Title: Chapter 5Choice
1Chapter 5 Choice
- Course Microeconomics
- Text Varians Intermediate Microeconomics
2Economic Rationality
- The principal behavioral postulate is that a
decision-maker chooses its most preferred
alternative from those available to it. - The available choices constitute the budget set.
- How is the most preferred bundle in the budget
set located?
3Rational Constrained Choice
x2
x1
4Rational Constrained Choice
Utility
x2
x1
5Rational Constrained Choice
Utility
Affordable, but not the most preferred affordable
bundle.
x2
x1
6Rational Constrained Choice
The most preferredof the affordable bundles.
Utility
Affordable, but not the most preferred affordable
bundle.
x2
x1
7Rational Constrained Choice
x2
One will choose the bundle on the outermost
indifference curve. Therefore, it is the one that
just touch the budget constraint.
Affordablebundles
x1
8Rational Constrained Choice
x2
(x1,x2) is the mostpreferred affordablebundle.
x2
x1
x1
9Rational Constrained Choice
- The most preferred affordable bundle is called
the consumers ORDINARY DEMAND at the given
prices and budget. - Ordinary demands will be denoted byx1(p1,p2,m)
and x2(p1,p2,m).
10Rational Constrained Choice
- When x1 gt 0 and x2 gt 0 the demanded bundle is
INTERIOR. - If buying (x1,x2) costs m then the budget is
exhausted.
11Rational Constrained Choice
- Assuming monotonicity and smooth indifference
curve, for an interior solution (x1,x2), it
satisfies two conditions - (a) the budget is exhausted p1x1
p2x2 m - (b) the slope of the budget constraint, -p1/p2,
and the slope of the indifference curve
containing (x1,x2) are equal at (x1,x2).
12Rational Constrained Choice
- Condition (b) can be written as
- So, at the optimal choice, the marginal
willingness to pay for an extra unit of good 1 in
terms of good 2 is the same as the price you
actually need to pay. - If the price is lower than your willingness to
pay, you would buy more, otherwise buy less.
Adjust until they are equal.
13Mathematical Formulation
The consumer problem can be formulated
mathematically as
One way to solve is to use Lagrangian method
14Mathematical Treatment
- Assuming the utility function is differentiable,
and there exists interior solution - The first order conditions are
15Mathematical Treatment
- So, we have the same condition as before that MRS
equals price ratio.
16Mathematical Treatment
- So, for interior solution, we can solve for the
optimal bundle using the two conditions
17Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas
Example.
- Suppose that the consumer has Cobb-Douglas
preferences. - Then
18Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas
Example.
- So the MRS is
- At (x1,x2), MRS p1/p2 so
19Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas
Example.
(A)
(B)
20Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas
Example.
(A)
Substitute
(B)
and get
This simplifies to .
21Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas
Example.
22Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas
Example.
Substituting for x1 in
then gives
23Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas
Example.
So we have discovered that the mostpreferred
affordable bundle for a consumerwith
Cobb-Douglas preferences
is
24Computing Ordinary Demands - a Cobb-Douglas
Example.
x2
x1
25Demand for Cobb-Douglas Utility Function
- With the optimal bundle
- Note the expenditures on each good
- It is a property of Cobb-Douglas Utility function
that expenditure share on a particular good is a
constant.
26Special Example
27Special Examples
1. Tangency condition is only necessary but not
sufficient.
2. There can be more than one optimum.
3. Strict Convexity implies unique solution.
28Corner Solution
- But what if x1 0?
- Or if x2 0?
- If either x1 0 or x2 0 then the ordinary
demand (x1,x2) is at a corner solution to the
problem of maximizing utility subject to a budget
constraint. - E.g. it happens when the indifference curves are
too flat or steep relative to the budget line.
29Special Example
The indifference curves are too steep in this
case to touch the budget line. The willingness to
pay for good 2 is still lower than the price of
good 2 even when x2 is zero.
