Eminent Domain in United States Constitutional Law - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

About This Presentation
Title:

Eminent Domain in United States Constitutional Law

Description:

Fifth Amendment Takings Clause Takings Clause: . . . nor shall private property be taken for public use, without just compensation. – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:60
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 22
Provided by: biiclOrg3
Learn more at: https://www.biicl.org
Category:

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: Eminent Domain in United States Constitutional Law


1
Eminent Domain in United States Constitutional Law
Investment Treaty Forum Conference British
Institute of International and Comparative Law 5
May 2006
Gary B. Born Wilmer Cutler Pickering Hale and
Dorr LLP
2
Fifth Amendment Takings Clause
  • Takings Clause . . . nor shall private property
    be taken for public use, without just
    compensation.
  • Due Process Clause Fifth Amendment No person
    shall . . . be deprived of life, liberty, or
    property, without due process of law. . .
  • Due Process and Equal Protection Clauses
    Fourteenth Amendment
  • . . . nor shall any State deny to any person
    within its jurisdiction the equal protection of
    the laws.

3
Historical Origins of Takings Clause
  • Fifth Amendment . . . is designed to bar
    Government from forcing some people alone to bear
    public burdens which, in all fairness and
    justice, should be borne by the public . . .
    Penn Central Transp. Co. v. City of New York, 438
    U.S. 104, 123 (1978) (quoting Armstrong v. United
    States, 364 U.S. 40, 49 (1960)).
  • Relatively limited use of Takings Clause for more
    than 100 years after adoption

4
Origin of Regulatory Takings Doctrine
  • Takings historically limited to direct
    expropriation / eminent domain
  • Pennsylvania Coal Co. v. Mahon Takings Clause
    requires just compensation for so-called
    regulatory takings

5
Origin of Regulatory Takings Doctrine
  • Justice Brandeis dissent
  • Restriction imposed to protect the public
    health, safety or morals from dangers threatened
    is not a taking. The restriction here in
    question is merely the prohibition of a noxious
    use. The property so restricted remains in the
    possession of its owner. . . . Where the
    police power is exercised, not to confer
    benefits upon property owners but to protect the
    public from detriment and danger, there is in my
    opinion, no room for considering reciprocity of
    advantage. Mahon, 260 U.S. at 422.

6
Origin of Regulatory Takings Doctrine
  • Justice Holmes majority
  • As applied in this case, the statute is admitted
    to destroy preexisting rights of property and
    contract. The question is whether the police
    power can be stretched so far. Government hardly
    could go on if to some extent values incident to
    property could not be diminished without paying
    for every such change in the general law. . . .
    The general rule at least is that while property
    may be regulated to a certain extent, if
    regulation goes too far it will be recognised as
    a taking. 260 U.S. at 413.
  • Court holds that statutes essentially complete
    destruction of the mineral rights reserved by the
    coal company constituted a taking

7
Overview of Contemporary Takings Law
  • Lack of clear rules under Takings Clause,
    particularly in regulatory takings analysis
  • U.S. Supreme Court has repeatedly said that there
    is no set formula, Goldblatt v. Town of
    Hempstead, 369 U.S. 590, 594 (1962)
  • Takings analysis depends largely on essentially
    ad hoc, factual inquiries. Penn Central, 438
    U.S. at 124.

8
Overview of Contemporary Takings Law
  • Doremus, Takings and Transitions, 19 J. Land Use
    Envtl. L. 1, 1-2 (2003) (regulatory takings law
    famously incoherent)
  • Bell Parchomovsky, Takings Reassessed, 87 Va.
    L. Rev. 277, 278 (2001) (Takings jurisprudence
    is replete with inconsistent distinctions that
    provide scant guidance for courts and
    policymakers.)
  • Schroeder, Never Jam To-day On the Impossibility
    of Takings Jurisprudence, 84 Geo. L.J. 1531, 1531
    (1996) (Takings jurisprudence is a top contender
    for the dubious title of most incoherent area of
    American law.)
  • Farber, Public Choice and Just Compensation, 9
    Const. Comment. 279, 279 (1992) (Takings
    doctrine is a mess.)

