Title: Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001)
1Introductory Microeconomics (ES10001)
- Topic 5 Imperfect Competition
2I. Introduction
- PC Monopoly are useful benchmarks.
- But, in more than half of the 800 major UK
manufacturing product categories, 70 of market
is shared by 5 largest firms in the market. - Real world markets are imperfectly competitive
- Imperfectly competitive (IC) firms cannot sell as
much as want at going market price they face a
downward sloping demand curve.
3I. Introduction
- Two models of imperfect competition
- Monopolistic Competition
- Oligopoly
- And in terms of Oligopoly
- Non-Collusive
- Collusive
4II. Monopolistic Competition
- Theory originally developed by Chamberlain (USA)
and Robinson (UK) in early 1930s - Many sellers producing similar, but not
identical, products that are close substitutes
for each other -
- Each firm has only a limited ability to affect
the market price
5II. Monopolistic Competition
- Assumptions
- Large number of small firms firms assume own
behaviour has no influence on rivals actions - Similar, but not identical, products
- Free entry and exit into industry
6II. Monopolistic Competition
- Implication
- Each firm can, to some extent, influence its
market share by changing its price relative to
its competitors - Demand curve is downward sloping because
different firms products are only limited
substitutes for each other - Advertising product differentiation
7II. Monopolistic Competition
- Short-run equilibrium of typical monopolistically
competitive firm - Profit-maximising monopolist in its own brand
- Thus MR MC and (we assume) profit gt 0
8Figure 1 Monopolosit Competition (SR) p gt 0
p
SMC
p0
SAC
Profit
LAC0
D AR
MR
Q
0
Q0
9II. Monopolistic Competition
- Existence of supernormal profit induces other
firms to enter industry with their own brands - This shifts down/left demand curve facing
existing monopolistically competitive firms - Moreover, demand curve becomes more elastic since
consumers now have a greater variety of choice - Process continues until no more firms enter
industry (i.e. all firms are earning normal
profit)
10Figure 2 Impact on AR of entry of rival brands
p
AR0
AR1
Q
0
11Figure 3 Monopolist LR Equilibrium p 0
p
LMC
LAC
p0 LAC0
D AR
MR
Q
0
Q0
12II. Monopolistic Competition
- Long-run tangency equilibrium where p LAC
- Monopolistically competitive firms are neither
electively nor productively efficient - ... too many firms each producing too little
output. (Chamberlain) - But
- ... excess capacity is the cost of
differentness. (Chamberlain).
13III. Oligopoly
- Competition among the few
- Few producers, each of whom recognises that its
own price depends on both its own output and the
output of its rivals - Thus, firms are of a size and number that each
must consider how its own actions affect the
decisions of its relatively few competitors. - For example, firm must consider likely response
of rivals before embarking on a price cutting
strategy
14III. Oligopoly
- Collusion or competition?
- Key element of all oligopolistic situations
- Collusion agreement between existing firms to
avoid competition with one another - Can be explicit or implicit
15III. Oligopoly
- For example, existing firms might collude to
maximise joint profits by behaving as if they
were a multi-plant monopolist - i.e. restricting q to monopolist level, say q0,
and then negotiating over the division of q and
monopoly profits - Note, might not agree to divide up q equally
sensible for more efficient members of the cartel
to produce q
16Figure 4 Collusion or Competition
p
E0
p0
p1
MC
MR
D AR
q
q0 q1
0
17III. Oligopoly
- But, since cartel p gt MC, each firm has an
incentive to renege on the collusive agreement - ... temptation to reach the first best renders
the second best unsustainable and drives firms
to third best - First-Best I renege, you collude
- Second-Best Neither renege we both collude
- Third-Best We both renege
- Cartels are inherently fragile!
