Title: Chapter 3 Preferences
1Chapter 3 Preferences
- Course Microeconomics
- Text Varians Intermediate Microeconomics
2Introduction
- Last chapter we talk about what is affordable or
feasible to consumers. - This time we talk about preferences what the
consumer like more and what they like less. - As a rational agent, a consumer chooses the
option in the budget set that is highest in their
preference order (i.e. one likes the most).
3Preference Relations
- Let x, y are consumption bundles.
- denotes strict preference so x y
means that bundle x is preferred strictly to
bundle y. - denotes indifference x y means x and y are
equally preferred. - denotes weak preferencex y means x is
preferred at least as much as is y.
p
p
4Preference Relations
- Strict preference, weak preference and
indifference are all preference relations. - Particularly, they are ordinal relations i.e.
they state only the order in which bundles are
preferred. - It has no indication of how much they like one
versus the other.
5Preference Relations
- x y and y x imply x y.
- x y and (not y x) imply x y.
p
6Assumptions about Preference Relations
- Completeness For any two bundles x and y it is
always possible to make the statement that either
x y or
y x. - Bundles are always comparable.
- If both are true, then they are indifferent to
the individual.
7Assumptions about Preference Relations
- Reflexivity Any bundle x is always at least as
preferred as itself i.e.
x x.
8Assumptions about Preference Relations
- Transitivity Ifx is at least as preferred as
y, andy is at least as preferred as z, thenx is
at least as preferred as z i.e. x y and
y z x z. - It avoids circular preference, and ensure that
there exists the best bundle.
9Indifference Curves
- Take a reference bundle x. The set of all
bundles equally preferred to x is the
indifference curve (set) containing x the set
of all bundles y y x. - Weakly preferred set bundles that are weakly
preferred to x. y y x.
10Indifference Curves
x2
x x x
x
The consumer is indifferent between every point
on the indifference curve.
x
x
x1
11Indifference Curves
z x y
p
p
If consumer prefers more to less for each goods,
all bundles on the northeast of the indifference
curve are strictly preferred to x, and all
bundles southwest of the indifference curve are
less preferred to x.
x2
x
z
y
x1
12Indifference Curves
I1
All bundles in I1 are strictly preferred to all
in I2.
x2
x
z
I2
All bundles in I2 are strictly preferred to all
in I3.
y
I3
x1
13Indifference Curves
x2
WP(x), the set of bundles weakly preferred to
x.
x
I(x)
I(x)
x1
14Indifference Curves
x2
WP(x), the set of bundles weakly preferred to
x.
x
WP(x) includes I(x).
I(x)
x1
15Indifference Curves
x2
SP(x), the set of bundles strictly preferred
to x, does not include
I(x).
x
I(x)
x1
16Indifference Curves Cannot Intersect
From I1, x y. From I2, x z. Therefore y
z. But because I1 and I2 represent distinct
level of preference, we see y z, a
contradiction.
I2
x2
I1
p
x
y
z
x1
17Goods
- When more of a commodity is always preferred, the
commodity is a good. - If every commodity is a good then indifference
curves are negatively sloped. - It is because when one has more of one good, one
has to get less of another to make this bundle
indifferent to the original one.
18Slopes of Indifference Curves
Good 2
Two goodsa negatively sloped indifference curve.
Better
Worse
Good 1
19Bads
- If less of a commodity is always preferred then
the commodity is a bad. - e.g. rotten fruits tobacco smoke (if you do not
smoke) - If one good is good and the other is bad, then
the indifference curve would be upward sloping.
20Slopes of Indifference Curves
Good 2
One good and onebad a positively
sloped indifference curve.
Better
Worse
Bad 1
If you want more of the good, you also have to
get more of the bad so that you are indifferent
between them.
21Neutrals
- If one just do not care about whether or how much
to have a commodity, this is called a neutral
good. - E.g. goods that you dont use and do not care
about their existence. - If one commodity is neutral, the other is good,
the indifference curve would be vertical /
horizontal.
22Slope of Indifference Curve
23Extreme Cases of Indifference Curves Perfect
Substitutes
- If a consumer always regards units of commodities
1 and 2 as equivalent, then the commodities are
perfect substitutes. - Only the total amount (or a weighted sum) of the
two commodities in bundles determines their
preference rank-order. - Example orange juice of two different brands.
Apartment in different locations.
24Extreme Cases of Indifference Curves Perfect
Substitutes
x2
Slopes are constant at - 1.
15
I2
Bundles in I2 all have a totalof 15 units and
are strictly preferred to all bundles in
I1, which have a total of only 8 units
in them.
8
I1
x1
8
15
25Extreme Cases of Indifference Curves Perfect
Complements
- If a consumer always consumes commodities 1 and 2
in fixed proportion (e.g. one-to-one), then the
commodities are perfect complements. - Only the number of pairs of units of the two
commodities determines the preference rank-order
of bundles. - E.g. left shoes/right shoes computer and
monitor.
26Extreme Cases of Indifference Curves Perfect
Complements
x2
Each of (5,5), (5,9) and (9,5) contains5 pairs
so each is equally preferred.
