Public Economics - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

1 / 50
About This Presentation
Title:

Public Economics

Description:

Chapter 16 Tax Evasion Reading Essential reading Hindriks, J and G.D. Myles Intermediate Public Economics. (Cambridge: MIT Press, 2005) Chapter 16. – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:173
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 51
Provided by: myl83
Category:

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: Public Economics


1
Chapter 16 Tax Evasion
2
Reading
  • Essential reading
  • Hindriks, J and G.D. Myles Intermediate Public
    Economics. (Cambridge MIT Press, 2005) Chapter
    16.
  • Further reading
  • Allingham M. and A. Sandmo (1972) Income tax
    evasion a theoretical analysis, Journal of
    Public Economics, 1, 323338.
  • Baldry, J.C. (1986) Tax evasion is not a
    gamble, Economics Letters, 22, 333335.
  • Becker, G. (1968) Crime and punishment an
    economic approach, Journal of Political Economy,
    76, 169217.
  • Cowell, F.A. Cheating the Government (Cambridge
    MIT Press, 1990) ISBN 0262532484 pbk.

3
Reading
  • Glaeser, E.L., B. Sacerdote and J.A. Scheinkman
    (1996) Crime and social interaction, Quarterly
    Journal of Economics, 111, 506548.
  • Schneider F. and D.H. Enste D.H. (2000) Shadow
    economies Size, causes, and consequences,
    Journal of Economic Literature, 38, 77114.
  • Mork, K.A. (1975) Income tax evasion some
    empirical evidence, Public Finance, 30, 7076.
  • Spicer, M.W. and S.B. Lundstedt (1976)
    Understanding tax evasion, Public Finance, 31,
    295305
  • Challenging reading
  • Bordignon, M. (1993) A fairness approach to
    income tax evasion, Journal of Public Economics,
    52, 345362.
  • Cowell, F.A. and J.P.F. Gordon (1988)
    Unwillingness to pay, Journal of Public
    Economics, 36, 305321.

4
Reading
  • Graetz, M., J. Reinganum and L. Wilde (1986) The
    tax compliance game towards an interactive
    theory of law enforcement, Journal of Law,
    Economics and Organization, 2, 132.
  • Hindriks, J., M. Keen and A. Muthoo (1999)
    Corruption, extortion and evasion, Journal of
    Public Economics, 74, 395430.
  • Myles, G.D. and R.A. Naylor (1996) A model of
    tax evasion with group conformity and social
    customs, European Journal of Political Economy,
    12, 4966.
  • Reinganum, J. and L. Wilde (1986) Equilibrium
    verification and reporting policies in a model of
    tax compliance, International Economics Review,
    27, 739760.
  • Scotchmer, S. (1987) Audit classes and tax
    enforcement policy, American Economic Review, 77,
    229233.

5
Introduction
  • Tax evasion is the illegal failure to pay tax
  • Tax avoidance is the reorganization of economic
    activity to lower tax payment
  • Tax avoidance is legal but tax evasion is not
  • The borderline between avoidance and evasion is
    unclear
  • Estimates show evasion to be a significant
    fraction of measured economic activity
  • It is an important consideration for tax policy

6
The Extent of Evasion
  • The names black, shadow or hidden economy are
    used to described economic activity for which
    payment is received but is not officially
    declared
  • Included in the hidden economy are
  • Illegal activities
  • Unmeasured legal activity such as output of
    smallholders
  • Legal but undeclared activity
  • The unmeasured economy is the shadow economy plus
    activities which are economically valuable but do
    not involve any transaction

7
The Extent of Evasion
  • There are many methods for measuring the hidden
    economy
  • The difference between the income and expenditure
    measures of national income
  • Survey data directly or indirectly as an input
    into an estimation procedure
  • The demand for cash on the basis hidden activity
    is financed by cash (monetary approach)
  • The use of a basic input that is measured to
    estimate true output (input approach)

8
The Extent of Evasion
  • Table 16.1 presents estimates of the size of the
    hidden economy
  • These estimates are subject to error
  • There is a degree of consistency
  • Undeclared economic activity is substantial