18Figure 4 Collusion or Competition
p
Cartel price is above cartel members marginal
cost, thus incentive to renege (i.e. increase q)
p0
Normal profit equilibrium
p1
MC
MR
D AR
q
q0 q1
0
19III. Oligopoly
- Collusion is easiest when formal agreements
between firms are legally permitted (e.g. OPEC). - More common in 19th century, but increasingly
outlawed - Collusion is more difficult the more firms there
are in the market, the less the product is
standardised, and the more demand and cost
conditions are changing in the absence of
collusion
20III. Oligopoly
- In absence of collusion, each firms demand curve
depends upon how competitors react, and firms
have to make assumptions about this - A simple model of this was developed by Sweezy
(1945) to explain that apparent fact that prices
once set as a mark-up on average costs, tend not
too change - Kinked Demand Curve model
21III. Oligopoly
- Assume firm is at E0 selling q0 output at a unit
price of p0 - Firm believes that if it raises price, its rivals
will not raise their price (i.e. DA), but that if
it lowers price, then its rivals will follow him
(i.e. DB) - Thus demand curve is kinked at E0 being flatter
for p gt p0 and steeper for p lt p0
22Figure 5a Kinked Demand Curve Model
p
E0
p0
DA
DB
q
0
q0
23III. Oligopoly
- Both the no-follow demand curve (DA) and the
follow demand curve (DB) will have an
associated MR curve (MRA, MRB) - Thus MR is discontinuous (i.e. vertical) at q0
since an increase in q beyond q0 will lead to a
discontinuous fall in total revenue
24Figure 5b Kinked Demand Curve Model
p
E0
p0
DA
DB
q
0
q0
MRA
MRB
25Figure 5c Kinked Demand Curve Model
p
E0
p0
D
q
0
q0
MR
26III. Oligopoly
- Thus, fluctuations in marginal cost within the
discontinuous part of the MR curve (i.e. within
A-B) do not lead to a change in the firms
profit-maximising level of output - Sweezy used the model to model the inflexibility
of US agricultural prices in the face of cost
changes
27Figure 5a Kinked Demand Curve Model
p
LMC
E0
p0
A
B
D
q
0
q0
MR
28III. Oligopoly
- But two key weaknesses
- Empirical
- Further evidence suggested that agriculture
prices did not behave asymmetrically - Theoretical
- Model does not explain how we got to the initial
equilibrium, or where we go if LMC moves outside
of the discontinuity
29III. Oligopoly
- Cournot (1833)
- Firms compete over quantities with conjectural
variation that other firm(s) will hold their
output constant - Cournot originally envisaged two firms producing
identical spring water at zero cost
30III. Oligopoly
- Two firms (a, b) costlessly produce identical
spring water - Assume normal (inverse) demand curve for spring
water is - qd 100 5p ltgt pd 20 0.2q
- Assume that firm a believes that firm b will
produce zero output (i.e. Eaqb 0) firm as
optimal q is that which maximises firm as total
revenue vis.
31Figure 6a Cournot Competition Firm as optimal
output if Eaqb 0
p
20
Ea1
10
D AR
q
50
100
0
MR
32III. Oligopoly
- However, if firm a were to produce 50 units, then
firm b would presume that it (i.e. firm b) faces
a (residual) demand curve of - i.e. a residual demand given by the market demand
for the good less firm as output - And firm b would make its optimal choice of
output accordingly
33Figure 6b Cournot Competition
p
Firm as supply Firm bs (residual)
demand
20
Ea1
10
D AR
q
50
0
100
MR
MR
34Figure 6c Cournot Competition Firm bs
residual demand
p
10
Eb2
5
D AR
q
25
0
50
MR
35III. Oligopoly
- Thus, if qa 50, then firm b would maximise its
profit (i.e. revenue) by setting qb 25 - But this would imply that firm a would want to
change its initial level of output i.e. qa1 50
was optimal under the assumption that qb 0 - But now that qb 25, firm a will want to revise
its choice of q accordingly
36III. Oligopoly
- Thus, firm a will choose the level of output that
maximises total revenue given qb 25 - Firm as residual demand curve is thus
- Such that
37Figure 6d Cournot Competition
p
Firm as supply Firm as
(residual) demand
20
Eb2
15
D AR
MR
q
25
0
100
38Figure 6e Cournot Competition Firm as
residual demand
p
15
Ea3
7.5
D AR
q
37.5
0
75
MR
39III. Oligopoly
- This process will continue until neither firm
regrets its optimal choice of output - i.e. until its conjectural variation regarding
