
34
Some choice rules satisfying BRP
  • Pareto efficiency
  • Approximate Pareto efficiency
  • The core
  • Stable matching
  • Envy-free
  • More generally Any CU rule described by
    coalitions blocking sets ?(x,S) ? X outcomes
    coalition S ? N can use to block candidate
    outcome x 2 X
  • x ? F(R) ? no coalition S ? N has a strict Pareto
    improvement over x within ?(x,S)

35
Venn Diagram
M verified with budget protocol
Pareto  
IM BRP
CU
Approx. Pareto  
Core  
No-Envy  
36
Social Choice Rules Boolean Representation
  • x ? F(R) can be written as a boolean formula
    with R atoms z Ri yy,z ? X, i ? N describing R
  • Using conjunctions (? AND), disjunctions (?
    OR), negations (? NOT)
  • F is monotonic ? need only use atoms
    x Ri yy ? X, i ? N , no negations
  • ? can be written in Monotone Disjunctive Normal
    Form ?? ? ? (? (i,y)?? (x Ri y))
  • ? ?R? F-1(x), MDNF can be verified with one of
    its clauses ? - a budget equilibrium (cf.
    Theorem 1)

37
Restrictions imposed by IM
  • Equivalently, for monotonic rules, x ? F(R) can
    also be written in Monotone Conjunctive Normal
    Form ?? ? ? (?(i,y)?? (x Ri y))
  • F is Intersection Monotonic ? can be written as
    MCNF whose disjunctive clauses ? dont contain
    (x Ri y) ? (x Ri z) with y ? z
  • Intuition if x ? F(R) is preserved by taking y
    or z individually out of L(x,Ri), should be
    preserved by taking out y and z together

38
Restrictions imposed by CU
  • F if CU ? x ? F(R) can be written as MCNF
    ?? ? ? (?(i,y)?? (x Ri y)) s.t. each clause ? has
    a single y
  • i.e., ? takes the form ?i?S (x Ri y)
  • Interpretation coalition S does not want to
    block x with y
  • i.e., does not contain (x Ri y)?(x Rj z) with y ?
    z
  • Characterizes monotonic choice rule that are
    binary, which means
  • calculate social relation S between ?x,y from
    agents preferences x Ri y (e.g., S not
    blocked by) IIA
  • Choose maximal elements in S from X
  • Note if we required S to be rational we would
    hit Arrows Impossibility Theorem

39
Lecture 3 Market Design Applications
40
Necessity of budget equilibria
x
  • Definition F has the Budget Revelation Property
    if for any message verifying x there exists a
    less informative budget equilibrium (B,x)
    verifying x.
  • Theorem F satisfies BRP ? F is
    Intersection-Monotonic.
  • Stronger than monotonicity, but satisfied by many
    choice rules e.g. Pareto, approx. Pareto, core,
    stability, envy-free all CU rules.

41
Intuition
  • Social goals congruent with private preferences
    ? minimize communication by asking agents to act
    on their knowledge selfishly within budget sets
    (cf. Hayek)
  • Design budget sets to coordinate choices and
    attain social goals with minimal communication

42
Minimally Informative Verifying Messages
R
x
  • Budget Revelation Property ? use budget
    equilibria
  • Minimize informativeness shrink budget sets
  • ? critical states R
  • Bi L(x, Ri) \ R'i ?Ri x?F(R'i, R-i) L(x,
    R'i) ?i
  • In such R, (B1,, BN, x) is a unique budget
    equilibrium verifying x (up to equivalence)

43
Market Design Roadmap
  • Use budget-shrinking algorithm to construct min.
    informative budget equilibria (B,x) verifying x
  • If Bi L(x, Ri) ?i for some R 2 R (critical
    state) ? minimal message space for full
    verification of F
  • To bound below simple verification cost - use
    tricks, e.g.,
  • Restrict to states R in which F(R) is a singleton
  • Construct a fooling set whose states cant share
    a verifying budget equilibrium
  • Verification cost very high ? problem is hopeless
  • Verification cost low ? Can it be achieved in a
    deterministic, incentive-compatible protocol?