9
Overview of Contemporary Takings Law
  • Peterson, The Takings Clause In Search of
    Underlying Principles, 77 Cal. L. Rev. 1301, 1304
    (1989) (It is difficult to imagine a body of
    case law in greater doctrinal and conceptual
    disarray.)
  • Rose, Mahon Reconstructed Why the Takings Issue
    is Still a Muddle, 57 S. Cal. L. Rev. 561, 561-62
    (1984) (Takings jurisprudence is by far the
    most intractable constitutional property issue.)
  • Epstein, The Seven Deadly Sins of Takings Law, 26
    Loy. L.A. L. Rev. 955, 956 (1993) (Making
    sense of the Takings Clause . . . is complicated
    enough when the constitutional text stands alone,
    but it has been made more formidable still by the
    grotesque judicial gloss on the clause that now
    passes for constitutional interpretation.)

10
Overview of Contemporary Takings Law
  • Despite a general absence of clear rules, it is
    possible to derive a few principles, even in the
    field of regulatory takings
  • Eminent Domain - acquisition of title or formal
    expropriation virtually always requires just
    compensation United States v. Gen. Motors Corp.
    (1945)
  • Permanent physical occupation of property
    virtually always requires just compensation -
    Loretto v. Teleprompter Manhattan CATV Corp.
    (1982)
  • Total (100) destruction of property value
    generally requires just compensation, subject to
    general nuisance doctrine - Lucas v. South
    Carolina Coastal Council (1992)
  • Ordinary Regulatory Takings Claims Generally
    Subject to Multi-Factor Analysis - Penn Central
    Transp. Co. v. City of New York (1978)
    Tahoe-Sierra Preservation Council, Inc. v. Tahoe
    Regional Planning Agency (2002).

11
Permanent Physical Occupation Loretto
  • New York statute requiring land owner to permit
    installation of cable television cable and
    directional taps on private rental property
  • U.S. Supreme Court held that statute effected a
    regulatory taking
  • A permanent physical occupation authorized by
    government is a taking without regard to the
    public interests it may serve a physical
    intrusion is a property restriction of an
    unusually serious character for purposes of the
    Takings Clause when the physical intrusion
    reaches the extreme form of a permanent physical
    occupation, a taking has occurred. Loretto, 458
    U.S. at 426.

12
Total Destruction of Economic Value Lucas
  • South Carolina Beachfront Management Act - no
    construction within specified distance from
    beachfront
  • We have found categorical treatment
    appropriate . . . where regulation denies all
    economically beneficial or productive use of
    land. Lucas v. South Carolina Coastal Council,
    505 U.S. 1003, 1015 (1992).
  • 100 loss of value required for categorical
    treatment NOT 90

13
Lucas Exception Nuisance Law
  • Lucas exception Background principles of
    nuisance law
  • where the State seeks to sustain regulation
    that deprives land of all economically beneficial
    use, we think it may resist compensation only if
    the logically antecedent inquiry into the nature
    of the owner's estate shows that the prescribed
    use interests were not part of his title to begin
    with must inhere in the title itself, in the
    restrictions that background principles of the
    State's law of property and nuisance already
    place upon land ownership Lucas, 505 U.S. at
    1027.

14
Lucas Exception Nuisance Law
  • Examples
  • zoning restrictions - Village of Euclid v. Ambler
    Realty (1926)
  • industrial uses prohibited - Hadacheck v.
    Sebastian (1915) (brickyard plant operations in
    urban areas) United States v. Central Eureka
    Mining Co. (1958) (non-essential gold mine)
    Mugler v. Kansas (1887) (brewery)
  • height restrictions - Welch v. Swasey (1909)
  • health/crop restrictions - Miller v. Schoene
    (1928) (destruction of ornamental cedars)

15
Ordinary Regulatory Takings Claims Penn
Central Factors
  • In contrast to the categorical per se rules under
    Loretto and Lucas, most regulatory takings claims
    are subject to ad hoc, case-by-case analysis.
  • Penn Central Transp. Co. v. City of New York, 438
    U.S. 104 (1978) NY Court of Appeals held that
    there could be no taking since the Landmarks
    Preservation Law had not transferred control of
    the property to the city, but only restricted
    appellants exploitation of it.
  • US Supreme Court held that, for alleged
    regulatory taking, the Fifth Amendment required
    essentially ad hoc, factual inquiries, with
    several factors that have particular
    significance.

