Title: Microeconomics 2
1Microeconomics 2
- Answers to the questions on the First Specimen
Examination Paper for the new style examination
2Rules of examination
- Please use the answer sheets attached to the
examination paper. Students should not bring
their own electronic calculators standard
university electronic calculators will be
provided at each desk. - There are (at the moment 27 there will be) n
questions in sets of various sizes. Each set of
questions is preceded by a preamble, which
remains in force until the next preamble. Four
marks are awarded for each correct answer and one
mark will be deducted for each wrong answer. The
resulting mark, denoted by x will be between -n
and 4n. It will then be converted into a final
mark for this module y using the formula y
20(xn)/n, which ensures that the final mark will
lie between 0 and 100.
3(No Transcript)
4Preamble to and Questions 1 to 4
- Consider a market for a hypothetical good in
which there are a number of buyers and sellers,
each of which wants to buy or sell one unit of
the good. The reservation prices for the buyers
are 9, 7, 11 and 7. The reservation prices of the
sellers are 6, 10 and 6. - Question 1What is the maximum quantity demanded?
- Question 2What is the maximum quantity supplied?
- Question 3 What is the price at which aggregate
demand equals aggregate supply? - Question 4 What is the quantity exchanged when
aggregate demand equals aggregate supply?
5Notes to Questions 1 to 4
- Aggregate demand equals aggregate supplyIf the
demand or supply at a price consists of a set of
values because some buyers are indifferent about
buying at that price or some sellers are
indifferent about selling at that price, then
interpret this condition as being satisfied if
there is some possible value of aggregate demand
at that price which is equal to some possible
value of aggregate supply at that price. - Might also be questions on
- Price-setting by sellers
- Price-setting by buyers
- Other forms of trade
6Answers to Questions 1 to 4found by drawing
demand and supply curves
Question 1 4 Question 2 3 Question 3 any price
between 7 and 9 Question 4 2
7Preamble to and Questions 5 and 6
- Consider an individual with quasi-linear
preferences whose indifference curve between
money (on the vertical axis) and the quantity of
a DISCRETE good (on the horizontal axis) is as
given in Figure 1 attached to this script.
Suppose the individual starts with an endowment
at the point marked X in the figure. Suppose
there is a market in which the DISCRETE good can
be sold or bought at a fixed price. Suppose the
price at the moment is 15. (You might like to
know that the equation of the curve is m 60/q
where m and q are the variables on the vertical
and horizontal axes respectively.) - Question 5 State whether the individual will be
a buyer or a seller and how many units he or she
will buy or sell at this price. - Question 6 What will the individual's surplus be
at this price?
8(No Transcript)
9Answers to Questions 5 and 6
- Starts at (3,20) (good, money). Price is 15
- Cannot buy 2 not enough money
- If buys 1 moves to (4,5) surplus -10 (minus 10)
- If does nothing surplus nothing
- If sells 1 moves to (2,35) surplus 5
- If sells 2 moves to (1,50) surplus -10 (minus
10) - Hence sells 1 and has surplus 5.
10Preamble to and Questions 7 and 8
- Consider an individual with quasi-linear
preferences whose indifference curves between
money (on the vertical axis) and the quantity of
a CONTINUOUS good (on the horizontal axis) are as
given in Figure 2 attached to this script.
Suppose the individual starts with an endowment
at the point marked X in the figure. Suppose
there is a market in which the CONTINUOUS good
can be sold or bought at a fixed price. Also
inserted in the figure are the budget lines for 4
different prices. Suppose the price is such that
the individual's optimal decision is to buy 2
units. (You might like to know that the equation
of the curve is m 60/q where m and q are the
variables on the vertical and horizontal axes
respectively. - Question 7 What approximately is the price in
the market? - Question 8 What approximately is the
individual's surplus at this price?
11(No Transcript)
12Answers to Questions 7 and 8
- If buys two units moves to flattest budget line
- This intersects the vertical axis at just over 27
- Hence has a slope of (27.2-20)/3 - 2.4
- Spends 4.8
- So moves from (3,20) to (5,15.2)
- The original indifference curve m 60/q passes
through (5,12) an hence ends up 3.2 above it. - Hence the price is 2.4 and the surplus is 3.2.
