Title: Eastman%20Kodak%20Co.%20v.%20Image%20Technical%20Services
1Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Technical Services
- Kodak Changes Policy to Require Most Users of its
Micrographic Equipment to Purchase Service from
Kodak in order to get Replacement Parts - Majority Finds Sufficient Evidence to go to Jury
re - Parts and Service Market as Separate
- Sufficient Power in Parts Market
- Harm to Consumers
2Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Technical Services
- Kodak/DOJ/Scalia tying monopolization claims
involving aftermarkets should be barred as a
matter of law if D has no power in original
equipment market - Kodak If consumers harmed, theyd switch to
competitors equipment - Majority Rejects Claim
- Theory Imperfect
- Evidence Doesnt Support
3Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Technical Services
- Ps Explanations of Why Theory Doesnt Work
- Buyers have high info costs
- Hard to figure LT costs of durable gds/services.
- Many purchases are govts
- don't do good job
- different departments do capital costs
operating costs. - High costs to switch
- Evidence of Price Discrimination
4Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Technical Services
- Ps Explanations of Why Theory Doesnt Work
- Buyers have high info costs
- High costs to switch
- High sunk costs (training price if already paid
for machine) - Unlikely to invest in new machine just b/c
service expensive - Evidence of Price Discrimination
5Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Technical Services
- Ps Explanations of Why Theory Doesnt Work
- Buyers have high info costs
- High costs to switch
- Evidence of Price Discrimination
- Favoring high volume users supports P's theory
- Suggests treating more favorably those customers
most likely to have had good info or incentive to
switch machines
6Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Technical Services
- DOJ version of theory
- Ks tie is part of marketing strategy spread
costs over time - Hide true price of machines
- Low sale price for equipment
- Make up with high service prices
7Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Technical Services
- DOJ version of theory
- Ks tie is marketing strategy spread costs over
time - Hide true price of machines
- Low sale price for equipment
- Make up with high service prices
- Majority Again record doesn't support
- K says its equipment prices were normal, not low
- If theory true, K shouldnt allow purchasers to
self-service.
8Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Technical Services
- SCALIA version of theory
- Ties of either parts or service to original
equipment OK if no power in equipment market.
(undisputed).
9Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Technical Services
- SCALIA version of theory
- Ties of either parts or service to original
equipment OK if no power in equipment market.
Should be same here b/c - Rational consumers should take policy into
account when purchasing equipment - Shouldnt base rule on irrational consumers
- Nut-N-Bolt analysis applies to Parts-N-Service
10Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Technical Services
- SCALIA version of theory
- 1. Rational consumers should take policy into
account when purchasing equipment - BUT policy changed no evidence that customers
aware of in advance - Leads to lower ct cases different result if made
explicit to consumers at sale
11Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Technical Services
- SCALIA version of theory
- 2. Shouldnt base rule on irrational consumers.
Sounds appealing BUT - Not merely about stupid consumers thought
process hard and expensive (e.g., cars) - changes in models, service, etc.
- hard to get info
12Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Technical Services
- SCALIA version of theory
- 2. Shouldnt base rule on irrational consumers.
Sounds appealing BUT - Not merely about stupid consumers thought
process hard and expensive (e.g., cars) - Not clear monopolist should be allowed to take
advantage - If consumers irrational or have bad info, shd co.
get monopoly profits? - If govt bad consumer, shd taxpayers have to pay?
13Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Technical Services
- SCALIA version of theory
- 3. Nut-N-Bolt analysis applies to
Parts-N-Service - Scalia assumes services/parts purchased in fixed
proportions, so no addtl harm to consumer from
spreading parts monopoly into service.
14Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Technical Services
- SCALIA version of theory
- 3. Nut-N-Bolt analysis applies to
Parts-N-Service - Scalia assumes services/parts purchased in fixed
proportions, so no addtl harm to consumer from
spreading parts monopoly into service. BUT - No evidence of this at all
- Counterintuitive service varies may not require
parts
15Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Technical Services
- SCALIA version of theory
- Note that Scalias analysis focuses entirely on
theory no discussion of evidence or of what
Kodak actually was doing.
16Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Technical Services
- Significance of Case
- Evidence gt Theory
- Like Brown Williamson wont preclude cause of
action based on theory alone look at evidence - Note good lawyering by Ps
- Demonstrated evidence was inconsistent w Ds
theory - Theoretical explanation for why Ds theory didnt
work - Further evidence supporting that explanation
17Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Technical Services
- Significance of Case
- Evidence gt Theory
- 6-3 Majority (including Rehnquist) reject broad
read of Matsushita. - Key Language in middle paragraph of p.402
18Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Technical Services
p.402
- The Courts requirement in Matsushita that the
plaintiffs claims make economic sense did not
introduce a special burden on plaintiffs facing
summary judgment in antitrust cases. The Court
did not hold that if the moving party enunciates
any economic theory supporting its behavior,
regardless of its accuracy in reflecting the
actual market, it is entitled to summary
judgment. Matsushita demands only that the
nonmoving partys inferences be reasonable in
order to reach the jury, a requirement that was
not invented, but merely articulated, in that
decision. If the plaintiffs theory is
economically senseless, no reasonable jury could
find in its favor, and summary judgment should be
granted.
19Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Technical Services
- Significance of Case
- Evidence gt Theory
- 6-3 Majority (including Rehnquist) reject broad
read of Matsushita. - No reason for stronger test here than in
Matsushita - Didnt want to overdeter alleged behavior in
Matsushita (price-cutting) - Here, OK to deter high prices market
foreclosure -
20Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Technical Services
- Significance of Case
- Evidence gt Theory
- 6-3 Majority (including Rehnquist) reject broad
read of Matsushita. - No reason for stronger test here than in
Matsushita - Mid-para p.406 2d sentence It is clearly
reasonable to infer that Kodak has market power
to raise prices and drive out competition in the
aftermarkets, since respondents offer direct
evidence that Kodak did so.
21Eastman Kodak Co. v. Image Technical Services
22Post-Kodak Tying Caselaw
- Unsurprisingly, after Kodak, lot of cases re
aftermarkets, including - Kodak on Remand
- Franchising Cases
- Aftermarket Policies Announced in Advance
- University Housing/Food Service Cases
23Post-Kodak Tying Caselaw
- Kodak on Remand Info in Outline p. 416
- Franchising Cases
- Aftermarket Policies Announced in Advance
- University Housing/Food Service Cases
24Post-Kodak Tying Caselaw
- Kodak on Remand
- Franchising Cases (p.416)
- Aftermarket Policies Announced in Advance
- University Housing/Food Service Cases
25Post-Kodak Tying Caselaw Franchising Cases
(p.416)
- Nature of claims
- To operate franchise (tying product), franchisee
must use specific product brands (tied products) - Franchisees claim that their investment in the
franchise gives the franchisor market power
26Post-Kodak Tying Caselaw Franchising Cases
(p.416)
- Cases split as to availability of tying cause of
action - Some courts
- Kodak n/a once franchise agreement signed.
- E.g., Queen City (3d Cir. 1997) (Franchisees
purchase products because bound by contract, not
because forced by market power) ME Too simple
contract could forcing - Some courts
- Switching costs for franchisees higher than those
in Kodak - Franchisor can force franchisee to buy fungible
goods from it at market or above-market prices
27Post-Kodak Tying Caselaw Franchising Cases
- Franchise Cases Arguably Different From Kodak
- Franchisees are dealers of package of products
services - To get franchise, agree to sell package chosen by
franchisor - Franchisor needs franchisees has interest in
their profitability. - Tie is more like a non-price restraint on how
franchise products sold (generally OK under
Sylvania) - Franchisee is not ultimate consumer
- No info/switching costs for consumer
