Title: Lecture 6: Compensating Wage Differentials
1Lecture 6 Compensating Wage Differentials
- The model of competitive labor markets implies
that as long as workers or firms can freely enter
and exit the marketplace, there will be a single
wage in the economy if all jobs are alike and all
workers are alike.
2- All jobs are not the same. Adam Smith in 1776
argued that compensating wage differentials arise
to compensate workers for the nonwage
characteristics of jobs. It is not the wage that
is equated across jobs in a competitive market,
but the whole of the advantages and
disadvantages of the job. - Workers differ in their preferences for job
characteristics and firms differ in the working
conditions that they offer. The theory of
compensating differentials tells a story of how
workers and firms match and mate in the labor
market.
31. Workers and Firms Choice with Risky Jobs
- E.g. Employer X NT.100 per hour, clean, safe
work conditions - Employer Y NT.100 per hour, dirty, noisy
factory - ? Most workers would undoubtedly choose employer
X. - If employer Y decides not to alter working
conditions, it must pay wage above NT.100 to be
competitive in the labor market. - ? The extra wage it must pay to attract workers
is called a compensating wage differential
because the higher wage is paid to compensate
workers for the undesirable working conditions. - After the wage rise of firm Y, if both firms
could obtain the quantity and quality of works
they wanted, the wage differential would be an
equilibrium differential, in the sense that there
be no forces causing the differential to change.
4 The compensating wage differential serves two
purposes
- It serves a social need by giving people an
incentive to voluntarily do dirty, dangerous, or
unpleasant work or a financial penalty on
employers offering unfavorable working
conditions. - At an individual level, it serves as a reward to
workers who accept unpleasant jobs by paying them
more than comparable workers in more pleasant
jobs. Those who opt for more pleasant conditions
have to buy them by accepting lower pay.
5- ? Compensating wage differentials provide the key
to the valuation of the nonpecuniary aspects of
employment. - Note
- The predicted outcome of the compensating
wage differential theory of job choice is not
that employees working under bad conditions
receive more than those working in good
conditions. The prediction is that, holding
worker characteristics constant, employees in bad
jobs receive higher wages than those working
under more pleasant conditions.
6 The compensating wage differential theory is
based on three assumptions
- Utility Maximization
- Workers seek to maximize their utility, not
their income. Compensating wage differentials
will only arise if some people do not choose the
highest-paying job offered, preferring instead a
lower-paying but more pleasant job. - ? Wages do not equalize in this case. The net
advantage the overall utility from the pay and
the psychic aspects of the job tend to equalize
for the marginal workers.
7- 2. Worker Information
- Workers are aware of the job
characteristics of - potential importance to them.
- ? Company offering a bad job with no
compensating wage differential would have trouble
recruiting or retaining workers, trouble that
would eventually force it to raise its wage. - Note Our predictions about compensating wage
differentials hold only for job characteristics
that workers know about. - 3. Workers Mobility
- Workers have a range of job offers from
which to choose. It is the act of choosing safe
jobs over dangerous ones that forces employers
offering dangerous work to raise wages.
82. The Hedonic Wage Function
- A wage theory based on the assumption of
philosophical hedonism that workers strive to
maximize utility. - To simplify our discussion, we shall analyze
just one dimension risk of injury on the job
and assume that the compensating wage
differentials for every other dimension have
already been established. - ? To obtain a complete understanding of the job
selection process and the outcomes of that
process, it is necessary to consider both the
employer and employee sides of the market.
9(1) Employee Considerations
Some combinations of wage rates and risk levels
that would yield the same level of utility can be
represented by indifference curve map.
U2 slopes upward because risk of injury is a
bad job characteristics. i.e., if
risk increases, wage must rise if utility is to
be held constant.
W
U3
U2
U1
Risk
10People differ in their aversion to the risk of
being injured. Those who are very sensitive to
this risk will require large wage increases for
any increase in risk (UH), while those who are
less sensitive will require smaller wage
increases to hold utility constant (UL).
