Title: PHARMACEUTICAL PRICING POLICY PROJECT Executive Summary and Conclusions
1PHARMACEUTICAL PRICING POLICY PROJECT
Executive Summary and Conclusions
- Valérie Paris
- Warsaw
- 19 March 2008
2OECD pharmaceutical pricing policy
project2005-2007
- Objective Assess the cross-national impact of
national pricing and reimbursement policies in
OECD countries - Impact on availability and prices of drugs in
other countries - Impact on innovation
- Outputs
- Case studies Canada, Mexico, Slovak Republic,
Sweden, Switzerland (working papers available on
OECDs website) and Germany (forthcoming). - Final report to be published in June 2008
3More than half of OECD countries had per capita
spending on pharmaceuticals within 20 of the
OECD average in 2005
(1) 2004 (2) 2003 (3) 2005 pharmaceutical sales
per capita
Source OECD HEALTH DATA 2007, July 07
4Retail pharmaceutical prices vary between -30 to
85 of the OECD average
Note Prices were converted to a common currency
using the 2005 average exchange rate
Source Eurostat-OECD Purchasing Power Parity
Programme, 2007, Pharmaceutical Pricing Project
Final Report, forthcoming
5Limited cross-national variation is also seen in
pharmaceutical consumption levels, but the range
is somewhat larger than it is for expenditures
Real pharmaceutical expenditure per capita, 2005
Source Eurostat-OECD Purchasing Power Parity
Programme, 2007 OECD Health Data 2007, July 07
Pharmaceutical Pricing Project
Final Report, forthcoming
6Per capita income explains only one quarter of
the variability observed in per capita volumes of
consumption across OECD countries
Note Data from Japan, Hungary and Australia are
from 2004. Source Pharmaceutical Pricing Project
Final Report, forthcoming
7Characteristics of pharmaceutical spending
- Pharmaceutical expenditures increased faster than
total health expenditures and faster than GDP
between 1980 and 2005 - Most rapid period of growth in late 1990s, has
since slowed - Pharmaceutical expenditures account for 17 of
total health expenditures and 1.5 of GDP, on
average, in OECD countries - but represent about one-third of THE and
more than 2 of GDP in Hungary, the Slovak
Republic and Portugal -
- Private financing accounts for 40 of
pharmaceutical spending in OECD countries - The share of expenditure financed out-of-pocket
is relatively high, compared to other types of
services
8Pharmaceutical market characteristics
- In 2006, the top 10 firms accounted for nearly
50 of global sales - Generic products account for 14 of the global
market value, despite accounting for 40 or more
of units sold in several of the largest markets
--- very significant variation across countries - Original products have a longer life-cycle in
countries where they do not face significant
competition upon patent expiry - Prices received by manufacturers for their
products vary across countries - Japan, Switzerland and the United States have
been found to have high ex-factory prices for
on-patent drugs - Nevertheless, convergence of list prices over
time has been observed --- especially in Europe,
Switzerland, Canada --- and especially for the
most innovative products - The pharmaceutical industry plays an important
role in the economies of several OECD countries
(location of headquarters, production facilities,
RD activities)
9The United States account for 45 of worldwide
sales, followed by Japan (9), Germany and France
(5), United Kingdom and Italy (4)
Source IMS Health (2007), Intelligence.360
Global pharmaceutical perspectives 2006.