30Corner Solution
- The mathematical treatment for corner solution is
more complicated. - We have to consider also the inequality
constraints. (x1 0 and x2 0) - We skip the details here.
31Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Perfect
Substitutes Case
x2
MRS 1
x1
32Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Perfect
Substitutes Case
x2
MRS 1
Slope -p1/p2 with p1 gt p2.
x1
33Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Perfect
Substitutes Case
x2
MRS 1
Slope -p1/p2 with p1 gt p2.
x1
34Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Perfect
Substitutes Case
x2
MRS 1
Slope -p1/p2 with p1 gt p2.
x1
35Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Perfect
Substitutes Case
x2
MRS 1
Slope -p1/p2 with p1 lt p2.
x1
36Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Perfect
Substitutes Case
So when U(x1,x2) x1 x2, the mostpreferred
affordable bundle is (x1,x2)where
if p1 lt p2
and
if p1 gt p2.
37Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Perfect
Substitutes Case
x2
MRS 1
Slope -p1/p2 with p1 p2.
x1
38Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Perfect
Substitutes Case
x2
All the bundles in the constraint are equally
the most preferred affordable when
p1 p2.
x1
39Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Non-Convex
Preferences Case
x2
Better
x1
40Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Non-Convex
Preferences Case
x2
x1
41Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Non-Convex
Preferences Case
x2
Which is the most preferredaffordable bundle?
x1
42Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Non-Convex
Preferences Case
x2
The most preferredaffordable bundle
x1
43Examples of Corner Solutions -- the Non-Convex
Preferences Case
Notice that the tangency solutionis not the
most preferred affordablebundle.
x2
The most preferredaffordable bundle
x1
44Examples of Kinky Solutions -- the Perfect
Complements Case
U(x1,x2) minax1,x2
x2
x2 ax1
x1
45Examples of Kinky Solutions -- the Perfect
Complements Case
U(x1,x2) minax1,x2
x2
MRS -
x2 ax1
MRS 0
x1
46Examples of Kinky Solutions -- the Perfect
Complements Case
U(x1,x2) minax1,x2
x2
MRS -
MRS is undefined
x2 ax1
MRS 0
x1
47Examples of Kinky Solutions -- the Perfect
Complements Case
U(x1,x2) minax1,x2
x2
x2 ax1
x1
48Examples of Kinky Solutions -- the Perfect
Complements Case
U(x1,x2) minax1,x2
x2
Which is the mostpreferred affordable bundle?
x2 ax1
x1
49Examples of Kinky Solutions -- the Perfect
Complements Case
U(x1,x2) minax1,x2
x2
The most preferred affordable bundle
x2 ax1
x1
50Examples of Kinky Solutions -- the Perfect
Complements Case
U(x1,x2) minax1,x2
x2
(a) p1x1 p2x2 m(b) x2 ax1
x2 ax1
x2
x1
x1
51Examples of Kinky Solutions -- the Perfect
Complements Case
(a) p1x1 p2x2 m (b) x2 ax1.
-Intuitively, it is clear to have (b) because we
dont want to spend money on something that
cannot raise my utility.
-Substitution from (b) for x2 in (a) gives
p1x1 p2ax1 mwhich gives
52Examples of Kinky Solutions -- the Perfect
Complements Case
U(x1,x2) minax1,x2
x2
x2 ax1
x1
53Implications of MRS condition
- Recall
- As price is the same for all individuals, every
individual has the same MRS at the optimal
consumption bundle, even if they have very
different preferences. - Thus, it can be interpreted as a social
willingness to pay for good 1 in terms of good 2.
54Summary
- In this chapter we put together budget constraint
and preference together to analyze consumption
decision. - Typically, if we have interior solution, then the
optimal condition is MRSp1 / p2. - It can also have corner solution if one good is
not consumed at all.
55Whats next?
- Next, we will look at comparative statics.
- In particular, how will prices and income changes
affect the optimal consumption bundle?