Highly Averse to Risk
W
Moderately Averse to Risk
UL
UH
Risk
11(2) Employer Considerations
- Assumptions
- It is presumably costly to reduce the risk of
injury facing employees. - Perfect competition ? Firms operate at zero
profits. - All other job characteristics are presumably
given or already determined. - ? If a firm undertakes a program to reduce the
risk of injury, it must reduce wages to remain
competitive.
12- Forces on the employer side of the market tent
to cause low risk to be associated with low wages
and high risk to be associated with high wages,
holding other things constant. - ?The employer trade-offs between wages and levels
of injury risk can be graphed through the use of
isoprofit curves , which show the various
combinations of risk and wage level that yield a
given level of profits.
13W
The concavity of isoprofit curves is a
representation of our assumption that there are
diminishing marginal returns to safety
expenditures. ? The cost of reducing risk levels
is reflected in the slope of the isoprofit curve.
M
N
Risk
14W
Y
Employers differ in the ease (cost) with which
they can eliminate hazards. ? Firm X can reduce
risk more cheaply than firm Y.
X
X
Y
Risk
15 (3) The Matching of Employer and Employees
- Graphing worker indifference curves and
employer isoprofit curves together can show which
workers choose which offers.
B2
W
Y
As choice (WAX, RAX) ? value safety higher If
A took Bs offer A1 lt A2 Bs choice (WBY,
RBY)
B1
WBY
X
WAX
A2
Y
X
A1
Risk
RAX
RBY
16- Since X can produce safety more cheaply than Y, X
will be a low-risk producer who attracts
employees, like A, who value safety highly. Y
attracts people like B, who have a relatively
strong preference for money wages and a
relatively weak preference for safety. - Note The only offers of jobs to workers with a
chance of being accepted lie along XRY. - ? The curve XRY can be called an offer curve,
because only along XRY will offers employers
can afford to make be potentially acceptable to
employees.
17W
Offer Curve
The more types of firms there are in a market,
the smoother this offer curve will be. It will
always slope upward because of our assumptions
that risk is costly to reduce and that employees
must be paid higher wages to keep their utility
constant if risk is increased.
Risk
18 Major Insights
- Wages rise with risk, other things equal.
? There will be compensating wage differentials
for job characteristics that are viewed as
undesirable by workers. - Workers with strong preferences for safety will
tend to take jobs in firms where safety can be
generated most cheaply.
? Firms and workers offer and accept jobs
in a fashion that makes the most of their
strengths and preferences.
193. Policy Application How Much is a Life Worth?
- Empirical Evidences
- Many studies estimate the hedonic function
relating wages - and the probability of injury on the job. This
literature - typically estimates regressions of the form
- wi ??i other variables
- Where wi gives the wage of worker i and ?i.
gives the - probability of injury on the workers job.
The coefficient?gives the wage change associated
with a one-unit increase in the probability of
injury. - Many empirical studies report a positive
relationship - between wages and hazardous or unsafe work
conditions, - regardless of how the hazard or the unsafe
nature of the - work environment is defined.
20- 2. Calculating the Value of Life
- The correlations of the wages and the probability
of injury on the - job allow us to calculate the value of life.
- Example
- Firm Probability of Fatal Injury
Annual Earnings - X ?x
wx - Y ?x .001
wx 5,000
21- The data suggests that each of the workers in
firm Y is willing to give up 5,000 per year to
reduce the probability of fatal injury in their
job by 0.001 units. Put differently, the 1,000
workers employed in firm Y are willing to give up
5 million (or 5,000x 1,000 workers) to save the
life of the one worker who will almost surely die
in any given year. The workers in firm Y,
therefore, value a life at 5 million. - This calculation instead gives the amount that
workers are jointly willing to pay to reduce the
likelihood that one of them will suffer a fatal
injury in any given year. It is the statistical
value of a life.