10RD investments and outcomes
- The output of RD investments has stabilised at a
level lower than was seen during the mid-80s,
despite increased investment, resulting in a
decline in RD productivity - Most pharmaceutical innovation is (as in other
industries) incremental, with most new products
offering little or no added therapeutic value
over existing treatments - Innovation is perceived as not always aligned
with public health priorities
11Pharmaceutical industrys strategy
- The objective is to maximise profit over a
products life cycle, by - Launching as quickly as possible in profitable
markets - Pricing as high as possible according to market
conditions and regulatory constraints - Trying to extend the period of market exclusivity
- Engaging in promotional activities to grow the
market and gain market share - Firms have traditionally sought to maximise their
rents by segmenting markets and differentiating
their sales prices according to purchasers
ability and willingness to pay, within and across
countries, to the extent possible
12Manufacturers responses to globalisation of the
pharmaceutical market
- The circulation of information on prices and
threat of parallel and cross-border trade have
reduced opportunities for market segmentation - In response, manufacturers have developed
strategies, such as - Strategic launch
- Strategies to reduce parallel trade, where it is
permitted, and cross-border trade (such as
product proliferation, supply chain management,
lobbying, etc.) - Strategies to avoid external benchmarking
(product proliferation, confidential rebates)
13The global market for pharmaceuticals market
power of buyers and sellers
- Pharmaceutical products are launched in 10
countries, on average - No purchaser is in a monopsony position in the
global market, as numerous purchasers exist for
any given product - Patent protection gives firms exclusive rights to
manufacture their products, but their monopoly
position may be weakened by competition in a
therapeutic area - Market power of payers/purchasers linked to
- The number of covered lives and
willingness/ability to pay - Insurers ability to influence the volume and mix
of drugs used - Is the insurer obliged to cover all products
meeting criteria for reimbursement? - Does the insurer have the ability to designate
products as preferred or to restrict coverage to
particular circumstances?
14Pharmaceutical pricing policy in OECD countries
- Some countries regulate prices of on-patent drugs
to protect consumers against the risk of
manufacturers exploiting their monopoly position - Many public purchasers set or limit the prices of
reimbursed medicines in exchange for subsidy (de
facto regulation) - Manufacturers have the option of not submitting
their products for reimbursement, but instead
marketing their products directly to consumers
(at the cost of losing insurance subsidy) - Free or market-based pricing is often the rule
for OTC products and for products that are not
reimbursed, rarely also for products that are
reimbursed
15Techniques used in OECD countries to define or
limit prices or reimbursement prices
- International benchmarking - other
payers/purchasers used as a reference - Internal referencing other products used as a
reference - In therapeutic referencing, the price for new
products is defined in comparison to therapeutic
alternatives - Under so-called reference pricing, a common
reimbursement level is set for a defined group of
products (patients pay the difference) - Pharmaco-economic assessment price based on
considerations of the products
cost-effectiveness (net benefits against costs) - Tendering seller defines price
- Indirect price control (profit control)
16More sophisticated approaches are used on a
limited or experimental basis
- Some countries or purchasers experiment with
approaches such as - Product-specific price-volume agreements,
especially with products with high risk of
overuse or misuse - Risk-sharing agreements link the price paid to
the outcome for products with high uncertainty as
to effectiveness of a product in actual experience
17Outcomes of price or reimbursement price
regulation
- Regulators often have objectives other than
cost-containment (such as ensuring prompt access
to effective medicines, support national
industry, encourage future innovation, etc.) - and do not always seek to obtain the lowest
possible price - Private payers face strong incentives to
negotiate the lowest possible price - Outcome depends on relative market power
- Beyond pricing policy, many other policies affect
the pharmaceutical market (marketing
authorisation, IPR standards and enforcement,
formularies and cost-sharing requirements,
policies directed to pharmacists and prescribing
doctors)
18Shortfalls in access to effective medicines exist
even in OECD countries
- Gaps in coverage in some countries, some people
are uninsured or under-insured, even in case of
catastrophic expenditures and may face financial
barriers - Some effective medicines are not subsidised
because of budgetary constraints
19OECD countries have scope to improve the value
for money in their pharmaceutical expenditures
- Experience from OECD countries demonstrates the
potential to - Improve the use of generic alternatives
- Foster the erosion of off-patent products prices