the other firms response is validated - The Cournot equilibrium is thus where
-
40Figure 6d Cournot Competition Cournot
Equilibrium
p
20
Ea
Eb
D AR
q
0
33.3 33.3
100
MR MR
41III. Oligopoly
Round 1 2 3 4 n
Firm a 50 50 37.5 37.5 33.33
Firm b 0 25 25 31.25 33.33
42III. Oligopoly
- It can be shown that total (i.e. market)
equilibrium output under Cournot competition is
given by - where qc is the perfectly competitive level of
output (i.e. where p MC) - N.B. Usually termed Nash-Cournot equilibrium,
hence superscript n
43III. Oligopoly
- Monopoly
- n 1 qn (1/2)qc
- Duopoly
- n 2 qn (2/3)qc
- Perfect Competition
- n qn qc
44III. Oligopoly
- Cournot originally envisaged his model in term of
sequential decision making on the part of firms - But it would irrational for each firm to persist
with the conjectural variation that its rival
will hold output constant when they only do so in
equilibrium - Moreover, the model implies the existence of a
future, in which case it can be shown that
profitable collusion is sustainable
45III. Oligopoly
- Economists have re-interpreted Cournots model in
terms of a one-shot game - i.e. only one amount of output actually put onto
market vis. Cournot equilibrium level of output
qn - But, it is assumed that each firm goes through a
rational sequential decision making process
before implementing its output choice
46III. Oligopoly
- The Cournot equilibrium may be re-interpreted in
this sense as a Nash Equilibrium - That is, an equilibrium in which each party is
maximising his utility given the behaviour of all
the other parties - I am doing the best I can do, given what you are
doing and vice versa
47III. Oligopoly
- Stackelberg competition
- Variation of Cournot in which firm a announces
its output and, once that announcement is made,
the output cannot be changed. - i.e. one-shot game or repeated game in which firm
a produces the same level of output in each
period.
48III. Oligopoly
- Assume
- Firm 1 - market leader
- Firm 2 - market follower
- N.B. firm 1 has to be able to make a credible,
binding commitment to a particular output level
49Figure 7 Stackelberg Competition
p
20
E1
E2
Es
5
D AR
q
50 25 75
0
100
MR
MR
50III. Oligopoly
- Bertrand Competition
- Both Cournot and Stackelberg assume that firms
chose outputs with prices determined by the
inverse demand functions. - But in many oligopolistic markets firms appear to
set prices and then sell whatever the market
demands at those prices
51III. Oligopoly
- In perfect competition and monopoly, it makes no
difference whether we carry out analysis in terms
of prices or quantities - That is, price determines quantity and quantity
determines price - But in oligopoly the distinction is crucial
52III. Oligopoly
- Bertrand presented an alternative to the Cournot
model in his review of Cournots book. - He asked the question, what would be the outcome
if the two firms chose prices -
- (a) simultaneously
- (b) independently
- And then sold all the output that was demanded at
these prices via the inverse demand functions
53III. Oligopoly
- Conclusion
- Completely different result emerges
- Equilibrium which replicates perfectly
competitive (i.e. allocatively efficient)
equilibrium in which p MC
54III. Oligopoly
- Firms compete with each other by marginally
undercutting the others price (assuming
homogenous good, costs etc.) and thus taking the
whole market - Process continues until the only equilibrium is
one where each firm sets price equal to marginal
cost
55III. Oligopoly
- Nash equilibrium in Bertrand is p1 MC p2
- Rationalisation for the equilibrium is on the
same lines as in Cournot model vis. no other pair
of prices has the property of mutual consistency.
- Bertrand intended this to be a reductio ad
absurdum and to demonstrate the weakness of
Cournots approach
56Figure 8 Bertrand Competition
p
Monopoly Equilibrium
Em
pm
Bertrand Equilibrium
Eb
MC AC
pb
D AR
q
0
qb
qm
MR
57III. Oligopoly
- Bertrand model yields a striking prediction from
a quite reasonable model - If outputs are homogenous, an increase in the
number of firms in the market from one to two
leads from the monopoly equilibrium directly to
the perfectly competitive equilibrium!
