Title: Jeffrey Frankel (HKS, Harvard University )
1Estimation of De Facto Flexibility Parameter and
Basket Weightsin Evolving Exchange Rate
Regimes
- Jeffrey Frankel (HKS, Harvard University )
- Dan Xie (Peterson Inst. for Internatl. Econ.)
- Annual Meeting of the American Economics
Association, Atlanta. - Session on International Financial Markets, Ken
West presiding - January 4, 2010, 230 Atlanta Marriott Marquis,
Marquis Ballroom Salon C
2As is by now well-known, the exchange rate
regimes that countries follow in practice (de
facto) often depart from the regimes that they
announce officially (de jure).
- Many countries that say they float in fact
intervene heavily in the foreign exchange market.
1 - Many countries that say they fix in fact devalue
when trouble arises.2 - Many countries that say they target a basket of
major currencies in fact fiddle with the
weights.3 - 1 Fear of floating Calvo Reinhart (2001,
2002) Reinhart (2000). - 2 The mirage of fixed exchange rates
Obstfeld Rogoff (1995). Klein Marion (1997). - 3 Parameters kept secret Frankel, Schmukler
Servén (2000).
3Economists have offered de facto classifications,
placing countries into the true categories
- Important examples include Ghosh, Gulde Wolf
(2000), Reinhart Rogoff (2004), Shambaugh
(2004a), and more to be cited. - Tavlas, Dellas Stockman (2008) survey the
literature. - Unfortunately, these classification schemes
disagree with each other as much as they disagree
with the de jure classification! 1 - gt Something must be wrong.
1 Bénassy-Quéré, et al (Table 5, 2004)
Frankel (Table
1, 2004) and Shambaugh (2004b).
4Correlations Among Regime Classification Schemes
- GGW Ghosh, Gulde Wolf. LY-S Levy-Yeyati
Sturzenegger. R-R Reinhart RogoffSample 47
countries. From Frankel (2004).
5Several things are wrong.
- 1) Attempts to infer statistically a countrys
flexibility from the variability of its exchange
rate alone ignore that some countries experience
greater shocks than others. - That problem can be addressed by comparing
exchange rate variability to foreign exchange
reserve variability, - Calvo Reinhart (2002) Levy-Yeyati
Sturzenegger (2003, 05).
6First approach to estimate de facto regimes
estimate degree of flexibility,typically
presuming, e.g., anchor currency
- Calvo Reinhart (2002) Variability of
Exchange Rate (E) vs. Variability of
Reserves. - Levy-Yeyati Sturzenegger (2005) cluster
analysis based on Variability of E ? E, and
of ? Reserves
7This 1st approach can be phrased in terms of
Exchange Market Pressure
- Define EMP ? value of currency ? reserves.
- EMP represents shocks in demand for the currency.
- Flexibility can be estimated as the propensity
of the central bank to let shocks show up in the
price of the currency (floating) ,vs. the
quantity of the currency (fixed), or in between
(intermediate exchange rate regime).
8Several things are wrong, continued.
- 2) Those papers impose the choice of the major
currency around which the country in question
defines its value (often the ). - It would be better to estimate endogenously
whether the anchor currency is the , the , some
other currency, or some basket of currencies. - That problem has been addressed by a 2nd branch.
9Second approach in the de facto regime literature
estimates implicit basket weights
- Regress ?value of local currency against
? values of
major currencies. - First examples
- Frankel (1993) and Frankel Wei (1994, 95).
- More
- Bénassy-Quéré (1999), Ohno (1999), Frankel,
Schmukler, Servén Fajnzylber (2001),
Bénassy-Quéré, Coeuré, Mignon (2004). - Example of China, post 7/05
- Eichengreen (2006) , Shah, Zeileis, Patnaik
(2005), Yamazaki (2006), Ogawa (2006),
Frankel-Wei (2006, 2007), Frankel (2009) - Findings
- RMB still pegged in 2005-06, with 95 weight on
. - Moved away from (weight on ) in 2007-08
- Returned to approximate peg in mid 2008.
10 - Some currencies have basket anchors, often with
some flexibility that can be captured either by a
band or by leaning-against-the-wind intervention.
- Most basket peggers keep the weights secret.