Table 16.1 Hidden Economy as of GDP, Average
Over 1990-93 Source Schneider and Enste (2000)
9
The Evasion Decision
  • The simplest model of the evasion decision
    considers it to be a gamble
  • If a taxpayer declares less than their true
    income (or overstates deductions)
  • They may do so without being detected
  • There is also a chance that they may be caught
  • When they are a punishment is inflicted
  • Usually a fine but sometimes imprisonment
  • A taxpayer has to balance these gains and losses
    taking account of the chance of being caught and
    the level of the punishment

10
The Evasion Decision
  • The taxpayer has a fixed income level Y
  • This income level is known to the taxpayer
  • The level of income is not known to the tax
    collector
  • The taxpayer declares a level of income X where X
    Y
  • Income is taxed at a constant rate t
  • The amount of unreported income is Y X 0
  • The unpaid tax is tY - X

11
The Evasion Decision
  • If the taxpayer evades without being caught their
    income is given by
  • Ync Y - tX
  • When the taxpayer is caught evading all income is
    taxed and a fine at rate F is levied on the tax
    that has been evaded.
  • The income level when caught is
  • Yc 1 - tY - FtY - X
  • If income is understated the probability of being
    caught is p

12
The Evasion Decision
  • Assume that the taxpayer derives utility U(Y)
    from an income Y
  • After making declaration X the taxpayer obtains
  • Income level Yc with probability p
  • Income level Ync with probability 1 p
  • The taxpayer chooses X to maximize expected
    utility
  • The declaration X solves
  • maxX EU(X) 1 pU(Ync) pU(Yc)

13
The Evasion Decision
  • Observe that there are two states of the world.
  • In one state of the world the taxpayer is not
    caught evading and income is Ync
  • In the other state of the world they are caught
    and income is Yc
  • The expected utility function describes
    preferences over income levels in the two states
  • The choice of X determines income in each state
  • Varying X trades-off income between the states
  • High X provides relatively more income in the
    caught evading state
  • Low X provides relatively more in the not
    caught

14
The Evasion Decision
  • When X Y the income after tax is 1 - tY in
    both states
  • When X 0 income is 1 - t(1 F)Y if caught
    and Y if not caught
  • The options facing the taxpayer lie on the line
    joining the points for X 0 and X Y
  • This is the opportunity set of income allocations
    between the two states
  • The utility function provides a set of
    indifference curves
  • Along an indifference curve are income levels in
    the two states giving equal expected utility

15
The Evasion Decision
  • The choice problem is shown in Fig. 16.1
  • The optimal declaration achieves the highest
    indifference curve
  • The taxpayer chooses to locate at the point with
    declaration X
  • This is an interior point with 0 lt X lt Y
  • Some tax is evaded but some income is declared

Figure 16.1 Interior choice 0 lt X lt Y
16
The Evasion Decision
Figure 16.2 Corner solutions
  • Corner solutions can also arise
  • In Fig. 16.2a X Y so all income is declared
  • In Fig. 16.2b X 0 so no income is declared

17
The Evasion Decision
  • Evasion occurs when indifference curves are
    steeper than the budget constraint on the 45o
    line
  • The indifference curves have slope
  • dYc/dYnc 1 pU'(Ync)/pU'(Yc)
  • On the 45o line Yc Ync so U'(Ync) U'(Yc)
    implying
  • dYc/dYnc 1 p/p
  • The slope of the budget constraint is F
  • The indifference curve is steeper than the budget
    constraint on the 45o line
  • p lt 1/1 F

18
The Evasion Decision
  • Evasion occurs if the p is small relative to F
  • The condition applies to all taxpayers
  • In practice F is between 0.5 and 1 so 1/(1 F)
    1/2
  • Information on p hard to obtain
  • In the US
  • The proportion of individual tax returns audited
    was 1.7 per cent in 1997
  • The Taxpayer Compliance Measurement Program
    revealed that 40 percent of US taxpayers
    underpaid their taxes
  • This is large but less than the model predicts