13Preamble to and Questions 9 and 10
- Consider an individual whose preferences are
either Perfect Substitutes, Perfect Complements
or Cobb-Douglas with parameter a, allocating a
given endowment between two goods whose prices
are p and 1 respectively. The individual's
endowments of the two goods are 15 and 8
respectively. In the first situation the price p
of Good 1 was 0.5 and the individual chose to
consume 15.5 of Good 1 and 7.75 of Good 2. In the
second situation the price p of Good 1 was 2 and
the individual chose to consume 15.2 of Good 1
and 7.6 of Good 2. - Question 9 What are the individual's
preferences? - Question 10 What is the value of the parameter a?
14Key results about demands(useful for questions 9
to 12)
- With Perfect Substitute preferences (with
parameter a)... - ...the Individual always spends all his or her
income on one of the two goods, unless... - ... the price equals the parameter a. (If pgta
then q10 if plta then q20) - With Perfect Complement preferences (with
parameter a)... - ...the ratio of the quantities (q2/q1) purchased
is always equal to the parameter a. - With Cobb-Douglas preferences (with parameter
a)... - ...the individual always spends a fraction a of
his or her income on Good 1.
15Answers to Questions 9 and 10
- Are prices different in the two situations?
- Is the quantity purchased of either good zero?
- No so cannot be Perfect Substitutes.
- Is the proportion of income spent on Good 1 in
the two situations the same? proportion
15.50.5/(150.58)0.5 in 1 and proportion
15.22/(1528)0.796666 in 2. - No so cannot be Cobb-Douglas.
- Is the ratio of quantities (q2/q1) the same in
the two situations 7.75/15.51/2 and
7.6/15.21/2. - Yes - hence Perfect Complements with a1/2.
16A little bit more on CD demands(useful for
questions 13 to 16)
- ...the individual always spends a fraction a of
his or her income on Good 1. - Suppose the individual has an endowment only of
Good 1 e1 - Suppose the prices are p1 and p2. The value of
his endowment is p1e1. Spending a fraction a of
this on Good 1 means that p1q1 ap1e1 so that
q1 ae1. - Suppose the individual has an endowment only of
Good 2 e2 - Suppose the prices are p1 and p2. The value of
his endowment is p2e2. Spending a fraction a of
this on Good 1 means that p1q1 ap2e2 and
spending the residual fraction on Good 2 means
that p2q2 (1-a)p2e2 so that q2 (1-a)e2.
17Preamble to and Questions 11 and 12
- Consider an individual whose preferences are
either Perfect Substitutes, Perfect Complements
or Cobb-Douglas with parameter a, allocating a
given monetary income between two goods whose
prices are p and 1 respectively. The individual's
endowment of money is 80. In the first situation
the price p of Good 1 was 1 and the individual
chose to consume 20 of Good 1 and 60 of Good 2.
In the second situation the price p of Good 1 was
1/3 and the individual chose to consume 60 of
Good 1 and 60 of Good 2. - Question 11 What are the individual's
preferences? - Question 12 What is the value of the parameter a?
18Answers to Questions 11 and 12
- Are prices different in the two situations?
- Is the quantity purchased of either good zero?
- No so cannot be Perfect Substitutes.
- Is the ratio of quantities (q2/q1) the same in
the two situations 60/203 in situation 1 and
60/601 in situation 2. - No cannot be Perfect Complements.
- Is the proportion of income spent on Good 1 in
the two situations the same? proportion
20/80¼ in situation 1 and proportion
60(1/3)/80¼ in situation 2. - Yes hence Cobb-Douglas with parameter ¼.
19Preamble to and Questions 13 to 16
- Consider competitive exchange of two goods, Good
1 and Good 2, between two Individuals A and B. A
starts with an endowment of 12 units of Good 1
and none of Good 2. B starts with an endowment of
12 units of Good 2 and none of Good 1. Individual
A has Perfect Complement Preferences with a
parameter 2. Individual B has Cobb-Douglas
Preferences with a parameter 2/3. (In answering
this question you should note a convention that
we use here in order for a situation to be
termed a competitive equilibrium we require that
both individuals are STRICTLY better off than
they were with their initial endowments.) - Question 13 Determine whether a competitive
equilibrium exists, and if so, determine the
competitive equilibrium exchange rate. - Question 14 If a competitive equilibrium exists,
how many units of good 1 are exchanged? - Question 15 If a competitive equilibrium exists,
how many units of good 2 are exchanged? - Question 16 Would dividing EQUALLY the initial
endowments of the two goods be an efficient way
of finally allocating the two goods to the two
individuals?