58IV. Game Theory
- Game situation in which intelligent decisions
are necessarily interdependent - The players in the game attempt to maximise their
own payoffs via a strategy - Strategy game plan describing how the player
will act (or move) in every conceivable
situation. - Equilibrium Concept - Nash
59IV. Game Theory
- Nash equilibrium occurs when each player chooses
his best strategy, given the strategies of the
other players. - Consider
- Prisoners Dilemma
60IV. Game Theory
Player 2 Confess Deny
Player 1
Confess -8, -8 0, -10
Deny -10, 0 -1, -1
61IV. Game Theory
Player 2 Confess Deny
Player 1
Confess -8, -8 0, -10
Deny -10, 0 -1, -1
62IV. Game Theory
Player 2 Confess Deny
Player 1
Confess -8, -8 0, -10
Deny -10, 0 -1, -1
63IV. Game Theory
Player 2 Confess Deny
Player 1
Confess -8, -8 0, -10
Deny -10, 0 -1, -1
64IV. Game Theory
Player 2 Confess Deny
Player 1
Confess -8, -8 0, -10
Deny -10, 0 -1, -1
65IV. Game Theory
Player 2 Confess Deny
Player 1
Confess -8, -8 0, -10
Deny -10, 0 -1, -1
66IV. Game Theory
Player 2 Confess Deny
Player 1
Confess -8, -8 0, -10
Deny -10, 0 -1, -1
67IV. Game Theory
Player 2 Confess Deny
Player 1
Confess -8, -8 0, -10
Deny -10, 0 -1, -1
68IV. Game Theory
Player 2 Confess Deny
Player 1
Confess -8, -8 0, -10
Deny -10, 0 -1, -1
69IV. Game Theory
Player 2 Confess Deny
Player 1
Confess -8, -8 0, -10
Deny -10, 0 -1, -1
70IV. Game Theory
Player 2 Confess Deny
Player 1
Confess -8, -8 0, -10
Deny -10, 0 -1, -1
71IV. Game Theory
Player 2 Confess Deny
Player 1
Confess -8, -8 0, -10
Deny -10, 0 -1, -1
72IV. Game Theory
Player 2 Confess Deny
Player 1
Confess -8, -8 0, -10
Deny -10, 0 -1, -1
73IV. Game Theory
Player 2 Confess Deny
Player 1
Confess -8, -8 0, -10
Deny -10, 0 -1, -1
74IV. Game Theory
Player 2 Confess Deny
Player 1
Confess -8, -8 0, -10
Deny -10, 0 -1, -1
75IV. Game Theory
Player 2 Confess Deny
Player 1
Confess -8, -8 0, -10
Deny -10, 0 -1, -1
76IV. Game Theory
Player 2 Confess Deny
Player 1
Confess -8, -8 0, -10
Deny -10, 0 -1, -1
77IV. Game Theory
Player 2 Confess Deny
Player 1
Confess -8, -8 0, -10
Deny -10, 0 -1, -1
78IV. Game Theory
Player 2 Confess Deny
Player 1
Confess -8, -8 0, -10
Deny -10, 0 -1, -1
79IV. Game Theory
- Nash Equilibrium Confess, Confess
- Indeed, to confess is each players dominant
strategy vis. optimal strategy that is
independent of the strategy of the other
player(s) - Recall, collusion versus competition
80IV. Game Theory
- Collusion versus Competition
Firm 2 Renege Collude
Firm 1
Renege -8, -8 0, -10
Collude -10, 0 -1, -1
81IV. Game Theory
- Collusion versus Competition
Firm 2 Renege Collude
Firm 1
Renege -8, -8 0, -10
Collude -10, 0 -1, -1
82IV. Game Theory
- Collusion versus Competition
Firm 2 Renege Collude
Firm 1
Renege -8, -8 0, -10
Collude -10, 0 -1, -1
83IV. Game Theory
- Collusion versus Competition
Firm 2 Renege Collude
Firm 1
Renege -8, -8 0, -10
Collude -10, 0 -1, -1
84IV. Game Theory
- Collusion versus Competition
Firm 2 Renege Collude
Firm 1
Renege -8, -8 0, -10
Collude -10, 0 -1, -1
85III. Oligopoly
- First-best (i.e. dominant strategy) would be to
renege given that the other firm colludes - Second-best would to both collude (i.e. a
voluntary agreement to maintain the cartel output
but restrictive practices are usually illegal
and so agreements are usually tacit) - Third-best is to both renege and compete
86III. Oligopoly
- Again
-
- Temptation to reach the first-best renders the
second-best unsustainable and so forces players
to the third-best