Title: Chapter Thirty-Three
1Chapter Thirty-Three
2Effects of Laws
- Property right assignments affect
- asset, income and wealth distributions
- e.g. nationalized vs. privately owned industry.
3Effects of Laws
- Property right assignments affect
- asset, income and wealth distributions
- e.g. nationalized vs. privately owned industry.
- resource allocations
- e.g. the tragedy of the commons
- e.g. patents encourage research.
4Effects of Laws
- Punishments affect
- incentives for illegal behavior
- e.g. high speeding fines can reduce the amount of
speeding.
5Effects of Laws
- Punishments affect
- incentives for illegal behavior
- e.g. high speeding fines can reduce the amount of
speeding. - asset, income and wealth distributions
- e.g. jail time results in lost income.
6Crime and Punishment
- x is the quantity of an illegal activity produced
by an individual. - C(x) is the production cost.
- B(x) is the benefit.
- Gain is B(x) - C(x).
- What is the rational choice of x?
7Crime and Punishment
First-order condition is
Notice that marginal costs matter more than do
total costs.
8Crime and Punishment
B(x)
C(x), low MC
9Crime and Punishment
B(x)
C(x), higher, but same MC
C(x), low MC
No change to illegal activity level.
10Crime and Punishment
B(x)
C(x), low MC
11Crime and Punishment
B(x)
C(x), high MC
C(x), low MC
Higher marginal costs deter crime.
12Crime and Punishment
- Detection of a criminal is uncertain.
- e is police effort.
- ?(e) is detection probability ?(e) 0 if e
0 ?(e) ? as e ?.
13Crime and Punishment
- Given e, the criminals problem is
14Crime and Punishment
- Given e, the criminals problem is
- First-order condition is
15Crime and Punishment
- Given e, the criminals problem is
- First-order condition is
- Low e ? low ?(e) ? low marg. cost.
- High e ? high ?(e) ? high marg. cost.
16Crime and Punishment
B(x)
Higher police effort deters crime.
17Crime and Punishment
- Higher fines and larger police effort both raise
marginal production costs of illegal activity. - Which is better for society -- higher fines, or
more police effort?
18Crime and Punishment
- Higher fines and larger police effort both raise
marginal production costs of illegal activity. - Which is better for society -- higher fines, or
more police effort? - Police effort consumes resources higher fines do
not. - Better to fine heavily.
19Liability Law
- An injurer, IN, and a victim, V.
- x is effort by IN to avoid injuring V.
- cIN(x) is INs cost of effort x cIN(x) ? as x
?. - L(x) is Vs loss when INs effort is x L(x) ?
as x ?.
20Liability Law
- Society wishes to minimize total cost i.e.
21Liability Law
- Society wishes to minimize total cost i.e.
- Social optimality requires
- I.e. INs private marginal cost of effort equals
marginal benefit of her extra effort.
22Liability Law
- Liability rules
- no liability rule
- strict liability rule
- negligence rule.
- Which is best?
23Liability Law
- No Liability Rule
- IN faces only private cost, cIN(x).
- Hence chooses effort level
- No liability results in suboptimal low care level
and excessive injury.
24Liability Law
- Full Liability Rule
- IN faces private cost and Vs costs, cIN(x)
L(x). - Hence chooses the socially optimal effort level
where
25Liability Law
- Negligence Rule IN is liable for Vs loss if
and only if care effort level , a legally
determined effort level.
26Liability Law
- Negligence Rule IN is liable for Vs loss if
and only if care effort level , a legally
determined effort level. - What if the court sets , the socially
optimal effort level?
27Liability Law
- So ? full liability for IN hence
she chooses
28Liability Law
- So ? full liability for IN hence
she chooses - And ? no liability for IN hence she
chooses
29Liability Law
- So ? full liability for IN hence
she chooses - And ? no liability for IN hence she
chooses - I.e. the negligence rule is socially optimal when
30Liability Law
- Both full liability and negligence rules are
socially optimal, but - full liability fully insures V always, and
- the negligence rule fully insures V only if INs
care effort level .
31Liability Law
- Both full liability and negligence rules are
socially optimal, but - full liability fully insures V always, and
- the negligence rule fully insures V only if INs
care effort level . - Victims prefer full liability injurers prefer
the negligence rule.
32Bilateral Accidents
- V and IN can each exert effort to avoid a loss.
- cV(xV) and cIN(xIN).
- Loss is L(xV,xIN).
- Society wishes to
33Bilateral Accidents
- Society wishes to
- Social optimality requires Vs MC of effort
MB of his effort INs MC of effort MB of her
effort. - I.e.
34Bilateral Accidents
- No Liability Both V and IN face only their
private effort costs, not the full social costs
of their actions.
35Bilateral Accidents
- No Liability Both V and IN face only their
private effort costs, not the full social costs
of their actions. - Hence V and IN both provide too little effort.
- No liability is socially suboptimal.