20The simplest way is with an Edgeworth Box
- Draw in the price-offer curves.
- For PC it is easy. For PS it would help to draw
in some of the indifference curves. - For CD make use of the fact that A has all of
Good 1 and B all of Good 2. - Here B wants to keep 1/3 of his/her Good 2.
- If the price-offer curves intersect inside the
box at a point where both are better off then
that is the competitive equilibrium. If not, not.
21(No Transcript)
22Answers to Questions 13 to 16
- The competive exchange is at (4,8).
- The price line from the endowment point (12,12)
to (4,8) has slope 1. - The competitive exchange rate is therefore 1 for
1. - A gives up 8 of Good 1 for 8 of Good 2
- B gives up 8 of Good 2 for 8 of Good 1
- Diving equally at point (6,6) is not efficient.
- So answers are 1 for 1 8 8 No
23Preamble to and Question 17
- Consider a perfectly competitive firm with a
quadratic cost function C(q) a bq cq2 where
the parameters a, b and c are given below (note
that the firm has to incur its fixed cost a
whether it produces any output or not). Suppose
that the given price for its output is 20. The
value of a is 15, the value of b is 7, and the
value of c is 2. - Question 17 What profit does it make at its
profit-maximising (loss-minimising) output (a
negative number if it makes a loss)?
24Answer to Question 17
- The cost function is C(q) 15 7q 2q2
- Hence Marginal Cost MC 7 4q
- The profit-maximising condition for a competitive
(price-taking) firm is price MC - The price 20.
- The condition implies 20 7 4q
- So q 3.25 and hence
- Profit 203.25 (15 73.2523.252)6.125
25Preamble to and Question 18
- Consider a simple economy with two individuals, A
and B, each of whom can produce both of two
goods, 1 and 2. If A works full-time on Good 1,
he or she can produce 7 units of Good 1 if A
works full-time on Good 2, he or she can produce
9 units of Good 2 more generally, if he or she
works a fraction f of his or her time on Good 1
and a fraction (1-f) of his or her time on Good 2
then he or she can produce a quantity 7f of Good
1 and a quantity 9(1-f) of Good 2. If B works
full-time on Good 1, he or she can produce 14
units of Good 1 if B works full-time on Good 2,
he or she can produce 11 units of Good 2 more
generally, if he or she works a fraction f of his
or her time on Good 1 and a fraction (1-f) of his
or her time on Good 2 then he or she can produce
a quantity 14f of Good 1 and a quantity 11(1-f)
of Good 2. Suppose that they agree that they
jointly want to produce 14 units of Good 1. - Question 18 Given their decision (above) on how
much of Good 1 that they want to jointly produce,
what is the maximum amount of Good 2 that the two
individuals can produce?
26Answer to Question 18
- For every 1 unit less of Good 1 produced A(B) can
produce 9/7 (11/14) more of Good 2. - Thus A (B) is relatively better at producing Good
2 (1) than B (A). - So A (B) should specialise in Good 2 (1).
- Societys production possibility frontier goes
from (21,0) to (14,9) to (0,20). - If 14 of Good 1 is produced then 9 is the most of
Good 2 that they can produce.
27Preamble to and Question 19
- An individual is observed spending his or her
monetary income on two goods, 1 and 2, in two
situations, the price of Good 2 always being 1.
In the first situation the individual's income
was 14 and the price of Good 1 was 1. The
individual was observed to purchase 2 units of
Good 1 and 12 units of Good 2.In the second
situation the individual's income was 10 and the
price of Good 1 was 2/3. The individual was
observed to purchase 10 units of Good 1 and 3 1/3
units of Good 2. - Question 19 Does this behaviour violate the weak
axiom of revealed preference?
28Answer to Question 19
- In graph, the blue is the first situation (income
14 and prices both 1) and 1 the chosen point. - The red is the second situation (income 10 and
prices 2/3 and 1) and 2 the chosen point. - The lines are the budget lines.
- 1 revealed preferred to 2 (in the first
situation) but we cannot infer anything about 1
and 2 from the second situation (because 1 was
not available). - We can also draw convex indifference curves which
would rationalise both choices. - So it is not a violation of the axiom.