They want to preserve a degree of freedom from
prying eyes, whether to pursue - a lower degree of de facto flexibility, as China,
- or a higher degree, as with most others.
11Implicit basket weights method --
- regress ?value of local currency against ?
values of major currencies -- continued. - Null Hypotheses Close fit gt a peg.
- Coefficient of 1 on gt peg.
- Or significant weights on other currencies
gt basket peg. - But if the test rejects tight basket peg, what
is the Alternative Hypothesis?
12Several things are wrong, continued.
- 3) The 2nd approach (inferring the anchor
currency or basket) does not allow for
flexibility around that anchor. - Inferring de facto weights and inferring de facto
flexibility are equally important, - whereas most authors have hitherto done only one
or the other.
13The synthesis technique
- A synthesis of the two approaches for
statistically estimating de facto exchange rate
regimes (1) the technique that we have used in
the past to estimate implicit de facto weights
when the hypothesis is a basket peg with little
flexibility. (2) the technique used by
others to estimate de facto exchange rate
flexibility when the hypothesis is an anchor to
the , but with variation around that anchor.
- A majority of currencies today follow
- variants of Band-Basket-Crawl or a managed float.
- gt We need a technique that can cover both
dimensions inferring weights and inferring
flexibility.
14Several things are wrong, continued.
- 4) All these approaches, even the synthesis
technique are plagued by the problem that many
countries frequently change regimes or (for those
with intermediate regimes) change parameters. - E.g., Chile changed parameters 18 times in 18
years (1980s-90s) - Year-by-year estimation wont work, because
parameter changes come at irregular intervals. - Chou test wont work, because one does not
usually know the candidate dates. - Solution Apply Bai-Perron econometric
technique for endogenous estimation of
structural break point dates.
15Statistical estimation of de facto exchange rate
regimes
Estimation of implicit weights in basket peg
Frankel (1993), Frankel Wei (1993, 94, 95)
Ohno (1999), F, Schmukler Servén (2000),
Bénassy-Quéré (1999, 2006)
Estimation of degree of flexibility in managed
float Calvo Reinhart (2002) Levi-Yeyati
Sturzenegger (2003) also Reinhart
Rogoff
Application to RMBEichengreen (06), Ogawa (06),
FrankelWei (07)
- Synthesis Estimation of De Facto Exchange
Rate Regimes Synthesis of the Techniques for
Inferring Flexibility and Basket Weights F
Wei (IMF SP 2008)
Application to RMB Frankel (2009)
Econometric estimation of structural break
points Bai Perron (1998, 2003)
Allow for parameter variation Estimation of De
Facto Flexibility Parameter and Basket Weights in
Evolving Exchange Rate Regimes F Xie (2010)
16The technique that estimates basket weights
- Assuming the value of the home currency is
determined by a currency basket, how does one
uncover the currency composition weights? This
is a problem to which OLS is unusually well
suited. - We regress changes in the log of H, the value
of the home currency, against changes in the log
values of the candidate currencies. -
- Algebraically, if the value of the home currency
H is pegged to the values of currencies X1, X2,
Xn, with weights equal to w1, w2, wn, then - ? logH(t) c ? w(j) ? logX(j)
(1)
17- ? log Ht
- c ? w(j) ? logX(j)t
- c ß(1) ? log t ß(2) ? log t
ß(3) ? log t a ? log t
- If the exchange rate is truly governed by a
strict basket peg, then we should recover the
true weights, w(j), precisely and the equation
should have a perfect fit.
18The question of the numeraire
- Methodology question how to define value of
each currency.1 - In a true basket peg, the choice of numeraire
currency is immaterial we estimate the weights
accurately regardless. 2 - In practice, few countries take their basket pegs
literally enough to produce such a tight fit.
One must then think about non-basket factors in
the regression (EMP, the trend term, error
term)Are they better measured in terms of one
numeraire or another? - We choose as numeraire the SDR.
- FWei checked how much difference numeraire
choice makes. - by trying the Swiss franc as a robustness check
- and in Monte Carlo studies
- 1 Frankel(1993) used purchasing power
over a consumer basket of domestic goods as
numeraire Frankel-Wei (1995) used the SDR
Frankel-Wei (1994, 06), Ohno (1999), and
Eichengreen (2006) used the Swiss franc
Bénassy-Quéré (1999), the Frankel, Schmukler
and Luis Servén (2000), a GDP-weighted basket of
5 major currencies and Yamazaki (2006), the
Canadian . 2 assuming weights add to1, and no
error term, constant term, or other non-currency
variable.