44
Application Pareto Efficiency in Smooth Convex
Exchange Economies
  • L goods Ri over xi 2 RL convex, smooth, with a
    positive utility gradient

45
  • Proposition. m is a minimally informative message
    verifying the Pareto efficiency of an interior
    allocation in a smooth convex economy ? m is
    equivalent to a Walrasian equilibrium.
  • Any such equilibrium (B, x) is a unique Walrasian
    equilibrium supporting x
  • ? Number of variables for full verification
    (N-1)L quantities (L 1) prices

46
Verification Cost
  • Fix endowments ? (N-1)(L-1) quantities (L 1)
    prices N(L-1) numbers
  • Can we verify Pareto efficiency with fewer
    numbers?
  • Fooling set of Cobb-Douglas economies (Hurwicz)
  • Utilities ui (xi) ?l xilail with Sl ail 1
    for all i
  • Described with N(L -1) parameters
  • FOC for (p, x) being a Walrasian eqm
  • ail/aik (pl xil ) /(pk xik) for all l,k,I
  • No two distinct Cobb-Douglas economies share a
    Walrasian eqm ? give a fooling set for Pareto
    efficiency
  • What about deterministic communication?
  • Tatonnement converges fast in some but not all
    economies

47
Pareto Efficiency with Numeraire
  • x (k, t1,,tN ) feasibility Si ti 0
  • Ri 2 Ri given by quasilinear utility ui(k)ti
  • Efficiency maxk2K Si ui(k) (total surplus)

t2
t1
k
48
  • Proposition. m is a minimally informative message
    verifying efficiency with numeraire ? m is
    equivalent to a price equilibrium with
    personalized nonlinear prices p 2 ? NK s.t.
    ?i pi (k) const on k 2 K.
  • Each such price must be used in the critical
    state where Si ui(k) const on k 2 K
  • ? Cost (N 1)(K 1) real numbers full
    revelation of N 1 agents valuations
  • Combinatorial auctions N 2, K 2L ?
    communication cost 2L 1 numbers

49
Stable Many-to-one Matching
  • N consists of firms (F) and workers (W)
  • Matching x binary relation from F to W in which
    a worker matches with at most one firm
  • Ri 2 Ri depends only on is partners

x
50
Stable Matching
  • Matching is stable if these coalitional
    deviations are not strictly Pareto improving
  • Firm hires some new workers (and fires some)
  • Worker quits to become unemployed
  • This describes an IM choice rule

x
51
Minimally Informative Equilibria
  • A workers budget set described by available
    firms
  • A firms budget set available groups of workers
  • In a minimally informative equilibrium verifying
    stability, the groups consist of
  • The firms current workers
  • Workers who dont have the firm in their budget
    sets
  • ? firms budget sets, non-combinatorial

x
52
  • Lemma. m is a minimally informative message
    verifying the stability of matching x ? m is
    equivalent to a partitional equilibrium, in which
    each off-equilibrium match is in either partners
    budget set, but not both.
  • Any such equilibrium (B, x) is a unique
    partitional equilibrium supporting x in state R
    in which Bi L(x, Ri) ?i.
  • Cost of full verification 2FW bits
  • Cf. cost of describing a match x FW bits
  • Cf. describing firms preferences over 2W groups
    log2(2W)! W ?2W bits
  • Two questions
  • Is the cost of verification any lower?
  • Is the deterministic communication cost higher?

