Title: Indifference Curves
1Indifference Curves
- An indifference curve shows a set of consumption
bundles among which the individual is indifferent
Quantity of Y
Combinations (X1, Y1) and (X2, Y2) provide the
same level of utility
Y1
Y2
U1
Quantity of X
X1
X2
2Marginal Rate of Substitution
- The negative of the slope of the indifference
curve at any point is called the marginal rate of
substitution (MRS)
Quantity of Y
Y1
Y2
U1
Quantity of X
X1
X2
3Marginal Rate of Substitution
- MRS changes as X and Y change
- reflects the individuals willingness to trade Y
for X
Quantity of Y
Y1
Y2
U1
Quantity of X
X1
X2
4Indifference Curve Map
- Each point must have an indifference curve
through it
Quantity of Y
U1 lt U2 lt U3
U3
U2
U1
Quantity of X
5Transitivity
- Can two of an individuals indifference curves
intersect?
The individual is indifferent between A and
C. The individual is indifferent between B and
C. Transitivity suggests that the
individual should be indifferent between A and B
Quantity of Y
But B is preferred to A because B contains more X
and Y than A
C
B
U2
A
U1
Quantity of X
6Convexity
- A set of points is convex if any two points can
be joined by a straight line that is contained
completely within the set
Quantity of Y
The assumption of a diminishing MRS is equivalent
to the assumption that all combinations of X and
Y which are preferred to X and Y form a convex
set
Y
U1
Quantity of X
X
7Convexity
- If the indifference curve is convex, then the
combination (X1 X2)/2, (Y1 Y2)/2 will be
preferred to either (X1,Y1) or (X2,Y2)
Quantity of Y
This implies that well-balanced bundles are
preferred to bundles that are heavily weighted
toward one commodity
Y1
(Y1 Y2)/2
Y2
U1
Quantity of X
X1
(X1 X2)/2
X2
8Utility and the MRS
- Suppose an individuals preferences for
hamburgers (Y) and soft drinks (X) can be
represented by
- Solving for Y, we get
- Y 100/X
- Solving for MRS -dY/dX
- MRS -dY/dX 100/X2
9Utility and the MRS
- MRS -dY/dX 100/X2
- Note that as X rises, MRS falls
- When X 5, MRS 4
- When X 20, MRS 0.25
10Marginal Utility
- Suppose that an individual has a utility function
of the form - utility U(X1, X2,, Xn)
- We can define the marginal utility of good X1 by
- marginal utility of X1 MUX1 ?U/?X1
- The marginal utility is the extra utility
obtained from slightly more X1 (all else constant)
11Marginal Utility
- The total differential of U is
- The extra utility obtainable from slightly more
X1, X2,, Xn is the sum of the additional utility
provided by each of these increments
12Deriving the MRS
- Suppose we change X and Y but keep utility
constant (dU 0) - dU 0 MUXdX MUYdY
- Rearranging, we get
- MRS is the ratio of the marginal utility of X to
the marginal utility of Y
13Diminishing Marginal Utility and the MRS
- Intuitively, it seems that the assumption of
decreasing marginal utility is related to the
concept of a diminishing MRS - Diminishing MRS requires that the utility
function be quasi-concave - This is independent of how utility is measured
- Diminishing marginal utility depends on how
utility is measured - Thus, these two concepts are different
14Marginal Utility and the MRS
- Again, we will use the utility function
- The marginal utility of a soft drink is
- marginal utility MUX ?U/?X 0.5X-0.5Y0.5
- The marginal utility of a hamburger is
- marginal utility MUY ?U/?Y 0.5X0.5Y-0.5
15Examples of Utility Functions
- Cobb-Douglas Utility
- utility U(X,Y) X?Y?
- where ? and ? are positive constants
- The relative sizes of ? and ? indicate the
relative importance of the goods
16Examples of Utility Functions
- Perfect Substitutes
- utility U(X,Y) ?X ?Y
Quantity of Y
The indifference curves will be linear. The MRS
will be constant along the indifference curve.
Quantity of X
17Examples of Utility Functions
- Perfect Complements
- utility U(X,Y) min (?X, ?Y)
Quantity of Y
The indifference curves will be L-shaped. Only
by choosing more of the two goods together can
utility be increased.
Quantity of X
18Examples of Utility Functions
- CES Utility (Constant elasticity of substitution)
- utility U(X,Y) X?/? Y?/?
- when ? ? 0 and
- utility U(X,Y) ln X ln Y
- when ? 0
- Perfect substitutes ? ? 1
- Cobb-Douglas ? ? 0
- Perfect complements ? ? -?
19Examples of Utility Functions
- CES Utility (Constant elasticity of substitution)
- The elasticity of substitution (?) is equal to
1/(1 - ?) - Perfect substitutes ? ? ?
- Fixed proportions ? ? 0
20Homothetic Preferences
- If the MRS depends only on the ratio of the
amounts of the two goods, not on the quantities
of the goods, the utility function is homothetic - Perfect substitutes ? MRS is the same at every
point - Perfect complements ? MRS ? if Y/X gt ?/?,
undefined if Y/X ?/?, and MRS 0 if Y/X lt ?/?
21Nonhomothetic Preferences
- Some utility functions do not exhibit homothetic
preferences - utility U(X,Y) X ln Y
- MUY ?U/?Y 1/Y
- MUX ?U/?X 1
- MRS MUX / MUY Y
- Because the MRS depends on the amount of Y
consumed, the utility function is not homothetic
22Important Points to Note
- If individuals obey certain behavioral
postulates, they will be able to rank all
commodity bundles - The ranking can be represented by a utility
function - In making choices, individuals will act as if
they were maximizing this function - Utility functions for two goods can be
illustrated by an indifference curve map
23Important Points to Note
- The negative of the slope of the indifference
curve measures the marginal rate of substitution
(MRS) - This shows the rate at which an individual would
trade an amount of one good (Y) for one more unit
of another good (X) - MRS decreases as X is substituted for Y
- This is consistent with the notion that
individuals prefer some balance in their
consumption choices
24Important Points to Note
- A few simple functional forms can capture
important differences in individuals preferences
for two (or more) goods - Cobb-Douglas function
- linear function (perfect substitutes)
- fixed proportions function (perfect complements)
- CES function
- includes the other three as special cases