19Distillation of technique to infer flexibility
- When a shock increases international demand for
korona, do the authorities allow it to show up as
an appreciation, or as a rise in reserves? - We frame the issue in terms of Exchange Market
Pressure (EMP), defined as increase in the
value of the currency plus increase in reserves
(as share of monetary base). - EMP variable appears on the RHS of the equation.
The rise in the value of the currency appears
on the left. - A coefficient of 0 on EMP signifies a fixed E
(no changes in the value of the currency), - a coefficient of 1 signifies a freely floating
rate (no changes in reserves) and - a coefficient somewhere in between indicates a
correspondingly flexible/stable intermediate
regime.
20Synthesis equation
- ? logH(t) c ? w(j) ?logX(j, t)
- ß ? EMP(t) u(t) (2)
- where ? EMP(t) ?logH (t) ?Res (t) / MB
(t). - We impose ? w(j) 1, implemented by treating
as the last currency.
21Synthesis equation
- ? log H t c ?w(j) ? logXt d
?EMPt ut
(3) - c w(1) ? log t w (2) ? log t w
(3) ? log t w (4) ? log t
- d ? EMP
t u t .
22Now we introduce Bai-Perron technique for
endogenous estimation of m possible structural
break points
(6)
23Illustration using 5 currencies
- These are 5 emerging market currencies of
interest all of which now make available their
data on reserves on a weekly basis (which is
necessary to get good estimates, if structural
changes happen as often as yearly) - Mexico (monetary base is also available weekly)
- Chile, Russia, Thailand, India (although
reserves available weekly, denominator must be
interpolated from monthly monetary base data)
24Overview of findings
- For all five, the estimates suggest managed
floats during most of the period 1999-2009. - This was a new development for emerging markets.
- Most of the countries had some variety of a peg
before the currency crises of the 1990s. - But the Bai-Perron test shows statistically
significant structural breaks for every currency,
- even when the threshold is set high, at the 1
level of statistical significance.
25Table 1A reports estimation for the Mexican peso
- 5 structural breaks
- The peso is known as a floater.
- To the extent Mexico intervenes to reduce
exchange rate variation, is the primary anchor,
but there also appears to have been some weight
on starting in 2003. - Aug.2006 - Dec.2008, coefficient on EMP is
essentially 0, surprisingly, suggesting heavier
intervention around a target. - But in the period starting Dec.2008, the peso
once again moved away from the currency to the
north, as the worst phase of the global liquidity
crisis hit and appreciated.
26Table 1A. Identifying Break Points in Mexican
Exchange Rate Regime M11999-M72009
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
VARIABLES 1/21/1999-9/2/2001 9/9/2001-3/18/2003 3/25/2003-7/29/2006 8/5/2006-1/28/2008 2/4/2008- 12/15/2008 12/22/2008-7/29/2009
US dollar 0.92 0.88 0.62 1.11 0.96 0.20
(0.09) (0.12) (0.07) (0.10) (0.19) (0.22)
euro 0.14 -0.09 0.30 0.20 0.51 0.51
(0.08) (0.14) (0.09) (0.11) (0.16) (0.18)
Jpn yen -0.05 0.22 0.08 -0.34 -0.33 0.18
(0.06) (0.07) (0.06) (0.06) (0.12) (0.13)
?EMP 0.14 0.32 0.17 0.02 0.07 0.28
(0.03) (0.03) (0.03) (0.02) (0.07) (0.04)
Constant 0.00 -0.00 -0.00 -0.00 -0.00 0.00
(0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) (0.00)
Observations 131 78 168 76 46 29
R-squared 0.62 0.86 0.69 0.67 0.54 0.78
Br. Pound -0.01 -0.01 -0.01 0.02 -0.14 0.11
27Tables 1B-1E
- Chile (with 3 estimated structural breaks)
appears a managed floater throughout. - The anchor is exclusively the in some periods,
but puts significant weight on the in other
periods. - Russia (3 structural breaks) is similar, except
that the weight is always significantly less
than 1. - For Thailand (3 structural breaks), the share
in the anchor basket is slightly gt .6, but
usually significantly lt 1. - The and show weights of about .2 each
Jan.1999-Sept. 2006. - India (5 structural breaks) apparently fixed its
exchange rate during two of the sub-periods, but
pursued a managed float in the other four
sub-periods. - was always the most important of the anchor
currencies, but the was also significant in
four out of six sub-periods, and the in two.
