Title: INCOME AND SUBSTITUTION EFFECTS
1Chapter 5
- INCOME AND SUBSTITUTION EFFECTS
2Objectives
- How will changes in prices and income influence
influence consumers optimal choices? - We will look at partial derivatives
3Demand Functions (review)
- We have already seen how to obtain consumers
optimal choice - Consumers optimal choice was computed Max
consumers utility subject to the budget
constraint - After solving this problem, we obtained that
optimal choices depend on prices of all goods and
income. - We usually call the formula for the optimal
choice the demand function - For example, in the case of the Complements
utility function, we obtained that the demand
function (optimal choice) is
4Demand Functions
- If we work with a generic utility function (we do
not know its mathematical formula), then we
express the demand function as
x x(px,py,I) y y(px,py,I)
- We will keep assuming that prices and income is
exogenous, that is - the individual has no control over these
parameters
5Simple property of demand functions
- If we were to double all prices and income, the
optimal quantities demanded will not change - Notice that the budget constraint does not change
(the slope does not change, the crossing with the
axis do not change either) - xi di(px,py,I) di(2px,2py,2I)
6Changes in Income
- Since px/py does not change, the MRS will stay
constant - An increase in income will cause the budget
constraint out in a parallel fashion (MRS stays
constant)
7What is a Normal Good?
- A good xi for which ?xi/?I ? 0 over some range of
income is a normal good in that range
8Normal goods
- If both x and y increase as income rises, x and y
are normal goods
Quantity of y
As income rises, the individual chooses to
consume more x and y
Quantity of x
9What is an inferior Good?
- A good xi for which ?xi/?I lt 0 over some range of
income is an inferior good in that range
10Inferior good
- If x decreases as income rises, x is an inferior
good
As income rises, the individual chooses to
consume less x and more y
Quantity of y
Quantity of x
11Changes in a Goods Price
- A change in the price of a good alters the slope
of the budget constraint (px/py) - Consequently, it changes the MRS at the
consumers utility-maximizing choices - When a price changes, we can decompose consumers
reaction in two effects - substitution effect
- income effect
12Substitution and Income effects
- Even if the individual remained on the same
indifference curve when the price changes, his
optimal choice will change because the MRS must
equal the new price ratio - the substitution effect
- The price change alters the individuals real
income and therefore he must move to a new
indifference curve - the income effect
13Sign of substitution effect (SE)
- SE is always negative, that is, if price
increases, the substitution effect makes quantity
to decrease and conversely. See why - 1) Assume px decreases, so px1lt px0
- 2) MRS(x0,y0) px0/ py0 MRS(x1,y1) px1/ py0
- 1 and 2 implies that
- MRS(x1,y1)ltMRS(x0,y0)
- As the MRS is decreasing in x, this means that x
has increased, that is x1gtx0 -
-
14Changes in the optimal choice when a price
decreases
Quantity of y
Quantity of x
15Substitution effect when a price decreases
Quantity of y
The individual substitutes good x for good y
because it is now relatively cheaper
A
U1
Quantity of x
16Income effect when the price decreases
The income effect occurs because the individuals
real income changes (hence utility changes)
when the price of good x changes
Quantity of y
If x is a normal good, the individual will buy
more because real income increased
A
C
U2
U1
Quantity of x
How would the graph change if the good was
inferior?
17Subs and income effects when a price increases
Quantity of y
An increase in the price of good x means that the
budget constraint gets steeper
A
B
U1
U2
Quantity of x
How would the graph change if the good was
inferior?
