Title: Public Economics
1Chapter 16 Tax Evasion
2Reading
- Essential reading
- Hindriks, J and G.D. Myles Intermediate Public
Economics. (Cambridge MIT Press, 2005) Chapter
16. - Further reading
- Allingham M. and A. Sandmo (1972) Income tax
evasion a theoretical analysis, Journal of
Public Economics, 1, 323338. - Baldry, J.C. (1986) Tax evasion is not a
gamble, Economics Letters, 22, 333335. - Becker, G. (1968) Crime and punishment an
economic approach, Journal of Political Economy,
76, 169217. - Cowell, F.A. Cheating the Government (Cambridge
MIT Press, 1990) ISBN 0262532484 pbk.
3Reading
- Glaeser, E.L., B. Sacerdote and J.A. Scheinkman
(1996) Crime and social interaction, Quarterly
Journal of Economics, 111, 506548. - Schneider F. and D.H. Enste D.H. (2000) Shadow
economies Size, causes, and consequences,
Journal of Economic Literature, 38, 77114. - Mork, K.A. (1975) Income tax evasion some
empirical evidence, Public Finance, 30, 7076. - Spicer, M.W. and S.B. Lundstedt (1976)
Understanding tax evasion, Public Finance, 31,
295305 - Challenging reading
- Bordignon, M. (1993) A fairness approach to
income tax evasion, Journal of Public Economics,
52, 345362. - Cowell, F.A. and J.P.F. Gordon (1988)
Unwillingness to pay, Journal of Public
Economics, 36, 305321.
4Reading
- Graetz, M., J. Reinganum and L. Wilde (1986) The
tax compliance game towards an interactive
theory of law enforcement, Journal of Law,
Economics and Organization, 2, 132. - Hindriks, J., M. Keen and A. Muthoo (1999)
Corruption, extortion and evasion, Journal of
Public Economics, 74, 395430. - Myles, G.D. and R.A. Naylor (1996) A model of
tax evasion with group conformity and social
customs, European Journal of Political Economy,
12, 4966. - Reinganum, J. and L. Wilde (1986) Equilibrium
verification and reporting policies in a model of
tax compliance, International Economics Review,
27, 739760. - Scotchmer, S. (1987) Audit classes and tax
enforcement policy, American Economic Review, 77,
229233.
5Introduction
- Tax evasion is the illegal failure to pay tax
- Tax avoidance is the reorganization of economic
activity to lower tax payment - Tax avoidance is legal but tax evasion is not
- The borderline between avoidance and evasion is
unclear - Estimates show evasion to be a significant
fraction of measured economic activity - It is an important consideration for tax policy
6The Extent of Evasion
- The names black, shadow or hidden economy are
used to described economic activity for which
payment is received but is not officially
declared - Included in the hidden economy are
- Illegal activities
- Unmeasured legal activity such as output of
smallholders - Legal but undeclared activity
- The unmeasured economy is the shadow economy plus
activities which are economically valuable but do
not involve any transaction
7The Extent of Evasion
- There are many methods for measuring the hidden
economy - The difference between the income and expenditure
measures of national income - Survey data directly or indirectly as an input
into an estimation procedure - The demand for cash on the basis hidden activity
is financed by cash (monetary approach) - The use of a basic input that is measured to
estimate true output (input approach)
8The Extent of Evasion
- Table 16.1 presents estimates of the size of the
hidden economy - These estimates are subject to error
- There is a degree of consistency
- Undeclared economic activity is substantial
Table 16.1 Hidden Economy as of GDP, Average
Over 1990-93 Source Schneider and Enste (2000)
9The Evasion Decision
- The simplest model of the evasion decision
considers it to be a gamble - If a taxpayer declares less than their true
income (or overstates deductions) - They may do so without being detected
- There is also a chance that they may be caught
- When they are a punishment is inflicted
- Usually a fine but sometimes imprisonment
- A taxpayer has to balance these gains and losses
taking account of the chance of being caught and
the level of the punishment
10The Evasion Decision
- The taxpayer has a fixed income level Y
- This income level is known to the taxpayer
- The level of income is not known to the tax
collector - The taxpayer declares a level of income X where X
Y - Income is taxed at a constant rate t
- The amount of unreported income is Y X 0
- The unpaid tax is tY - X
11The Evasion Decision
- If the taxpayer evades without being caught their
income is given by - Ync Y - tX
- When the taxpayer is caught evading all income is
taxed and a fine at rate F is levied on the tax
that has been evaded. - The income level when caught is
- Yc 1 - tY - FtY - X
- If income is understated the probability of being
caught is p
12The Evasion Decision
- Assume that the taxpayer derives utility U(Y)
from an income Y - After making declaration X the taxpayer obtains
- Income level Yc with probability p
- Income level Ync with probability 1 p
- The taxpayer chooses X to maximize expected
utility - The declaration X solves
- maxX EU(X) 1 pU(Ync) pU(Yc)
13The Evasion Decision
- Observe that there are two states of the world.