29(No Transcript)
30(No Transcript)
31Preamble to and Question 20
- An individual has Perfect Substitute preferences
over two goods, 1 and 2. The price of Good 2 is
fixed at 1, and the individual's monetary income
is 110. Initially the price of Good 1 is 1.0 but
then it rises to 1.1.The value of the a parameter
is 0.8. - Question 20 What is the Equivalent Variation of
this price rise (that is, what reduction in his
income would be equivalent to the effect of the
price rise)?
32Answer to Question 20
- The blue (red) line is the budget line in the
first (second) situation income 110 and prices
1 and 1 (income 110 and prices 1.1 and 1). - The thin black line is the highest indifference
curve reached in the first situation... - ... and the second.
- So no loss of utility.
- So EV is 0.
33Preamble to and Question 21
- Consider an inter-temporal choice problem with
two periods where an individual's preferences
over consumption, c1 and c2, in two periods 1 and
2 is given by U(c1, c2)u(c1) u(c2)/(1 ?)
where ? is the individual's discount rate (which
should lie between 0 and 1) and u(c) is the
square root of c (that is, u(c) vc).The first
consumption stream gives 36 in the first period
and 1 in the second the second consumption
stream gives 16 in the first period and 16 in the
second. - Question 21 What discount rate (if any between 0
and 1) would make the individual indifferent
between these two streams of consumption?
34Answer to Question 21
- We have that U(c1, c2)u(c1) u(c2)/(1 ?)
- and that u(c) c1/2 vc
- We want the individual to be indifferent between
(36,1) and (16,16). - So we need utilities to be the same. Hence
- U(36, 1) U(16, 16), that is
- 6 1/(1 ?) 4 4/(1 ?) that is
- 2 3/(1 ?), that is, (1 ?) 3/2 1.5.
- Hence ? 0.5
35Preamble to and Question 22
- Consider an individual facing a risky choice
(given below) who has preferences over risky
choices given by the Expected Utility model. The
individual's utility function is given by u(x)
xr where the parameter r (which indicates his
risk attitude) is equal to 1. The risky choice
gives outcome x equal to 45 with probability 0.4
and outcome x equal to 33 with probability 0.6. - Question 22 What is the individual's Certainty
Equivalent for this risky choice (that is, what
amount of money, received with certainty, would
be equivalent for this individual to this risky
choice)?
36Answer to Question 22
- The Certainty Equivalent is the amount of money
received with certainty which is equivalent
(given the individuals preferences) to the risky
choice. - So the individual is indifferent between the CE
and the risky choice. The risky choice gives 45
with probability 0.4 and 33 with probability 0.6.
- The utility function is u(x) x.
- So the Expected Utility of the risky choice is
0.4u(45) 0.6u(33) 0.445 0.633 37.8. - The CE must therefore satisfy u(CE) 37.8 and
hence - CE 37.8
37Preamble to and Question 23
- Consider a competitive market with linear demand
and supply curves, as specified below. At the
moment there is no tax imposed by the
government.. The demand curve is given (in
inverse form) by P 70 - Q the supply curve is
given (in inverse form) by P 22 0.5Q. - Question 23 Suppose that the government have
decided to impose a tax at 10 of the price of
the good. This will cause a higher price for the
buyer, a lower price for the seller, and a
deadweight loss of surplus in the market.
Calculate this deadweight loss (to the nearest
integer).
38Answer to Question 23 (One way)
- Before the tax was imposed price and quantity
were given by supplydemand that is, by 70-Q
220.5Q that is, by P 38 and Q 32. - If we denote the price received by the seller as
P, then the price paid by the buyer becomes 1.1P. - Hence the demand curve becomes 1.1P 70-Q while
the supply curve remains as before. Solving
demand supply we now get and Q 29.548 and P
36.774. So the tax is 3.677 and the quantity
exchanged goes down by 2.452.
39Answer to Question 23 (one way)
- Hence the demand curve becomes 1.1P 70-Q while
the supply curve remains as before. Solving
demand supply we now get and Q 29.548 and P
36.774.