18Price Changes forNormal Goods
- If a good is normal, substitution and income
effects reinforce one another - when price falls, both effects lead to a rise in
quantity demanded - when price rises, both effects lead to a drop in
quantity demanded
19Price Changes forInferior Goods
- If a good is inferior, substitution and income
effects move in opposite directions - The combined effect is indeterminate
- when price rises, the substitution effect leads
to a drop in quantity demanded, but the income
effect is opposite - when price falls, the substitution effect leads
to a rise in quantity demanded, but the income
effect is opposite
20Giffens Paradox
- If the income effect of a price change is strong
enough, there could be a positive relationship
between price and quantity demanded - an increase in price leads to a drop in real
income - since the good is inferior, a drop in income
causes quantity demanded to rise
21A Summary
- Utility maximization implies that (for normal
goods) a fall in price leads to an increase in
quantity demanded - the substitution effect causes more to be
purchased as the individual moves along an
indifference curve - the income effect causes more to be purchased
because the resulting rise in purchasing power
allows the individual to move to a higher
indifference curve - Obvious relation hold for a rise in price
22A Summary
- Utility maximization implies that (for inferior
goods) no definite prediction can be made for
changes in price - the substitution effect and income effect move in
opposite directions - if the income effect outweighs the substitution
effect, we have a case of Giffens paradox
23Compensated Demand Functions
- This is a new concept
- It is the solution to the following problem
- MIN PXX PYY
- SUBJECT TO U(X,Y)U0
- Basically, the compensated demand functions are
the solution to the Expenditure Minimization
problem that we saw in the previous chapter - After solving this problem, we obtained that
optimal choices depend on prices of all goods and
utility. We usually call the formula the
compensated demand function - x xc(px,py,U),
- y yc(px,py,U)
24Compensated Demand Functions
- xc(px,py,U0), and yc(px,py,U0) tell us what
quantities of x and y minimize the expenditure
required to achieve utility level U0 at current
prices px,py - Notice that the following relation must hold
- pxxc(px,py,U0) pyyc(px,py,U0)E(px,py,U0)
- So this is another way of computing the
expenditure function !!!!
25Compensated Demand Functions
- There are two mathematical tricks to obtain the
compensated demand function without the need to
solve the problem - MIN PXX PYY
- SUBJECT TO U(X,Y)U0
- One trick(A) (called Shephards Lemma) is using
the derivative of the expenditure function - Another trick(B) is to use the marshallian demand
and the expenditure function
26Compensated Demand Functions
- Sheppards Lema to obtain the compensated demand
function
Intuition a 1 increase in px raises necessary
expenditures by x pounds, because 1 must be paid
for each unit of x purchased. Proof footnote 5
in page 137
27Trick (B) to obtain compensated demand functions
28Trick (B) to obtain compensated demand functions
- Suppose that utility is given by
- utility U(x,y) x0.5y0.5
- The Marshallian demand functions are
- x I/2px y I/2py
- The expenditure function is
29Another trick to obtain compensated demand
functions
- Substitute the expenditure function into the
Marshallian demand functions, and find the
compensated ones
30Compensated Demand Functions
- Demand now depends on utility (V) rather than
income - Increases in px changes the amount of x demanded,
keeping utility V constant. Hence the compensated
demand function only includes the substitution
effect but not the income effect
31Roys identity
- It is the relation between marshallian demand
function and indirect utility function
Proof of the Roys identity
32Proof of Roys identity
33Demand curves
- We will start to talk about demand curves. Notice
that they are not the same that demand functions
!!!!
34The Marshallian Demand Curve
- An individuals demand for x depends on
preferences, all prices, and income - x x(px,py,I)
- It may be convenient to graph the individuals
demand for x assuming that income and the price
of y (py) are held constant
35The Marshallian Demand Curve
Quantity of y
As the price of x falls...
px
Quantity of x
Quantity of x
36The Marshallian Demand Curve
- The Marshallian demand curve shows the
relationship between the price of a good and the
quantity of that good purchased by an individual
assuming that all other determinants of demand
are held constant - Notice that demand curve and demand function is
not the same thing!!!
