Title: Coase Theorem-Friedman, Harberger-Smit-Stigler Eric Rasmusen, erasmuse@Indiana.edu
1Coase Theorem-Friedman, Harberger-Smit-Stigler
Eric Rasmusen, erasmuse_at_Indiana.edu
G604, History of Thought, policy , 23 March 2006
2- Classics Public Policy George J. Stigler
(1971) "The Theory of Economic Regulation" The
Bell Journal of Economics and Management Science,
2(1) 3-21 (Spring 1971) David Friedman,
Law's Order, chapters 4 and 5, pages 36-62, on
the Coase Theorem and Calabresi and Melamed. (See
http//www.daviddfriedman.com/laws_order. )
Arnold C. Harberger (1954) "Monopoly and Resource
Allocation," The American Economic Review, Papers
and Proceedings of the Sixty-sixth Annual Meeting
of the American Economic Association, 44(2)
77-87 (May 1954) I have posted my lecture
notes and powerpoint slides on Stigler,
Coase-Friedman, and Harberger. Adam Smith,
The Wealth of Nations (1776) "Of the Causes of
Improvement in the productive Powers of Labour,
and of the Order according to which its Produce
is naturally distributed among the different
Ranks of the People," Book I, chapters 1-3. (skip
the intro and chapters 4 and on).
3Adam SmithThe Wealth of Nations
- The policy of some nations has given
extraordinary encouragement to the industry of
the country that of others to the industry of
towns. Scarce any nation has dealt equally and
impartially with every sort of industry.
4The Division of Labor
- is commonly supposed to be carried furthest in
some very trifling industries - not perhaps that it really is carried further in
them than in others of more importance but in
those trifling manufactures which are destined to
supply the small wants of but a small number of
people, the whole number of workmen must
necessarily be small and those employed in every
different branch of the work can often be
collected into the same workhouse, and placed at
once under the view of the spectator. - In those great manufactures, on the contrary,
which are destined to supply the great wants of
the great body of the people, every different
branch of the work employs so great a number of
workmen, that it is impossible to collect them
all into the same workhouse. - We can seldom see more, at one time, than those
employed in one single branch. - Though in such manufactures, therefore, the
work may really be divided into a much greater
number of parts, than in those of a more trifling
nature, the division is not near so obvious, and
has accordingly been much less observed.
5Pin Making
- One man 1-20/day
- Ten men 48,000/day
- Leonard Read, "I, Pencil," The Freeman (December
1958). http//www.econlib.org/library/Essays/rdPnc
l1.html.
6Advantage
- The corn of Poland, in the same degree of
goodness, is as cheap as that of France,
notwithstanding the superior opulence and
improvement of the latter country. - The corn of France is, in the corn provinces,
fully as good, and in most years nearly about the
same price with the corn of England, - The corn-lands of England, however, are better
cultivated than those of France, and the
corn-lands of France are said to be much better
cultivated than those of Poland. - But though the poor country, notwithstanding the
inferiority of its cultivation, can, in some
measure, rival the rich in the cheapness and
goodness of its corn, it can pretend to no such
competition in its manufactures at least if
those manufactures suit the soil, climate, and
situation of the rich country. - Absolute vs. comparative advantage (Ricardo,
rent)
7- A man commonly saunters a little in turning his
hand from one sort of employment to another. When
he first begins the new work he is seldom very
keen and hearty his mind, as they say, does not
go to it, and for some time he rather trifles
than applies to good purpose.
8Innovation
- A great part of the machines made use of in
those manufactures in which labour is most
subdivided, were originally the inventions of
common workmen, who, being each of them employed
in some very simple operation, naturally turned
their thoughts towards finding out easier and
readier methods of performing it. - (the steam engine boy)
9Harberger Triangle article,
10Harbergers Method
1. Get return on capital in mfgr. industries,
and sales (q) 2. Calculate deviations from
average profit as a percentage of sales. Call
this r. 3. Assume the elasticity of demand, k,
for each industry equals 1. 3. Calculate .5
r2qk for each industry. 4. Add them up. 5.
Multiply 2.2 since we just looked at a fraction
of manuf. industries. 5. The result about .1
of national income.
11(No Transcript)
12HarbergersRefinements
1. What if there are increasing costs in
industries? 2. Equity capital is measured to
include the value of patents, which capitalizes
monopoly profits. So it is greater than the
amount of real capital supplied, and monopoly
profits might look too low. 3. Sample
selection bias. These industries have an average
profit of 10.4, while for manufaturign as a
whole it was 8. 4. Aggregation. This smooths
out differences in profit rates across products.
13Some Big Problems
1. Why include the low-profit industries? 2.
Why use return on capital instead of return on
equity? Bondholders do not get monopoly profit.