- In one state of the world the taxpayer is not
caught evading and income is Ync - In the other state of the world they are caught
and income is Yc - The expected utility function describes
preferences over income levels in the two states - The choice of X determines income in each state
- Varying X trades-off income between the states
- High X provides relatively more income in the
caught evading state - Low X provides relatively more in the not
caught
14The Evasion Decision
- When X Y the income after tax is 1 - tY in
both states - When X 0 income is 1 - t(1 F)Y if caught
and Y if not caught - The options facing the taxpayer lie on the line
joining the points for X 0 and X Y - This is the opportunity set of income allocations
between the two states - The utility function provides a set of
indifference curves - Along an indifference curve are income levels in
the two states giving equal expected utility
15The Evasion Decision
- The choice problem is shown in Fig. 16.1
- The optimal declaration achieves the highest
indifference curve - The taxpayer chooses to locate at the point with
declaration X - This is an interior point with 0 lt X lt Y
- Some tax is evaded but some income is declared
Figure 16.1 Interior choice 0 lt X lt Y
16The Evasion Decision
Figure 16.2 Corner solutions
- Corner solutions can also arise
- In Fig. 16.2a X Y so all income is declared
- In Fig. 16.2b X 0 so no income is declared
17The Evasion Decision
- Evasion occurs when indifference curves are
steeper than the budget constraint on the 45o
line - The indifference curves have slope
- dYc/dYnc 1 pU'(Ync)/pU'(Yc)
- On the 45o line Yc Ync so U'(Ync) U'(Yc)
implying - dYc/dYnc 1 p/p
- The slope of the budget constraint is F
- The indifference curve is steeper than the budget
constraint on the 45o line - p lt 1/1 F
18The Evasion Decision
- Evasion occurs if the p is small relative to F
- The condition applies to all taxpayers
- In practice F is between 0.5 and 1 so 1/(1 F)
1/2 - Information on p hard to obtain
- In the US
- The proportion of individual tax returns audited
was 1.7 per cent in 1997 - The Taxpayer Compliance Measurement Program
revealed that 40 percent of US taxpayers
underpaid their taxes - This is large but less than the model predicts
19The Evasion Decision
- An increase in detection probability is shown in
Fig. 16.3 - An increase in p reduces the gradient of the
indifference curves on the 45o line - The optimal choice moves closer to X Y
- The income declared rises so an increase in the
detection probability reduces evasion
Figure 16.3 Increase in detection probability
20The Evasion Decision
- A change in the fine rate affects income when
caught evading - An increase in F pivots the budget constraint
around the point where X Y - The optimal choice moves closer to honest
declaration - This is shown in Fig. 16.4 by the move from Xold
to Xnew - An increase in F reduces evasion
Figure 16.4 Increase in the fine rate
21The Evasion Decision
- An income increase moves the budget constraint
outward - The optimal choice moves from Xold to Xnew in
Fig. 16.5 - The effect depends on absolute risk aversion
RA(Y) - U''(Y)/U'(Y) - If RA(Y) is constant the optimal choices lie on a
locus parallel to the 45o line - If RA(Y) decreases with income the choice locus
bends downward
Figure 16.5 Income increase
22The Evasion Decision
- An increase in the tax rate moves the budget
constraint inward as inFig. 16.6 - The outcome is not clear-cut
- If RA(Y) is decreasing a tax increase reduces tax
evasion - This is because the fine is Ft so an increase in
the t raises the penalty - This reduces income in the state in which income
is lowest
Figure 16.6 Tax rate increase
23Auditing and Punishment
- The analysis of the evasion decision assumed that
the p and F were fixed - This is satisfactory from the perspective of the
individual taxpayer - From the government's perspective these are
choice variables that can be chosen - The probability of detection can be raised by the
employment of additional tax inspectors - The fine can be legislated or set by the courts
- The issues involved in the government's decision
can be analyzed
24Auditing and Punishment
- An increase in either p or F will reduce the
amount of undeclared income - Assume the government wishes to maximize revenue
- Revenue is defined as taxes paid plus the money
received from fines - From a taxpayer with income Y the expected value
of the revenue collected is - R tX p(1 F)tY X
25Auditing and Punishment
- Differentiating with respect to p
- Differentiating with respect to F
- If pF lt1 p an increase in p or F will increase
the revenue the government receives - p is costly, F is free
- Optimal policy is low p very high F
26Auditing and Punishment
- This policy maximizes revenue not welfare
- The government may be constrained by political
factors - The government may not be a single entity that
chooses all policy instruments - A more convincing model would have
- The tax rate set by central government
- The probability of detection controlled by a
revenue service - The punishment set by the judiciary.