37Shifts in the Demand Curve
- Three factors are held constant when a demand
curve is derived - income
- prices of other goods (py)
- the individuals preferences
- If any of these factors change, the demand curve
will shift to a new position
38Shifts in the Demand Curve
- A movement along a given demand curve is caused
by a change in the price of the good - a change in quantity demanded
- A shift in the demand curve is caused by changes
in income, prices of other goods, or preferences - a change in demand
39Compensated Demand Curves
- An alternative approach holds utility constant
while examining reactions to changes in px - the effects of the price change are compensated
with income so as to constrain the individual to
remain on the same indifference curve - reactions to price changes include only
substitution effects (utility is kept constant)
40Marshallian Demand Curves
- The actual level of utility varies along the
demand curve - As the price of x falls, the individual moves to
higher indifference curves - it is assumed that nominal income is held
constant as the demand curve is derived - this means that real income rises as the price
of x falls
41Compensated Demand Curves
- A compensated (Hicksian) demand curve shows the
relationship between the price of a good and the
quantity purchased assuming that other prices and
utility are held constant - The compensated demand curve is a two-dimensional
representation of the compensated demand function - x xc(px,py,U)
42Compensated Demand Curves
Holding utility constant, as price falls...
Quantity of y
px
Quantity of x
Quantity of x
43Compensated Uncompensated Demand for normal
goods
px
x
xc
Quantity of x
44Compensated Uncompensated Demand for normal
goods
px
px
x
xc
Quantity of x
As we are looking at normal goods, income and
substitution effects go in the same direction, so
they are reinforced. X includes both while Xc
only the substitution effect. That is what drives
the relative position of both curves
45Compensated Uncompensated Demand for normal
goods
px
px
x
xc
As we are looking at normal goods, income and
substitution effects go in the same direction, so
they are reinforced. X includes both while Xc
only the substitution effect. That is what drives
the relative position of both curves
Quantity of x
46Compensated Uncompensated Demand
- For a normal good, the compensated demand curve
is less responsive to price changes than is the
uncompensated demand curve - the uncompensated demand curve reflects both
income and substitution effects - the compensated demand curve reflects only
substitution effects
47Relations to keep in mind
- Sheppards Lema Roys identity
- V(px,py,E(px,py,Uo)) U0
- E(px,py,V(px,py,I0)) I0
- xc(px,py,U0)x(px,py,I0)
48A Mathematical Examination of a Change in Price
- Our goal is to examine how purchases of good x
change when px changes - ?x/?px
- Differentiation of the first-order conditions
from utility maximization can be performed to
solve for this derivative
49A Mathematical Examination of a Change in Price
- However, for our purpose, we will use an indirect
approach - Remember the expenditure function
- minimum expenditure E(px,py,U)
- Then, by definition
- xc (px,py,U) x px,py,E(px,py,U)
- quantity demanded is equal for both demand
functions when income is exactly what is needed
to attain the required utility level
50A Mathematical Examination of a Change in Price
xc (px,py,U) xpx,py,E(px,py,U)
- We can differentiate the compensated demand
function and get
51A Mathematical Examination of a Change in Price
- The first term is the slope of the compensated
demand curve - the mathematical representation of the
substitution effect
52A Mathematical Examination of a Change in Price
- The second term measures the way in which changes
in px affect the demand for x through changes in
purchasing power - the mathematical representation of the income
effect
53The Slutsky Equation
- The substitution effect can be written as
- The income effect can be written as
54The Slutsky Equation
- A price change can be represented by
55The Slutsky Equation
- The first term is the substitution effect
- always negative as long as MRS is diminishing
- the slope of the compensated demand curve must be
negative
56The Slutsky Equation
- The second term is the income effect
- if x is a normal good, then ?x/?I gt 0
- the entire income effect is negative
- if x is an inferior good, then ?x/?I lt 0
- the entire income effect is positive
57A Slutsky Decomposition
- We can demonstrate the decomposition of a price
effect using the Cobb-Douglas example studied
earlier - The Marshallian demand function for good x was
58A Slutsky Decomposition
- The Hicksian (compensated) demand function for
good x was
- The overall effect of a price change on the
demand for x is
59A Slutsky Decomposition
- This total effect is the sum of the two effects
that Slutsky identified - The substitution effect is found by
differentiating the compensated demand function
60A Slutsky Decomposition
- We can substitute in for the indirect utility
function (V)
61A Slutsky Decomposition
- Calculation of the income effect is easier
- By adding up substitution and income effect, we
will obtain the overall effect