16
Ordinary Regulatory Takings Claims Penn
Central Factors
  • Three Penn Central factors
  • economic impact of the regulation on the
    claimant
  • the extent to which the regulation has
    interfered with distinct investment-backed
    expectations
  • the character of the governmental action A
    taking may more readily be found when the
    interference can be characterised as a physical
    invasion by government, than when interference
    arises from some public program adjusting the
    benefits and burdens of economic life to promote
    the common good

17
Ordinary Regulatory Takings Claims Penn
Central Factors
  • Penn Central held that permit denial was NOT a
    taking
  • other uses of property, including profitable use,
    are permitted by statute
  • no interference with present uses of property by
    statute, including historic use as a terminal
    (not office building)
  • development rights available for claimants with
    regard to their other properties
  • possibility for application for different office
    tower, which might be approved
  • comprehensive, city-wide scheme, which did not
    single out claimants or Grand Central Terminal
  • positive impact of legislation on property values

18
Ordinary Regulatory Takings Claims After Penn
Central
  • Supreme Court has not clarified the Takings
    Clause materially since Penn Central
  • Numerous, sharply-divided opinions ideological
    divide
  • A few generalizations may be made
  • Magnitude of Economic Harm (Lucas)
  • Interference with "Distinct Investment Backed
    Expectations" Correlates with Greater Likelihood
    of Taking (Lingle v. Chevron, U.S.A., Inc.)
  • Departure from Settled Custom (Eastern
    Enterprises v. Apfel)

19
Ordinary Regulatory Takings Claims After Penn
Central
  • Magnitude of Interference with Private
    Rights/Control (Eureka and Pewee)
  • Magnitude of Temporal and Spatial Intrusion
    (Tahoe)
  • Magnitude of Physical Invasion (United States v.
    Causby)
  • Singling Out, Particularly of Disfavoured
    Parties (Lucas)

20
Ordinary Regulatory Takings Claims After Penn
Central
  • Violation of Government Assurances / Promises
    (United States v. Winstar Corp.)
  • Government Actions Must Be Logically Related and
    Proportional to the Stated Government Objectives
    (Nollan v. Calif. Coastal Comm'n Dolan v. City
    of Tigard)
  • No Reciprocity of Advantages (Village of Euclid)

21
Conclusion
  • CAFTA Chapter 10 (Investments) Annex 10-C, para.
    4
  • 4. The second situation addressed by Article
    10.7.1 is indirect expropriation, where an
    action or series of actions by a Party has an
    effect equivalent to direct expropriation
    without formal transfer of title or outright
    seizure.
  • (a) The determination of whether an action or
    series of actions by a Party, in a specific
    fact situation, constitutes an indirect
    expropriation, requires a case-by-case,
    fact-based inquiry that considers, among other
    factors
  • (i) the economic impact of the
    government action, although the fact that an
    action or series of actions by a Party has an
    adverse effect on the economic value of an
    investment, standing alone, does not establish
    that an indirect expropriation has occurred
  • (ii) the extent to which the
    government action interferes with distinct,
    reasonable investment backed expectations and
  • (iii) the character of the government
    action.
  • (b) Except in rare circumstances,
    nondiscriminatory regulatory actions by a
    Party that are designed and applied to protect
    legitimate public welfare objectives, such as
    public health, safety, and the environment,
    do not constitute indirect expropriations.
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)
About PowerShow.com