19
The Evasion Decision
  • An increase in detection probability is shown in
    Fig. 16.3
  • An increase in p reduces the gradient of the
    indifference curves on the 45o line
  • The optimal choice moves closer to X Y
  • The income declared rises so an increase in the
    detection probability reduces evasion

Figure 16.3 Increase in detection probability
20
The Evasion Decision
  • A change in the fine rate affects income when
    caught evading
  • An increase in F pivots the budget constraint
    around the point where X Y
  • The optimal choice moves closer to honest
    declaration
  • This is shown in Fig. 16.4 by the move from Xold
    to Xnew
  • An increase in F reduces evasion

Figure 16.4 Increase in the fine rate
21
The Evasion Decision
  • An income increase moves the budget constraint
    outward
  • The optimal choice moves from Xold to Xnew in
    Fig. 16.5
  • The effect depends on absolute risk aversion
    RA(Y) - U''(Y)/U'(Y)
  • If RA(Y) is constant the optimal choices lie on a
    locus parallel to the 45o line
  • If RA(Y) decreases with income the choice locus
    bends downward

Figure 16.5 Income increase
22
The Evasion Decision
  • An increase in the tax rate moves the budget
    constraint inward as inFig. 16.6
  • The outcome is not clear-cut
  • If RA(Y) is decreasing a tax increase reduces tax
    evasion
  • This is because the fine is Ft so an increase in
    the t raises the penalty
  • This reduces income in the state in which income
    is lowest

Figure 16.6 Tax rate increase
23
Auditing and Punishment
  • The analysis of the evasion decision assumed that
    the p and F were fixed
  • This is satisfactory from the perspective of the
    individual taxpayer
  • From the government's perspective these are
    choice variables that can be chosen
  • The probability of detection can be raised by the
    employment of additional tax inspectors
  • The fine can be legislated or set by the courts
  • The issues involved in the government's decision
    can be analyzed

24
Auditing and Punishment
  • An increase in either p or F will reduce the
    amount of undeclared income
  • Assume the government wishes to maximize revenue
  • Revenue is defined as taxes paid plus the money
    received from fines
  • From a taxpayer with income Y the expected value
    of the revenue collected is
  • R tX p(1 F)tY X

25
Auditing and Punishment
  • Differentiating with respect to p
  • Differentiating with respect to F
  • If pF lt1 p an increase in p or F will increase
    the revenue the government receives
  • p is costly, F is free
  • Optimal policy is low p very high F

26
Auditing and Punishment
  • This policy maximizes revenue not welfare
  • The government may be constrained by political
    factors
  • The government may not be a single entity that
    chooses all policy instruments
  • A more convincing model would have
  • The tax rate set by central government
  • The probability of detection controlled by a
    revenue service
  • The punishment set by the judiciary.

27
Auditing and Punishment
  • The economics of crime views tax evasion as just
    another crime
  • The punishment should fit with the general scheme
    of punishments
  • Levels of punishment should provide incentives
    that lessen the overall level of crime
  • Lower punishments for less harmful rather crimes
  • Tax evasion has a low punishment if viewed as
    having limited harm

28
Evidence on Evasion
Income interval 17-20 20-25 25-30 30-35 35-40
Midpoint 18.5 22.5 27.5 32.5 37.5
Assessed income 17.5 20.6 24.2 28.7 31.7
Percentage 94.6 91.5 88.0 88.3 84.5
Table 16.2 Declaration and Income Source Mork
(1975)
  • Compares income level from interviews to income
    on tax return
  • Interviewees placed in income intervals based on
    interview
  • The percentage found by dividing the assessed
    income by the midpoint of the income interval
  • Declared income declines as a proportion of
    reported income occurs as income rises

29
Evidence on Evasion
  • The propensity to evade is reduced by an increase
    in the probability of detection, age, income but
    increased by an increase in perceived inequity
    and number of tax evaders known
  • Extent of tax evasion increased by inequity,
    number of evaders known and experience of
    previous tax audits.
  • Social variables are clearly important