45o
9
5
I1
x1
5
9
27Extreme Cases of Indifference Curves Perfect
Complements
x2
Since each of (5,5), (5,9) and (9,5) contains 5
pairs, each is less preferred than the bundle
(9,9) which contains 9 pairs.
45o
9
I2
5
I1
x1
5
9
28Preferences Exhibiting Satiation
- A bundle strictly preferred to any others is a
satiation point or a bliss point. - The satiation point is the best bundle. More of
anything are not better. - What do indifference curves look like for
preferences exhibiting satiation?
29Indifference Curves Exhibiting Satiation
x2
Satiation(bliss)point
x1
30Indifference Curves Exhibiting Satiation
x2
Better
Better
Satiation(bliss)point
Better
x1
31Indifference Curves Exhibiting Satiation
x2
Better
Better
Satiation(bliss)point
Better
x1
32Indifference Curves for Discrete Commodities
- A commodity is infinitely divisible if it can be
acquired in any quantity e.g. water or cheese. - A commodity is discrete if it comes in unit lumps
of 1, 2, 3, and so on e.g. aircraft, ships and
refrigerators.
33Indifference Curves for Discrete Commodities
- Suppose commodity 2 is an infinitely divisible
good (gasoline) while commodity 1 is a discrete
good (aircraft). What do indifference curves
look like?
34Indifference Curves With a Discrete Good
Gasoline
Indifference curvesare collections ofdiscrete
points.
Aircraft
0
1
2
3
4
35Well-Behaved Preferences
- Typical assumptions of preferences
- A preference relation is well-behaved if it is
- monotonic and convex.
- Monotonicity More of any commodity is always
preferred (i.e. no satiation and every commodity
is a good). - This implies a negatively sloped IC.
36Well-Behaved Preferences
- Convexity Mixtures of bundles are (at least
weakly) preferred to the bundles themselves.
E.g., the 50-50 mixture of the bundles x and y
is z (0.5)x (0.5)y.z is at least
as preferred as x or y.
37Well-Behaved Preferences -- Convexity.
x
x2
xy
Is (weakly) preferred to both x and y.
x2y2
z
2
2
y
y2
x1y1
x1
y1
2
38Well-Behaved Preferences -- Convexity.
x
x2
z (tx1(1-t)y1, tx2(1-t)y2)
is preferred to x and y for all 0 lt t lt 1.
y
y2
x1
y1
39Well-Behaved Preferences -- Convexity.
Preferences are strictly convex
when all mixtures z are
strictly preferred to their
component
bundles x and y.
x
x2
z
y
y2
x1
y1
40Non-Convex Preferences
The mixture zis less preferred than x or y. One
likes both, but does want to consume together.
x2
Better
z
y2
x1
y1
41More Non-Convex Preferences
x2
Better
The mixture zis less preferred than x or y.
z
y2
x1
y1
42Why convexity?
- It represents a more balanced preference rather
than a preference that induces a specialization. - It is natural to consume the goods involved in
positive amount. - It also implies a diminishing marginal rate of
substitution.
43Slopes of Indifference Curves
- The negative of the slope of an indifference
curve is its marginal rate of substitution (MRS). - Note this is slightly different from the
textbook, but my definition is more popular. - This represents the maximum amount of x2 one is
willing to give up per unit of x1 at a specific
consumption bundle.
44Marginal Rate of Substitution
x2
MRS at x is the (negative) slope of
theindifference curve at x
x
x1
45Marginal Rate of Substitution
x2
MRS at x is lim -Dx2/Dx1 Dx1
0 -dx2/dx1 at x
x
Dx2
Dx1
x1
46Marginal Rate of Substitution
-dx2 MRS dx1 so, at x, MRS is the rate at
which the consumer is only just willing to
exchange commodity 2 for a small amount of
commodity 1.
x2
x
dx2
dx1
x1
47MRS Ind. Curve Properties
Good 2
Two goodsa negatively sloped indifference curve
Better
MRS gt 0.
Worse
Good 1
48MRS Ind. Curve Properties
Good 2
One good and onebad a positively
sloped indifference curve
Better
MRS lt 0.
Worse
Bad 1
Because instead of giving up, you have to obtain
more good 2 for you to be willing to accept more
good 1.
49MRS Ind. Curve Properties
Good 2
MRS 5
MRS always decreases with x1 if and only if
preferences are strictly convex.
MRS 0.5
Good 1
We call it a diminishing marginal rate of
substitution.
50MRS Ind. Curve Properties
x2
MRS increasesas x1 increasesnon-convex
preferences
MRS 0.5
MRS 5
x1
51MRS Ind. Curve Properties
MRS is not always decreasing as x1 increases
non-convex preferences.
x2
MRS1.5
MRS 0.5
MRS 2
x1
52Summary
- In this chapter, we talk about how we can specify
consumers preference towards different
consumption bundles. - We can use indifferent curve to depict different
kinds of preferences. - The marginal rate of substitution is the slope of
indifference curve. It represents the willingness
to substitute one good for another one.
53Whats next?
- We have talked about preference and indifference
curve in this chapter. - To put preference in a more mathematically
convenient way, we introduce the utility function
in the coming chapter. - Then we can put together preference/utility and
budget constraint to analyze consumer choices.