53
Verification cost is the same
  • Take any partitional equilibrium (B, x), and
    critical state R s.t. Bi L(x, Ri) ?i
  • Further restrict R to ensure that x is unique
    stable match
  • Each i strictly prefers his current match within
    Bi
  • Each i strictly prefers quitting to getting a new
    partner from Bi
  • Cant have a stable match x? ? x
  • i gets a new partner from Bi ? i would quit
  • i gets a new partner j ? Bi ? i 2 Bj ? j would
    quit
  • x? ? x ? x? is in all budget sets ? a coalition
    would block x? by x
  • ? (B, x) must be used for verification in state R
  • ? Communication cost 2FW bits
  • Same logic works for 1-to-1 matching (cost FW
    bits)
  • This bounds below deterministic communication
    cost

54
Deterministic Communication
  • This lower bound is almost achieved for
    substitutable preferences by Gale-Shapley
    deferred acceptance algorithm
  • ( 2FW steps matches offered, rejected)
  • Exponentially less than full revelation of firms
    combinatorial preferences
  • The algorithm also minimizes evaluation costs of
    the responding side (whose budget sets are
    minimized)
  • With uniformly drawn preferences, on average only
    1/3 of potential partners evaluated

55
Determinism vs. Nondeterminism
  • Recall Deterministic CC in bits
    nondeterministic CC in bits
  • Gap is at most exponential e.g., try each of
    the M oracles messages for acceptance instead of
    encoding with log2M bits
  • Gap is small in some cases e.g., matching or
    auctions with substitute preferences - monotonic
    tatonnement converges quickly
  • But there are IM rules with exponential gap

56
Example of Exponential Gap
  • 2 agents hire 2 out of 3m workers
  • Agent 1 is happy if the hired workers share a
    language
  • Agent 1 knows privately each workers language
  • Public knowledge all workers are monolingual, m
    languages spoken by a pair of workers, and m
    languages spoken by a single worker.
  • Agent 2 knows privately 2m1 capable workers
  • Agent 2 is happy 1 if both hired workers are
    capable
  • Social goal make both agents happy. - CU, IM.
  • Such pair always exists and can be verified by
    its announcement - 2 log2 (3m) bits
  • But deterministic CC is asymptotically
    proportional to m
  • Equivalent to the Pair-Disjointness.problem

57
Average-Case Goals
  • E.g., approximate expected surplus, given a
    probability distribution over states
  • Example discrete public good, N agents i.i.d.
    values vi 20,1, Prvi 1 ?, Cost c lt ?N.
  • N large ? building is efficient with prob.? 1
  • Verifying efficiency requires finding c agents to
    charge Lindahl price 1, takes c logN bits
  • for ? -approximation guarantee, (k-?) log2N bits
  • Government solution approximates expected
    efficiency without any communication, prices
    (cf. Groves-Hart)
  • Another Example with many decisions, authority
    may approximate expected efficiency when finding
    prices would take exponentially longer (cf.
    Coase, Simon)
  • Examples known in which expected-surplus
    approximation is hard to attain e.g.,
    combinatorial auctions

58
Economics without Incentives?
  • Thought experiment people are honest. Would
    basic economics institutions (markets, firms)
    remain?
  • Minimize communication by asking people to pursue
    self-interest guided by prices
  • ? Scope of market design
  • ? Required price space
  • Lower bounds on communication and evaluation
    costs
  • Average-case goals may yield non-market
    institutions (governments, firms)

59
Lecture 4Communication Cost of Incentives
60
So far
  • Can calculate communication costs of many
    economic problems
  • E.g., use the Budget Revelation Property,
    construct min. informative verifying budget
    equilibria
  • In some cases, cost is prohibitive, ? cost of
    full revelation of preferences
  • E.g., combinatorial auctions with general
    valuations need whole combinatorial price space
  • In other cases, cost is manageable
  • E.g., auctions or matching with substitute
    preferences enough to use individual
    prices/budget sets
  • Can we then construct an incentive-compatible
    mechanism?