Variable Propensity to evade Extent of evasion
Inequity 0.34 0.24
Number of evaders known 0.16 0.18
Probability of detection -0.17
Age -0.29
Experience of audits 0.22 0.29
Income level -0.27
Income from wages and salaries 0.20
Table 16.3 Explanatory Factors Source Spicer
and Lundstedt (1976)
30
Evidence on Evasion
  • Data from the US Internal Revenue Services
    Taxpayer Compliance Measurement Program survey of
    1969
  • Evasion increases as the marginal tax rates
    increases but decreases when wages are a
    significant proportion of income
  • The difference between income and expenditure
    figures in National Accounts support this result
  • Belgian data found the converse tax increases
    lead to lower evasion
  • There remains ambiguity about the tax effect

31
Evidence on Evasion
  • Tax evasion games can be used to test evasion
    behavior
  • These games have shown that evasion increases
    with the tax rate
  • Evasion falls as the fine is increased or the
    detection probability increases
  • Women evade more often than men but evade lower
    amounts
  • Purchasers of lottery tickets were
  • No more likely to evade than non-purchasers
  • Evaded greater amounts when they did evade

32
Evidence on Evasion
  • The nature of the tax evasion decision has been
    tested by running two parallel experiments
  • One framed as a tax evasion decision and
  • The other as a simple gamble
  • These experiments have the same risks and payoffs
  • For the tax evasion experiment some taxpayers
    chose not to evade even when they would under the
    same conditions with the gambling experiment
  • This suggests that tax evasion is more than just
    a gamble

33
Evidence on Evasion
  • There are several important lessons to be drawn
    from the evidence
  • The theoretical predictions are generally
    supported except for the effect of the tax rate
  • Tax evasion is more than the simple gamble
    portrayed in the basic model
  • There are attitudinal and social aspects to the
    evasion decision in addition to the basic element
    of risk

34
Effect of Honesty
  • The act of tax evasion can have psychological
    effects
  • Taxpayers submitting incorrect returns feel
    varying degrees of anxiety and regret
  • The innate honesty of some taxpayers is not
    captured by representing tax evasion as just a
    gamble
  • Non-monetary costs of detection and punishment
    are not captured by preferences defined on income
    alone

35
Effect of Honesty
  • Honesty can introduced by assuming the utility
    function has the form
  • U U(Y) - cE
  • The level of evasion is E Y- X and c is a
    measure of honesty
  • The value of cE the psychological cost of evasion
  • Assume taxpayers differ in their value of c but
    are identical in all other respects
  • Those with high c will have a greater utility
    reduction for any given level of evasion

36
Effect of Honesty
  • Evasion occurs only if the utility gain from
    evasion must exceed the utility reduction
  • Let E be the optimal level of evasion
  • Evasion is chosen if EU( ) cE gt U(Y) where
    is the random income after optimal evasion
  • The population is separated into taxpayers who do
    not evade (high values of c) and others who evade
    (low c)
  • Those who do not evade are honest but will
    evade if the benefit is sufficiently great

37
Effect of Honesty
  • Empirical evidence shows a positive connection
    between number of tax evaders known and the level
    evasion
  • The evasion decision is not made in isolation but
    with reference to the norms and behavior of
    society
  • Social norms can be incorporated as an additional
    utility cost of evasion.
  • This cost can be assumed an increasing function
    of the proportion of taxpayers who do not evade.