27Auditing and Punishment
- The economics of crime views tax evasion as just
another crime - The punishment should fit with the general scheme
of punishments - Levels of punishment should provide incentives
that lessen the overall level of crime - Lower punishments for less harmful rather crimes
- Tax evasion has a low punishment if viewed as
having limited harm
28Evidence on Evasion
Income interval 17-20 20-25 25-30 30-35 35-40
Midpoint 18.5 22.5 27.5 32.5 37.5
Assessed income 17.5 20.6 24.2 28.7 31.7
Percentage 94.6 91.5 88.0 88.3 84.5
Table 16.2 Declaration and Income Source Mork
(1975)
- Compares income level from interviews to income
on tax return - Interviewees placed in income intervals based on
interview - The percentage found by dividing the assessed
income by the midpoint of the income interval - Declared income declines as a proportion of
reported income occurs as income rises
29Evidence on Evasion
- The propensity to evade is reduced by an increase
in the probability of detection, age, income but
increased by an increase in perceived inequity
and number of tax evaders known - Extent of tax evasion increased by inequity,
number of evaders known and experience of
previous tax audits. - Social variables are clearly important
Variable Propensity to evade Extent of evasion
Inequity 0.34 0.24
Number of evaders known 0.16 0.18
Probability of detection -0.17
Age -0.29
Experience of audits 0.22 0.29
Income level -0.27
Income from wages and salaries 0.20
Table 16.3 Explanatory Factors Source Spicer
and Lundstedt (1976)
30Evidence on Evasion
- Data from the US Internal Revenue Services
Taxpayer Compliance Measurement Program survey of
1969 - Evasion increases as the marginal tax rates
increases but decreases when wages are a
significant proportion of income - The difference between income and expenditure
figures in National Accounts support this result - Belgian data found the converse tax increases
lead to lower evasion - There remains ambiguity about the tax effect
31Evidence on Evasion
- Tax evasion games can be used to test evasion
behavior - These games have shown that evasion increases
with the tax rate - Evasion falls as the fine is increased or the
detection probability increases - Women evade more often than men but evade lower
amounts - Purchasers of lottery tickets were
- No more likely to evade than non-purchasers
- Evaded greater amounts when they did evade
32Evidence on Evasion
- The nature of the tax evasion decision has been
tested by running two parallel experiments - One framed as a tax evasion decision and
- The other as a simple gamble
- These experiments have the same risks and payoffs
- For the tax evasion experiment some taxpayers
chose not to evade even when they would under the
same conditions with the gambling experiment - This suggests that tax evasion is more than just
a gamble
33Evidence on Evasion
- There are several important lessons to be drawn
from the evidence - The theoretical predictions are generally
supported except for the effect of the tax rate - Tax evasion is more than the simple gamble
portrayed in the basic model - There are attitudinal and social aspects to the
evasion decision in addition to the basic element
of risk
34Effect of Honesty
- The act of tax evasion can have psychological
effects - Taxpayers submitting incorrect returns feel
varying degrees of anxiety and regret - The innate honesty of some taxpayers is not
captured by representing tax evasion as just a
gamble - Non-monetary costs of detection and punishment
are not captured by preferences defined on income
alone
35Effect of Honesty
- Honesty can introduced by assuming the utility
function has the form - U U(Y) - cE
- The level of evasion is E Y- X and c is a
measure of honesty - The value of cE the psychological cost of evasion
- Assume taxpayers differ in their value of c but
are identical in all other respects - Those with high c will have a greater utility
reduction for any given level of evasion
36Effect of Honesty
- Evasion occurs only if the utility gain from
evasion must exceed the utility reduction - Let E be the optimal level of evasion
- Evasion is chosen if EU( ) cE gt U(Y) where
is the random income after optimal evasion - The population is separated into taxpayers who do
not evade (high values of c) and others who evade
(low c) - Those who do not evade are honest but will
evade if the benefit is sufficiently great
37Effect of Honesty
- Empirical evidence shows a positive connection
between number of tax evaders known and the level
evasion - The evasion decision is not made in isolation but
with reference to the norms and behavior of
society - Social norms can be incorporated as an additional
utility cost of evasion. - This cost can be assumed an increasing function
of the proportion of taxpayers who do not evade.