- Consumers can discipline franchisor if they don't
like package or if prices too high - Should disputes between franchisees franchisors
be treble damage AT suits? Cf. Photovest (p.352)
28Post-Kodak Tying Caselaw
- Kodak on Remand
- Franchising Cases
- Aftermarket Policies Announced in Advance (p.416)
- University Housing/Food Service Cases
29Post-Kodak Tying Caselaw Prior Knowledge
- Several cases distinguish Kodak where purchasers
knew of tie involving aftermarkets prior to
purchasing equipment - These cases say that you cant succeed on Kodak
claim w/o market power in equipment market unless
the tie is a change in policy or is hidden
30Post-Kodak Tying Caselaw
- Kodak on Remand
- Franchising Cases
- Aftermarket Policies Announced in Advance
- University Housing/Food Service Cases (not in
outline)
31Post-Kodak Tying Caselaw University
Aftermarkets
- Hamilton 128 F.3d 59 (2d Cir. 1997)
- 2 claim by fraternities against D college re
both housing meal plans - Court allows to proceed over motion to dismiss
- Sufficient claim that interstate commerce is
involved (even though D is college) - Sufficient allegations of monopoly potential
harm from monopoly
32Post-Kodak Tying Caselaw University
Aftermarkets
- Hack, 237 F.3d 81 (2d Cir. 2000)
- Challenge to Yale U. requirement that
underclassmen live in co-ed housing. - 1st Amdt. Interference w Free Exercise of
Religion (held not state actor) - Fair Housing Act Discrimination on Basis of
Religion (insufficient allegations) - Sherman Act Tying (insufficient power)
33Post-Kodak Tying Caselaw University
Aftermarkets
- Hack, 237 F.3d 81 (2d Cir. 2000)
- Tying challenge to Yale U. housing requirement
fails - Yale doesnt have market power in higher
education market - Market isnt local
- Lots of superb institutions of higher learning
(citing US News)
34Post-Kodak Tying Caselaw University
Aftermarkets
- Hack, 237 F.3d 81 (2d Cir. 2000)
- Tying challenge to Yale U. housing requirement
fails - Yale doesnt have market power in higher ed.
market - Cant claim economic power on basis that youre
locked into Yale once youve accepted - For tying purposes, cant claim economic power
arises from contractual arrangement affecting
distinct class of consumers (citing Queen City
franchising case) - Distinguishes Hamilton b/c there college
abruptly changed rules after students attending
35Post-Kodak Tying Caselaw University
Aftermarkets
- Hack/Hamilton fact pattern could give rise to
several different issues - Kodak issues (market power 1 product or 2)
- Is university education subject to AT laws?
- State action issues if public university
- Policy clearly articulated in grant of authority?
- When is public univ. like municipality (as
opposed to actual arm of state)
36LOGISTICS ANNOUNCEMENTS
- Project
- Questions?
- Ill take questions Thursday not after
- Exam Workshop Online Live Shows
- Today 100-145 Room 209
- Thursday 1230- 145 Room 109
- Missing Write-Ups End-of-Chapter Info
37Microsoft Section Two in the New Millennium
38Difficulty Inherent in 2 Conduct Cases
- Monopoly Power inherently harmful b/c output low
prices high - Dont want to allow monopoly to perpetuate itself
- Dont want to allow monopoly to get extra
advantages in other markets
39Difficulty Inherent in 2 Conduct Cases
- Monopoly Power inherently harmful
- BUT dont want threat of enforcement to
exacerbate harm to market - Want monopoly to compete aggressively
- Want monopoly to innovate
- Want to take advantage of scale economies other
efficiencies - Enforcement is expensive
40Difficulty Inherent in 2 Conduct Cases
- Monopoly Power inherently harmful
- Dont want threat of enforcement to exacerbate
harm - How draw legal standards to strike balance?
- Is biggest danger under-enforcement or
over-deterrence? - i.e., When in doubt, should you presume harmful
or OK? - Obviously hard to draw lines precisely
- Also want to give adequate notice to firms w
market power
41Difficulty Inherent in 2 Conduct Cases
- Monopoly Power inherently harmful
- Dont want threat of enforcement to exacerbate
harm - How draw legal standards to strike balance?