38
Effect of Honesty
  • This captures the fact that more utility will be
    lost the more out of step the taxpayer is with
    the remainder of society
  • If evasion is chosen expected utility is
  • EU m(n)
  • The function m(n) is increasing in the number of
    honest taxpayers, n
  • This modification reinforces the separation of
    the population into evaders and non-evaders

39
Tax Compliance Game
  • A revenue service chooses the probability of
    audit to maximize total revenue taking as given
    the tax rate and the punishment
  • The government is viewed as allocating choices to
    separate agencies
  • The choice of probability requires an analysis of
    the interaction between the revenue service and
    the taxpayers
  • The revenue service reacts to income declarations
    and taxpayers react to the expected detection
    probability

40
Tax Compliance Game
  • A strategy for the revenue service is the
    probability with which it chooses to audit any
    given value of declaration
  • A strategy for a taxpayers is a choice of
    declaration given the audit strategy of the
    revenue service
  • At a Nash equilibrium the strategy choices must
    be mutually optimal
  • In this game predictability in auditing cannot be
    an equilibrium strategy

41
Tax Compliance Game
  • Observe
  • No auditing at all cannot be optimal because it
    would mean maximal tax evasion
  • Auditing of all declarations cannot be a solution
    because this incurs excessive auditing costs
  • A pre-specified limit on the range of
    declarations that will be audited since those
    evading will remain outside this limit
  • To be unpredictable the audit strategy must be
    random

42
Tax Compliance Game
  • The probability of an audit should be high for an
    income report that is low compared to what one
    would expect from someone in that taxpayer's
    occupation
  • Or it should be high given the information on
    previous tax returns for that taxpayer
  • In either case a taxpayer should not be able to
    predict if they will be audited

43
Tax Compliance Game
  • A version of the strategic interaction is
    depicted in Fig. 16.7
  • A taxpayer with income Y can either evade
    (reporting zero income) or not (truthful income
    report)
  • By reporting truthfully the taxpayer pays tax T
    to the revenue service (with T lt Y)
  • The revenue service can either audit the income
    report or not audit
  • An audit costs C, C lt T, for the revenue service
    to conduct and is accurate in detecting evasion
  • If the taxpayer is caught evading the tax T plus
    a fine F is paid (where F gt C)

44
Tax Compliance Game
Figure 16.7 Compliance game
45
Tax Compliance Game
  • There is no pure strategy equilibrium in this tax
    compliance game
  • If the revenue service does not audit the
    taxpayer strictly prefers evading and therefore
    the revenue service is better-off auditing as T
    F gt C
  • If the revenue service audits with certainty, the
    taxpayer prefers not to evade as T F gt T, which
    implies that the revenue service is better-off
    not auditing
  • The revenue must play a mixed strategy in
    equilibrium with the audit strategy being random
  • The taxpayers evasion strategy must also be
    random

46
Tax Compliance Game
  • Let e be the probability that the taxpayer
    evades, and p the probability of audit
  • In equilibrium the players must be indifferent
    between their two pure strategies
  • For the revenue service to be indifferent between
    auditing and not auditing the cost of auditing C
    must equal the expected gain in tax and fine
    revenue eT F
  • For the taxpayer to be indifferent between
    evading and not evading the expected gain from
    evading (1 p)T must equal the expected penalty
    pF
  • The equilibrium is
  • e C/(T F), p T/(T F)

47
Tax Compliance Game
  • The equilibrium payoffs are
  • u Y T, v T (C/(TF))T
  • The taxpayer is indifferent between evading or
    not evading so equilibrium payoff is equal to
    truthful payoff Y T
  • This is because
  • Unpaid taxes and the fine cancel out in expected
    terms
  • Increasing the fine does not affect the taxpayer

48
Tax Compliance Game
  • A higher fine increases the payoff of the revenue
    service since it reduces the amount of evasion
  • increasing the penalty is Pareto-improving
  • The equilibrium payoffs also reflect a cost of
    evasion
  • for any tax T paid by the taxpayer the revenue
    service receives T D
  • where D (C/(T F))T is the deadweight loss of
    evasion
  • Evasion involves a deadweight loss that is
    increasing with the tax rate

49
Compliance and Social Interaction
  • Evasion is more likely when others already evade
  • Payoff from non-compliance is increasing with the
    number of non-compliers
  • Aggregate compliance tendency is toward one of
    the extremes

50
Compliance and Social Interaction
  • This is shown in Fig. 16.8
  • Always move away from the intersection

Figure 16.8 Equilibrium compliance
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)
About PowerShow.com