28Future research
- Results for other currencies will be published in
other papers - Often requiring weekly interpolation between
monthly reserve figures. - Including our China updates
- And true basket/band/crawl currencies
- Econometric extension use Threshold
Autoregression for target zones.
29Conclusion It is harder to classify regimes than
one would think
- It is genuinely difficult to classify most
countries de facto regimes intermediate regimes
that change over time. - Need techniques
- that allow for intermediate regimes (managed
floating and basket anchors) - and that allow the parameters to change over
time. - Jarko Fidrmuc allows parameters to evolve
gradually over time, by means of a Kalman filter
(session Jan. 5).
30Bottom line(s)
- The new synthesis technique is necessary to
discern exchange rate regimes where both the
anchor weights and the flexibility parameter are
unknown. - Weekly data are necessary to capture the
frequency with which many countries exchange
rate regimes evolve.
31(No Transcript)
32Appendix 0 preliminary look at the data
- First set of countries examined
- 9 small countries that have been officially
identified by the IMF as following basket pegs
Latvia, Papua New Guinea, Botswana, Vanuatu,
Fiji, W.Samoa, Malta the Seychelles. - 4 known floaters Australia, Canada and Japan.
- 3 peggers of special interest China, Hong Kong
Malaysia.
33Variances of ? E ? Reserves are computed
- within the period 1980-2007,
- for 7-year intervals
- The aim in choosing this interval long enough
to generate reliable parameter estimates, and yet
not so long as inevitably to include major
changes in each countrys exchange rate regime. - All changes are logarithmic, throughout this
research. - We try subtracting imputed interest earnings from
reported ? Reserves to get intervention.
34(No Transcript)
35Lessons from Figure 1
- The folly of judging a countrys exchange rate
regime the extent to which it seeks to
stabilize the value of its currency by looking
simply at variation in the exchange rate. E.g.
Var(?E) for 1980-86 A gt 2001-07 . But not
because the A more flexible. It is rather
because Australia was hit by much larger shocks.
One must focus on Var(?E) relative to
Var(?Res). - Countries that specialize in mineral products
tend to have larger shocks.
36Lessons from Figure 1, continued
- Even countries that float use FX reserves
actively. E.g., Canada in the 1980s. - A currency with a firm peg (e.g., Hong Kong) can
experience low variability of reserves, because
it has low variability of shocks.
37Appendix 1Testing out the synthesis
technique,first on some known peggers
- RMB (Table 2.5)
- a perfect peg to the dollar during 2001-04 (
coefficient .99, flexibility coefficient
insignificantly different from 0, R2.99). - In 2005-07 the EMP coefficient suggested that
only 90 of increased demand for the currency
shows up in reserves, rather than 100 but
the weight R2 were as high as ever. - Hong Kong (Table 2.8)
- close to full weight on US, 0 flexibility,
perfect fit.
38A commodity-producing pegger
- Kuwaiti dinar shows a firm peg throughout most
of the period a near-zero flexibility
parameter, R2 gt .9 (IV estimates in Table 3.5
IV price of oil). - A small weight was assigned to other currencies
in the 1980s basket, - but in the 2nd half of the sample, the anchor
was usually a simple peg.
39A first official basket peggerwhich is on a path
to the
- The Latvian lat (Table 2.10)
- Flexibility is low during the 1990s, and has
disappeared altogether since 2000. R2 gt .9
during 1996-2003. - The combination of low flexibility coefficient
and a high R2 during 2000-03 suggests a
particularly tight basket peg during these years.
- Initially the estimated weights include -weight
.4 -weight .3 though both decline over
time. DM-weight .3 until 1999, - then transferred to .2 in 2000-03 and .5 in
2004-07.
40A 2nd official basket peggeralso on a path to
the
- The Maltese lira (Table 2.12)
- a tight peg during 1984-1991 and 2004-07 (low
flexibility coefficient high R2). - During 1980-2003, weight on the is .2 -.4.