3. What if all industries are monopolized,
and profit rates are all equal? His method would
show zero loss. 4. What about labor
monopolies? (unions, restrictive entry of the
kind Stigler discusses)
14Another Approach
Suppose ALL of the return to equity is
monopoly profit. What is the welfare loss? US
Mfgr corporations had profit of 245 billion
dollars in 1998. Sales were 4,591 billion. So the
profit rate on sales was .053. And the triangle
loss was .5 (.053)(.053) (4591) 6.5 billion
dollars. GDP was 8790 billion dollars, so the
loss is .07 of GDP.
15Refinement Fewer monopoly industries
Suppose ALL of the return to equity is
monopoly profit. What is the welfare loss? US
Mfgr corporations had profit of 245 billion
dollars in 1998. Sales were 4,591 billion. So the
profit rate on sales was .053. Suppose a
quarter of firms are monopolies, with profits of
20, and 3/4 are not, with profits of 0 of
sales. Then the triangle loss is .5 (.20)(.20)
(.25) (4591) 23.0 billion dollars. What if
prices were double what they should be, in every
industry? Then the approximation involved gets
bad, but we can compute . 5(1) (1) 4591 2296,
and the loss is 26 of GDP.
16- Coase, Ronald.The Problem of Social Cost, 3
Journal of Law and Economics 1-44 (1960).
17Coase Theorem Example
A steel mills pollution reduces resort profit
by 200,000 unless 100,000 is paid to control
pollution. There is a real externality of
200,000. The Pigouvian tax would be to charge
the steel mill 200,000 if it pollutes. It would
then choose to control the pollution instead.
Coase insight Suppose the resort could
switch to timber, earning 50,000 less. Then the
Pigouvian tax is inefficient. Or, just let
the steel mill and the resort negotiate with each
other. If the property right who has the legal
right to decide pollution is clear, the outcome
will be efficient.
18The Coase Theorem
If transaction costs are zero, then any initial
allocation of property rights leads to an
efficient outcome. (Friedmans
statement) What is interesting is to figure out
the implications of transaction costs. A
function of law is to minimize transaction costs.
http//www.daviddfriedman.com/laws_order/
19Property and Liability Rules
If you are protected by a property rule, you can
go to court and get an injunction to stop
someone from doing X. (court of common law). Good
if transactions are cheap. Examples Patent
infringement, someone building a house on your
land, someone stealing your car. If you are
protected by a liability rule, you can go to
court and get damages from someone who has done
X. (court of equity) Good if courts are cheap.
Examples tort suits for personal injury,
damages for breach of contract
Calabresi, Guido Melamed, Douglas, "Property
Rules, Liability Rules and Inalienability One
View of the Cathedral", 85 Harvard Law Review
1089 (1972).
20The Train Sparks Example
A railroad chooses whether to install a spark
arrester at cost 1000 or not. 100 farmers each
choose whether to plant clover or wheat. Clover
does not burn, but yields 800 less in revenue.
Wheat burns, for a loss of 400. Possible Rules
(who decides? who pays?) 1. Railroad property
right. The railroad can throw sparks if it so
desires. 2. Farmer property right. Any one
farmer can stop the railroad from throwing
sparks. 3. Farmer liability right. The
railroad can throw sparks if it pays the farmers
for any damage that results. 4. Railroad
liability right. Any one farmer can stop the
railroad from throwing sparks, but he must pay
the railroads cost of installing a spark
arrester.
21 Train Sparks II
- A railroad chooses whether to install a spark
arrester at cost 1000 or not. 100 farmers each
choose whether to plant clover or wheat. Clover
does not burn, but yields 800 less in revenue.
Wheat burns, for a loss of 400. - Possible Rules (no contracts enforced)
- Railroad property right. Farmers plant wheat and
it burns. 400 cost. - 2. Farmer property right. RR installs spark
arrester. 1,000 cost. - 3. Farmer liability right. Farmers plant wheat
and it burns. 400 cost. The RR pays 400 to the
farmer. - 4. Railroad liability right. Farmers plant wheat
and it burns. 400 cost. (The farmers could
insist on the spark arrester, but theyd have to
pay the 1,000.) -
22(No Transcript)
23Stigleron regulation, Bell Journal,
24 Stigler What does Government Supply?
Answer The power to coerce. Violence. 1.
Direct subsidy (US airlines before 1968,
universities) 2. Entry restrictions (US airlines
before 1975, tariffs) 3. Suppression of
substitute goods (margarine, plastic pipes) 4.
Price-fixing (interest rate regulation,
advertising restrictions)
25(No Transcript)
26(No Transcript)
27(No Transcript)
28(No Transcript)
29A blank slide for writing on
30- A link to the course website
- http//www.rasmusen.org/g604/0.g604.htm