61
Incentives and Prices
  • Budget set in mechanism design set of agents
    attainable outcomes
  • E.g. Menus Taxation Principle
  • Incentives agent maximizes utility within his
    budget set
  • Remarkable even with no incentives (truthful
    agents), must still describe budget sets, ask
    agents to maximize own utility within them
  • For social goals that are congruent with
    preferences

62
Nash implementation
  • Agents preferences commonly known (but not to
    designer)
  • Mechanism g M1? ? MN ? X
  • (Full) implementation Set of Nash Equilibria
    F(R) ?R 2 R
  • m is NE of g ? (B, x) is a budget equilibrium,
    where xg(m), Bi g(mi?,m-i) mi? 2 Mi ?i
  • ? A Nash protocol is a budget protocol
  • Theorem 1 ? Any Nash implementable F is monotonic
  • Even with symmetric info, selfishness ? reveal
    budget sets
  • Proposition Communication cost of Nash
    implementation ? communication cost of full
    realization
  • May not hold for extensive-form mechanisms (in
    which strategies m are not revealed)

63
Communication Cost of (1-stage) Nash
implementation
  • Monotonicity ? Nash implementability
    (not every budget equilibrium protocol is a Nash
    protocol)
  • But is almost sufficient
  • Definition F has No Veto Power (NVP) if i
    xRiy ?y 2 Y ? N 1 ? x 2 F(R).
  • Trivial in economic applications with N ? 3
  • Maskin (1977) Any monotonic NVP choice rule is
    Nash implementable
  • Proposition If F is IM and NVP,
    communication cost of Nash implementation ? N
    ? (communication cost of full realization)
    log2N.

64
Proof Mechanism
  • Let ? minimal space of budget equilibria fully
    verifying F
  • Each agent i announces (Ei, li), where Ei
    (B1i,, BNi, xi) 2 ?, li 2 1,, N
  • E1 EN (B1,, BN, x) ? implement x
  • Ej (B1,, BN, x) ?j?i and xi ? Bi ? implement x
  • Ej (B1,, BN, x) ?j?i and xi 2 Bi ? implement
    xi
  • Otherwise implement xi for i (?j lj ) modN 1
  • x 2 F(R) ? all agents announcing the same
    equilibrium (B1,, BN, x) 2 ? in state R is a NE
  • Case-1 NE (B1,, BN, x) verifies x, is a budget
    eqm in state R ? x 2 F(R)
  • Other cases all but (perhaps) one agent could
    deviate to Case 4 to get his best outcome ? by
    NVP, x 2 F(R)

65
  • May further reduce cost e.g. by letting Bi be
    announced only by agent i modN1
  • McKelvey, Reiter-Reichelstein
  • Key each agents budget set must be determined
    by others messages prevent price
    manipulation
  • With private information, incentives require
    constructing Bi without using is info ? extra
    communication cost

66
Communication Cost of Selfishness (with Ron Fadel)
  • Incentive-Compatibility with private information
  • Ex Post IC Each agents strategy is optimal
    given others even if he knew other agents types
  • Weaker than Dominant-Strategy IC in an extensive
    form, dont consider others unused strategies
  • Bayesian IC Each agents strategy is optimal
    given others on expectation over their types

67
Communication Cost of Selfishness
  • CCS (Minimal Communication Cost of an
    Incentive-Compatible mechanism) - Communication
    Complexity
  • Related work Reichelstein 1984, Green and
    Laffont 1987, Lahaie and Parkes 2004, Feigenbaum
    el al. 2004, Johari 2004

68
Setup
  • Quasilinear payoffs ui(y)ti, with y 2 Y
  • ui 2 Ui ½ ?Y - private type of agent i
  • Types drawn independently (basic model)
  • Decision function f U1 UI ! Y
  • Dont care about transfers

69
Communication Protocols
y1
y2
u1'
u1'
u1
u1
y3
y4
y5
Communication cost
3 bits (worst-case)
  • Binary extensive-form message game (tree)
  • Agents (type-contingent) strategies
  • Outcomes assigned to leaves

70
Incentivizing a Protocol
, t11, t21
y1
, t12 , t22
y2
2
1
, t13, t23
1
y3
, t14, t24
y4
2
, t15, t25
y5
  • Assign incentivizing payments to the leaves
  • Hide history (create Information Sets) to prevent
    contingent deviations
  • A given protocol may not be incentivizable may
    need more communication