- During 1980-1995, the European currencies garner
.3-.4, the .2-.3 the .1. - At the end of the sample period, the weight on
the rises almost to .9.
41 3rd official basket pegger
- Norwegian kroner (Table 2.14)
- The estimates show heavy intervention.
- Weights are initially .3 on the and .4 on
European currencies ( perhaps a little weight on
). - But the weight on the European currencies rises
at the expense of the , until the latter part of
the sample period shows full weight on the and
none on the .
424th official basket pegger
- Seychelles rupee (Table 2.17)
- confirms its official classification,
particularly in 1984-1995 not only is the
flexibility coefficient essentially 0, but R2 gt
.97. - Estimated weights .4 on the ,
.3 on the European currencies, .2 on
the and .1 on the . - After 2004, the weight suddenly shoots up to
.9 .
432 Pacific basket peggers
- Vanuatu (Table 2.19)
- low exchange rate flexibility and a fairly close
fit. - roughly comparable weights on the , , , and
. -
- Western Samoa (Table 2.20)
- heavy intervention during the first 3
sub-periods, - around a basket that weights the most , and the
2nd. - More flexibility after 1992.
- Weights in the reference basket during 2000-2003
are similar, except the now receives a large
significant weight (.4).
44A BBC country,rare in that it announced
explicitly the parameters basket weights, band
width and rate of crawl.
- Chile in the 1980s 1990s (Table 2.4)
- R2 gt .9.
- The weight is always high, but others enter
too. - Significant downward crawl 1980-99.
- Estimates qualitatively capture Chiles
- shift from anchor alone in the 1980s, to a
basket starting in 1992. - move to full floating in 1999.
45Chile, continued
- But the estimates do not correspond perfectly to
the policy shifts of 1992 99 - Possible explanations for gap between official
regime and estimates include - De facto ? de jure
- Parameter changes more frequent than the 4-year
sub-periods. - The Chilean authorities announced 18 changes in
regime parameters (weights, width, and rate of
crawl) during the 18-year period 1982 -1999. - The difficulty is that we have only monthly data
on reserves, for most countries gt it is not
possible to estimate meaningful parameter values
if they change every year or so.
46Floaters
- Australian (Table 2.1)
- The coefficient on EMP shows less flexibility
than one would have expected, given that the
currency is thought to have floated throughout
this period. - Perhaps the problem is endogeneity of EMP.
- World commodity prices are a natural IV. (Table
3.1) - For each sub-period, the estimated flexibility
coefficient is indeed higher than it was under
OLS, but still far below 1.
47Appendix 2 Current applicationsusing
higher-frequency data
- (I) RMB
- New Estimation of Chinas Exchange Rate Regime,
Pacific Ec.Rev., 2009. - Updated through early 2009, on my weblog
- http//content.ksg.harvard.edu/bl
og/jeff_frankels_weblog/2009/03/11/the-rmb-has-now
-moved-back-to-the-dollar/ . - (II) Estimation to allow for frequent parameter
shifts - Results for 13 countries offering weekly reserve
data, - Therefore allowing estimation intervals shorter
than 1 year. - Econometric techniques to estimate parameter
shifts endogenously.
48(2.I) Estimation of RMB with updated technique
and data (through early 2008)
- This approach reveals that the RMB basket had
loosened link to the by late 2006, and switched
substantial weight onto the by mid 2007. - An implication is that the appreciation of the
RMB against the dollar observed during this
period was due to the appreciation of the
against the , not to any upward trend in the RMB
relative to its basket.