through competition - Achieve more efficient distribution systems for
prescription and OTC drugs - Use more sophisticated reimbursement pricing
strategies
20Pros and cons of current policies
- International benchmarking
- Does not take into account cross-country
differences in the value of a product - Readily gameable by the pharmaceutical industry
- Has reduced the ability to price to market and
contributed to convergence of list prices, likely
resulting in list price inflation - Provides manufacturers with incentives to delay
launch in lower-priced markets where there is
risk of spill-over - Confidential rebates
- Have been more and more used by purchasers
because of international benchmarking and because
of the threat of parallel and cross-border trade - They create some confusion in international
benchmarking, resulting in artificial list
prices
21Pros and cons of current policies (contd)
- Therapeutic referencing can promote
value-for-money provided that - Existing alternatives are priced at a level which
reflects their value to society - Information about the relative added value of
the new product over existing alternatives is
available - Reference pricing should have similar
attributes, but - Consumers may not have information needed to
judge relative value and physician decision may
not reflect patient preferences - Manufacturers may therefore price at common
reimbursement level to avoid losing market share - If reference price is set too high, it may
restrain price competition/generic price erosion
by creating a floor
22Pros and cons of current policies (contd)
- The use of pharmaco-economic assessment
- Provides policy makers with information needed to
define prices that more reflect the value or
added value of products to patients or society
more broadly - Would be expected to result in different prices
and expenditures for products across countries,
given cross-country variation in health care
needs and preferences, health care costs, etc - Is technically challenging and value laden
- Has proven to be technically and politically
feasible in the few countries that employ this
tool formally
23The link between prices and RD investments
- The link between prices and RD investments is
not straightforward - RD investments are motivated by expected returns
on investment, which are in turn influenced by
expected prices and volumes (since marginal costs
of production are relatively low) - Absolute and relative prices affect profits. So
do volumes of consumption over product life-cycle
(affected by rate of uptake and diffusion,
competition in the off-patent market, etc) and
costs of doing business (e.g., RD costs,
litigation). - Given firms comparative advantages and the state
of the art, firms will invest in RD for products
which are expected to be most profitable
24Pharmaceutical pricing techniques have the
potential to influence expected ROI and future
investments
- International benchmarking encourages product
differentiation without therapeutic improvement
(product proliferation) - Therapeutic referencing and reference pricing
encourage investments in product differentiation
that provides an improvement over existing
products - Pharmaco-economic assessment provides incentives
for innovation that is valued by patients and
society - Each countrys policy will have a marginal impact
on future innovation (depending on its market
size), except when there are spill-overs
25Main conclusions
- Pharmacoeconomic assessment offers the most
promising opportunity to balance the trade-off
between static and dynamic efficiency - Price the drug according to its value to society
(static efficiency) - Promote the right type and level of RD
investments by sending signals to industry as to
which innovations are most valued by society and
how much value these products offer (dynamic
efficiency) - Price-volume and risk-sharing agreements are
promising approaches to achieve better
value-for-money in pharmaceutical spending
26Main conclusions (contd)
- Stability and consistency of pharmaceutical
pricing policies are important since they reduce
the risk to manufacturers of responding to
current incentives - Consistency in the mix of policies used is
important to achieve desired outcomes
27Three scenarios
- Status-quo general continuance of current mix of
pricing policies - convergence of list prices
- shortfalls in transparency
- prices may not well reflect the value offered by
products (too low or too high) - signals for RD investment may not result in the
outcomes that maximise consumer welfare, in terms
of type (orientation) and level of innovation - Policy-makers agree that cross-country variations
in pharmaceutical prices and expenditures are
appropriate - forego international benchmarking
- seek to define prices or expenditures for a given
product that reflect the products assessed value
within the country - improved affordability in lower-income countries
- signals for RD investment should better reward
valued innovation - RD is financed through alternative routes and
products are purchased at a price equals to the
marginal production cost - Affordability should be improved
- Impact on innovation depends on specifics of
alternative financing approach - Technical and political feasibility of this
scenario was not explored