36Bilateral Accidents
- Full Liability V is fully compensated for all
injury costs.
37Bilateral Accidents
- Full Liability V is fully compensated for all
injury costs. - Hence V chooses
- Full liability is socially suboptimal in
bilateral accidents.
38Bilateral Accidents
- Strict Division of Losses IN must pay a fixed
fraction, f, of loss caused. - IN minimizes
- IN chooses effort satisfying
39Bilateral Accidents
- IN chooses effort satisfying
- Optimality requires
- Since f lt 1, IN chooses less than the optimal
effort level
40Bilateral Accidents
- IN chooses effort satisfying
- Optimality requires
- Since f lt 1, IN chooses less than the optimal
effort level - Strict division of losses is a socially
suboptimal liability rule.
41Bilateral Accidents
- Negligence Rule IN is fully liable for loss only
if her effort level , a legally
determined effort level. - Social optimality requires V and IN to choose
effort levels
and
, where
and
42Bilateral Accidents
- Suppose V chooses
- Then IN is fully liable and wishes to
- I.e. IN chooses
43Bilateral Accidents
- Now suppose IN chooses
- Then V wishes to
- I.e. V chooses
44Bilateral Accidents
- Now suppose IN chooses
- Then V wishes to
- I.e. V chooses
- The Nash equilibrium of the negligence rule game
is the socially optimal outcome.
45Bilateral Accidents
- Strict Liability with Defense of Contributory
Negligence Rule IN is fully liable unless Vs
care level is less than a specified level
46Bilateral Accidents
- IN is fully liable unless Vs care level is less
than a specified level - If society chooses and V chooses
, then IN is fully liable, so her best
reply is
47Bilateral Accidents
- IN is fully liable unless Vs care level is less
than a specified level - If society chooses and V chooses
, then IN is fully liable, so her best
reply is - If IN chooses , then Vs best
reply is
48Bilateral Accidents
- IN is fully liable unless Vs care level is less
than a specified level - If society chooses and V chooses
, then IN is fully liable, so her best
reply is - If IN chooses , then Vs best
reply is - I.e. the rule causes a socially optimal Nash
equilibrium.
49Bilateral Accidents
- Notes
- socially optimal liability rules do not generally
fully compensate the victim. - socially optimal accident deterrence is distinct
from optimal accident compensation.
50Treble Damages Antitrust Law
- The Sherman and Clayton Acts allow an agent
damaged by price-fixing to sue and recover treble
damages. - How does such a penalty affect the behavior of a
price-fixing cartel?
51Treble Damages Antitrust Law
- Assume firms collude to form a cartel with a
constant marginal production cost, - Market demand is
52Treble Damages Antitrust Law
- Assume firms collude to form a cartel with a
constant marginal production cost, - Market demand is
- Cartels goal is
53Treble Damages Antitrust Law
- Assume firms collude to form a cartel with a
constant marginal production cost, - Market demand is
- Cartels goal is
- Solution is
54Treble Damages Antitrust Law
- Suppose fixing price at results in damages
to a victim V. - Vs probability of winning suit against the
cartel is - If V wins, the cartel must pay
55Treble Damages Antitrust Law
- Suppose fixing price at results in damages
to a victim V. - Vs probability of winning suit against the
cartel is - If V wins, the cartel must pay
- Cartels problem is now
56Treble Damages Antitrust Law
- Cartels problem is now
- Solution is not generally the same as for the
original problem - So generally cartel behavior is affected by the
penalty.
57Treble Damages Antitrust Law
- Special case -- suppose is the cartels
profit. The cartels goal is
58Treble Damages Antitrust Law
- Special case -- suppose is the cartels
profit. The cartels goal is - Maximizing after-penalty profit requires
maximizing before-penalty profit.
59Treble Damages Antitrust Law
- Special case -- suppose is the cartels
profit. The cartels goal is - Maximizing after-penalty profit requires
maximizing before-penalty profit. - The cartels behavior is unaffected by the
penalty.
60Treble Damages Antitrust Law
- What if consumers can seek to be damaged?
61Treble Damages Antitrust Law
- What if consumers can seek to be damaged?
- Suppose consumer utility is quasi-linear
- Consumer can win damages
- So consumers goal is
62Treble Damages Antitrust Law
63Treble Damages Antitrust Law
64Treble Damages Antitrust Law
- Consumers goal is
- Since consumers action depends upon the
effective price, rewrite the cartels problem as
65Treble Damages Antitrust Law
- Consumers goal is
- Since consumers action depends upon the
effective price, rewrite the cartels problem as - Solution is the sameas the original problem
66Treble Damages Antitrust Law
- Solution is the same as the original problem
- is the price paid by buyers. Then
67Treble Damages Antitrust Law
- Solution is the same as the original problem
- is the price paid by buyers. Then
- So
68Treble Damages Antitrust Law
-
- The cartels price , the price set
in the absence of damage penalties. - But the effective price to both consumers and the
cartel is the same as in the no damages case.