38Effect of Honesty
- This captures the fact that more utility will be
lost the more out of step the taxpayer is with
the remainder of society - If evasion is chosen expected utility is
- EU m(n)
- The function m(n) is increasing in the number of
honest taxpayers, n - This modification reinforces the separation of
the population into evaders and non-evaders
39Tax Compliance Game
- A revenue service chooses the probability of
audit to maximize total revenue taking as given
the tax rate and the punishment - The government is viewed as allocating choices to
separate agencies - The choice of probability requires an analysis of
the interaction between the revenue service and
the taxpayers - The revenue service reacts to income declarations
and taxpayers react to the expected detection
probability
40Tax Compliance Game
- A strategy for the revenue service is the
probability with which it chooses to audit any
given value of declaration - A strategy for a taxpayers is a choice of
declaration given the audit strategy of the
revenue service - At a Nash equilibrium the strategy choices must
be mutually optimal - In this game predictability in auditing cannot be
an equilibrium strategy
41Tax Compliance Game
- Observe
- No auditing at all cannot be optimal because it
would mean maximal tax evasion - Auditing of all declarations cannot be a solution
because this incurs excessive auditing costs - A pre-specified limit on the range of
declarations that will be audited since those
evading will remain outside this limit - To be unpredictable the audit strategy must be
random
42Tax Compliance Game
- The probability of an audit should be high for an
income report that is low compared to what one
would expect from someone in that taxpayer's
occupation - Or it should be high given the information on
previous tax returns for that taxpayer - In either case a taxpayer should not be able to
predict if they will be audited
43Tax Compliance Game
- A version of the strategic interaction is
depicted in Fig. 16.7 - A taxpayer with income Y can either evade
(reporting zero income) or not (truthful income
report) - By reporting truthfully the taxpayer pays tax T
to the revenue service (with T lt Y) - The revenue service can either audit the income
report or not audit - An audit costs C, C lt T, for the revenue service
to conduct and is accurate in detecting evasion - If the taxpayer is caught evading the tax T plus
a fine F is paid (where F gt C)
44Tax Compliance Game
Figure 16.7 Compliance game
45Tax Compliance Game
- There is no pure strategy equilibrium in this tax
compliance game - If the revenue service does not audit the
taxpayer strictly prefers evading and therefore
the revenue service is better-off auditing as T
F gt C - If the revenue service audits with certainty, the
taxpayer prefers not to evade as T F gt T, which
implies that the revenue service is better-off
not auditing - The revenue must play a mixed strategy in
equilibrium with the audit strategy being random - The taxpayers evasion strategy must also be
random
46Tax Compliance Game
- Let e be the probability that the taxpayer
evades, and p the probability of audit - In equilibrium the players must be indifferent
between their two pure strategies - For the revenue service to be indifferent between
auditing and not auditing the cost of auditing C
must equal the expected gain in tax and fine
revenue eT F - For the taxpayer to be indifferent between
evading and not evading the expected gain from
evading (1 p)T must equal the expected penalty
pF - The equilibrium is
- e C/(T F), p T/(T F)
47Tax Compliance Game
- The equilibrium payoffs are
- u Y T, v T (C/(TF))T
- The taxpayer is indifferent between evading or
not evading so equilibrium payoff is equal to
truthful payoff Y T - This is because
- Unpaid taxes and the fine cancel out in expected
terms - Increasing the fine does not affect the taxpayer
48Tax Compliance Game
- A higher fine increases the payoff of the revenue
service since it reduces the amount of evasion - increasing the penalty is Pareto-improving
- The equilibrium payoffs also reflect a cost of
evasion - for any tax T paid by the taxpayer the revenue
service receives T D - where D (C/(T F))T is the deadweight loss of
evasion - Evasion involves a deadweight loss that is
increasing with the tax rate
49Compliance and Social Interaction
- Evasion is more likely when others already evade
- Payoff from non-compliance is increasing with the
number of non-compliers - Aggregate compliance tendency is toward one of
the extremes
50Compliance and Social Interaction
- This is shown in Fig. 16.8
- Always move away from the intersection
Figure 16.8 Equilibrium compliance