- Subset of more general issue What to do with
arrangements that plausibly have both pro- and
anti-competitive effects? - Exclusion from Joint Ventures
- Mergers
- Vertical Price-Fixing
42Overview of Microsoft
- Microsoft Windows
- The Backstreet Boys
43Overview of Microsoft
- Common Claim by Opponents of Lawsuit Punishing
MS for Success
44Overview of Microsoft
- Claim by Opponents Punishing MS for Success
- Common Industry View
- Not successful b/c of strengths of products
- History of Windows made difficulties for
software competitors - Re compatibility
- Re unnecessary size of Windows
45Overview of Microsoft
- Claim by Opponents Punishing MS for Success
- Common Industry View
- Not successful b/c of strengths of products
- History re Windows made difficulties for
software competitors - Lots of evidence of specific bad conduct often
ignored in commentary
46Overview of Microsoft
- Theory of case MS trying to maintain monopoly by
discouraging development of platforms in
competition with Windows - Unusual b/c not really trying to leverage Windows
monopoly into market power/profits elsewhere
47Overview of Microsoft
- Theory of case MS trying to maintain monopoly by
discouraging development of competing platforms - E.g., 2 Claim Attempt to monopolize browser
market - Lots of evidence of use of monopoly power to try
to eliminate Netscape - But not targeted at making monopoly profits in
browser market - Attempt to eliminate alternate platforms from
which competitors could attack Windows
48Overview of Microsoft
- Conduct Lots of evidence of attempts to prevent
growth of systems that would compete with Windows - Enough to be pretty clearly violation under
existing cases maintenance of Windows monopoly - Lot of very bad behavior ,
- Threats to IBM Intel
- Lying about compatibility w Java
- Some more questionable
- Aspects of integrating Explorer into Windows
- Exclusionary Ks
49Overview of Microsoft
- Monopoly Power Pretty Clear
- 95 share
- Entry barriers from network effects
- Behavior suggests market power (threats to
IBM/Intel)
50Overview of Microsoft
- Important Questions Raised
- Relevance of High-Tech Markets Network Effects
- Burdens of Proof in 2 Conduct Cases
- Application of Tying Doctrine to Software
Integration - Difficulty of Remedy
51Microsoft Network Effects in Rapidly Changing
High-Tech Markets
- Two special contextual problems raised by
Microsoft noted in Overview in case - Rapidly Changing High-Tech Markets
- Network Effects
52Microsoft Network Effects in Rapidly Changing
High-Tech Markets
- Rapidly Changing High-Tech Markets
- Market conditions regularly change with technical
improvements - How should we address Antitrust violations?
- Focus on Deterrence
- Act quickly firmly
- Punish so others dont take advantage
- Laissez-Faire?
- Assume market will cure harms in medium run
- Assume costs of intervention enforcement gt harms
53Microsoft Network Effects in Rapidly Changing
High-Tech Markets
- Rapidly Changing High-Tech Markets
- Market conditions regularly change with technical
improvements - How should we address Antitrust violations?
- Court notes great difficulties re remedy
- Conduct remedies may be rendered obsolete very
quickly - Difficult to arrive at appropriate structural
remedies
54Microsoft Network Effects in Rapidly Changing
High-Tech Markets
- 2. Network Effects
- P. 419 In markets characterized by network
effects, one product or standard tends towards
dominance, because the utility that a user
derives from consumption of the good increases
with the number of other agents consuming the
good. Michael L. Katz Carl Shapiro, Network
Externalities, Competition, and Compatibility.
55Microsoft Network Effects in Rapidly Changing
High-Tech Markets
- 2. Network Effects
- Utility increases with the number of other
agents consuming the good - E.g., VHS, Windows, telephone networks,
YouTube/MySpace
56Microsoft Network Effects in Rapidly Changing
High-Tech Markets
- 2. Network Effects
- Utility increases with the number of other
agents consuming the good - Competition may be sequential not simultaneous
57Microsoft Network Effects in Rapidly Changing
High-Tech Markets
- 2. Network Effects
- Utility increases with the number of other
agents consuming the good - Competition may be sequential not simultaneous
- Court no consensus about how to address
- Let market operate v.
- Worry about acts to extend/maintain ST monop
58Microsoft Network Effects in Rapidly Changing
High-Tech Markets
- Legal Effects of Two Taken Together?
- Court notes might push in opposite directions
- MS argued should affect Q of monopoly power
- MS did not argue conduct (might be stronger)
- Also argument going to remedy
59Microsoft Burdens of Proof in 2 Conduct Cases
- MS was allowed to offer justification for conduct
- Aspen IBM suggest OK if legitimate business
reason (LBR), at least - For refusal to deal w rival
- For physical integration of system
- Who bears burden of proof on LBR?
- cf. per se v. Rule of Reason