71
Sources of CCS
  • EPIC No need to hide info CCS comes from the
    need to compute payments
  • BIC CCS comes from need to hide info (computing
    payments does not require extra bits)
  • Restrict to f that is implementable in some IC
    mechanism (e.g. full revelation)
  • for others, CCS 1

72
A Protocol that cant be EPIC incentivized
  • Allocate one object between two agents
  • efficiently values v1 2 1,2,3,4, v2 2 0,5.
  • Protocol
  • Agent 1 announces v1 (2 bits)
  • Agent 2 takes iff v2 v1 (1 bit)
  • Intuition for EPIC, agent 1 must be charged a
    price within 1 of v2, but it is not revealed
  • Can show that any EPIC protocol must take 3
    bits ? EPIC CCS 1
  • A similar example for BIC

73
An Upper Bound on CCS(both BIC and EPIC)
  • Take a protocol P computing f (which is
    implementable)
  • Can incentivize agents if observe their
    strategies in P
  • Transfers need only depend on the strategies
  • Punish strategies that are not consistent with
    any type
  • Protocol in which all agents simultaneously
    announce their strategies in P is incentivizable

74
An Upper Bound on CCS(both BIC and EPIC)
y1
y2
2
1
1
y3
y4
2
y5
  • A d-bit protocol P has 2d decision nodes ?
    agents strategies can be described with 2d
    bits
  • ? Comm. Complexity with IC 2Comm. Complexity
  • Is the bound tight? For EPIC, open question

75
Example Low CCS for Efficiency
  • f(u) solves maxy ?i ui(y)
  • Let agents announce final utilities wi ui(y),
    pay each agent ti ?j?i wj
  • ? Agents become a team
  • ? Efficient protocol is EPIC
  • ? Even if cant reach full efficiency, strategies
    maximizing expected surplus form a BNE
  • Also, any EPIC implementable f (e.g., efficiency)
    has BIC CCS 0

76
Exponential Bound reached for BIC
Boss
  • Expert privately knows 1-to-1 mapping between K
    decisions and K consequences
  • Also has a private utility over decisions
  • Boss privately knows desired consequence

77
Bound is reached for BIC
Expert
4
5
2
3
1
Decisions
Consequences
Boss
  • A simple protocol
  • Boss announces desired consequence (logK bits),
  • Expert decides (logK bits)
  • Not BIC Expert will maximize own utility

78
Bound is reached for BIC
Boss
  • A BIC protocol
  • Expert reveals mapping
  • ( log(K!)KlogK bits exponentially longer)
  • Boss decides
  • We show that any BIC protocol takes K/2 bits
    - exponentially longer than the simple protocol

79
Extensions CCS is unbounded for
  • Average-case communication complexity
  • Example allocate object efficiently between 2
    agents with values uniformly drawn from 0,1
  • Bisection takes on expectation 4 bits (Arrow et
    al.)
  • EPIC for Agent 1 requires essentially charging
    him agent 2s value, which has unbounded entropy
  • BIC CCS with Correlated Types
  • Example Agent 1 has large type that determines
    binary outcome and correlates with Agent 2s type
  • BIC must punish Agent 1 when caught lying by
    Agent 2
  • EPIC CCS with Interdependent Valuations
    vi(x,si,s-i), where si is agent is type
  • Example Agent 1 knows whether he should get the
    object but his value for it is known only to
    Agent 2
  • EPIC requires charging Agent 1 this value

80
Open Questions
  • EPIC CCS how high can it be?
  • In what practical problems is CCS low?
  • Can CCS be reduced substantially if ICs only need
    to be satisfied approximately (equivalently,
    utilities given with finite precision)?

81
Ideas for understanding firms
  • Coase (1937), Simon (1951) firms are islands of
    authority where discovering what the relevant
    prices are is too costly
  • Have example where authority achieves efficiency
    with probability ? 1, but verifying it (finding
    prices) takes exponentially more bits
  • Communication may be distributed to economize on
    individual costs
  • Individual costs may be reduced by hiring extra
    agents (managers) to relay prices (cf.
    computational models of Radner - van Zandt)
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)
About PowerShow.com