40Answer to Question 23 (Other way)
- Before the tax was imposed price and quantity
were given by supplydemand that is, by 70-Q
220.5Q that is, by P 38 and Q 32. - If we denote the price paid by the buyer as P,
then the price received by the seller becomes
P/1.1 - Hence the demand curve remains as before while
the supply curve becomes P/1.1 22 0.5Q.
Solving demand supply we now get and Q 29.548
and P 40.451.774. So the tax is 3.677 and the
quantity exchanged goes down by 2.452.
41Answer to Question 23 (other way)
- Hence the demand curve remains as before while
the supply curve becomes P/1.1 22 0.5Q.
Solving demand supply we now get and Q 29.548
and P 40.451.774.
42Answer to Question 23 (a simpler way)
- 40.451 is price paid by buyers with tax.
- 36.774 is price received by sellers with tax.
- 29.548 is quantity exchanged with tax.
- So the deadweight loss is the area of the
triangle of height 3.667 and width 2.452 which
is ½3.6772.452 which is 5 to nearest integer.
43Preamble to and Question 24
- Consider a monopolist with a linear demand
function (as given below) and a linear cost
function (as given below). The demand curve is
given (in inverse form) by P 81 - Q the cost
function is given by - C(Q) 39 Q.
- Question 24 What are the monopolist's optimal
price and output?
44Answer to Question 24
- The monopolists Marginal Cost is MC 1.
- Its revenue is PQ (81-Q)Q 81Q Q2.
- Hence its Marginal Revenue MR 81 2Q.
- For maximum profits MC MR and hence
- 1 81 2Q
- and hence Q40 and so its price P 41.
- So the answers (price and output) are 41 and 40.
45Preamble to and Questions 25 and 26
- Consider a game between a row player (Individual
A) and a column player (Individual B) where the
payoff matrix is given in the 'table for the game
theory questions' attached to this examination
paper and is repeated here. The first row of the
payoff matrix is 27,213,39 33,49. The
second row of the payoff matrix is 8,12 38,50
40,23. The third row of the payoff matrix is
23,25 37,48 15,5. - Question 25 List all the Nash Equilibrium of
this game when played simultaneously. - Question 26 Now suppose we change the rules of
the game with New Rules 1 we let A move first
and then B responds with New Rules 2 we let B
move first and then A responds What is A's best
optimal row decision with New Rules 1 and what
is B's best column decision with New Rules 2?
46Answers to Questions 25 and 26
Table for questions 25 and 26 Table for questions 25 and 26 Individual B Individual B Individual B
Table for questions 25 and 26 Table for questions 25 and 26 Column 1 Column 2 Column 3
Individual A Row 1 27,2 13,39 33,49
Individual A Row 2 8,12 38,50 40,23
Individual A Row 3 23,25 37,48 15,5
- For Question 25 you just try each cell and see it
is a NE you will find 2,2 as the only NE. - For Question 26 you just see what the starting
player would end up with for each choice. (A
would choose row 2 B column 2.)
47Preamble to and Question 27
- Consider a Cournot (quantity-setting) duopoly in
which the aggregate demand curve (given below)
and the cost functions (given below) are all
linear. The demand curve is given (in inverse
form) by P 86 - Q, where Q is aggregate output
the cost function of firm 1 is given by C(Q1)
Q1, where Q1 is the output of Firm 1 the cost
function of firm 2 is given by C(Q2) 2 Q2,
where Q2 is the output of Firm 2 of course Q Q1
Q2. - Question 27 What are the equilibrium (Cournot)
optimal outputs for the two firms?
48Answer to Question 27
- Profits of firm 1 are PQ1 ? C(Q1)
- 86-Q1-Q2 Q1 ? Q1 85Q1 ? Q12 ? Q1Q2
- Maximising this wrt Q1 given Q2 gives
- 85 ? 2Q1 ? Q2 0 firm 1s reaction curve.
- Doing the same for firm 2 gives
- 84 ? Q1 ? 2Q2 0 firm 2s reaction curve.
- Solving the two reaction curves simultaneously
gives us Q128? and Q227?.
49That is the end of the First Specimen Examination
Paper
- Go slow there is plenty of time.
- The questions are easy if you understand
microeconomics. - They are difficult if you do not.
- You cannot memorise answers.
- You may want to memorise methods - but that is
exactly what I have been trying to teach you. - Obviously this is a specimen do look at the
document detailed description on the site.
50First Specimen Paper