49Table 1 Evolution of RMB Basket Weights from
10-22-2006, 3-month windows of daily data,
ending on the month shown
COEFFICIENT 12/2006 3/2007 2/2008 9/2008 11/2008
usd 1.005 0.814 0.878 0.992 0.971
(0.038) (0.035) (0.041) (0.027) (0.039)
eur 0.006 0.068 0.019 0.049 0.070
(0.038) (0.027) (0.026) (0.020) (0.028)
jpy -0.023 0.020 0.044 -0.030 -0.022
(0.035) (0.011) (0.017) (0.019) (0.027)
Constant 0.000 0.000 0.001 0.000 0.000
(0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000) (0.000)
Observations 61 64 61 60 18
R-squared 0.95 0.94 0.96 1.00 1.00
krw 0.011 0.098 0.059 -0.011 -0.019
Robust standard errors in parentheses
plt0.01, plt0.05, plt0.1
50Table 2 Rolling 12-month regressions of value of
RMB ? (EMP) defined as res(t)-res(t-1)/mb(t-1)
exr(t)-exr(t-1)/exr(t-1) 12-month windows,
ending on the month shown
COEFFICIENT 06M11 07M2 07M3 08M3 08M5
usd 0.909 0.756 0.756 0.613 0.597
(0.147) (0.105) (0.067) (0.171) (0.130)
jpy -0.015 -0.095 -0.140 0.059 0.030
(0.098) (0.085) (0.089) (0.081) (0.083)
eur 0.029 0.116 0.169 0.357 0.397
(0.117) (0.096) (0.068) (0.143) (0.105)
? emp 0.137 0.179 0.187 0.290 0.249
(0.100) (0.047) (0.029) (0.076) (0.097)
Constant -0.001 -0.003 -0.004 -0.006 -0.004
(0.003) (0.002) (0.001) (0.003) (0.003)
Observations 12 12 12 12 12
R-squared 0.984 0.967 0.975 0.967 0.966
krw 0.077 0.215 -0.030 -0.024
51In 2008, however, RMB policy changed again.
- The appreciation of the previous year had put
unwelcome pressure on exporters. - Chinese leaders changed policy
- Naughton (2008).
- Observing that putting half-weight on the
during a downward trend had led to
appreciation, - in mid-2008, they decided to switch back
virtually to a peg. - During the most recent period, September
2008-February 2009, estimates show that all the
weight has once again fallen on the .
52The weights in the RMB basket
toward in 2007,
shifted
back to in 2008.
53RMB was roughly flat against basket of ½-
½- in 2007 in 2008 (like 2005) .
Appreciation vs. was due to weight on during
period of weakening
54Ironically
- The has appreciated vs. the since 2008.
- So the -pegged RMB is stronger than if the
basket had been retained ! - Yet US Congressmen are still agitating for a more
flexible exchange rate -- - not realizing that, recently, a more flexible
exchange rate would have meant a weaker RMB ! - especially since the PBoC lost reserves in
January February 2009.
55(2.II) Results for 13 countries that offer weekly
reserve data (1991-2008)
- Argentina, Brazil, Canada, Chile, Colombia,
India, Indonesia, Mexico, Peru, Russia, Thailand,
Turkey Venezuela. - E.g.,
- Colombia during 2008, weight fell
flexibility increased. - Turkey during 2008 2008 moved from high euro
weight with low flexibility to low euro weight
with high flexibility.
56 Colombia Evolution of Basket Weights,Monthly
Regressions with Daily data, 2008
(2) (4) (5) (8) (9) (10)
VARIABLES 2/2008 4/2008 5/2008 8/2008 9/2008 10/2008
JPY -0.028 0.023 0.227 0.028 -0.139 0.319
(0.093) (0.063) (0.198) (0.134) (0.164) (0.121)
USD 0.480 0.334 0.019 -0.073 0.218 -0.294
(0.165) (0.060) (0.340) (0.173) (0.233) (0.230)
EUR 0.602 0.522 0.226 0.774 0.738 0.886
(0.274) (0.091) (0.277) (0.180) (0.343) (0.347)
?(emp) 0.160 0.447 0.688 0.931 0.858 0.650
(0.110) (0.049) (0.091) (0.062) (0.076) (0.203)
Observations 21 22 14 15 20 21
GBP -0.054 0.121 0.528 0.270 0.183 0.089
Robust standard errors in parentheses
plt0.01, plt0.05, plt0.1
57 Turkey Evolution of Basket Weights, Quarterly
Regressions with Weekly data
Turkey Evolution of Basket Weights, Quarterly
Regressions with Weekly data
(1) (3) (5) (7)
VARIABLES 1/2007 1/2007 7/2007 1/2008 7/2008
JPY JPY -0.660 -0.250 -0.758 0.899
(0.329) (0.166) (0.255) (0.803)
USD USD 0.397 -0.036 0.912 -0.961
(0.930) (0.302) (0.500) (0.920)
EUR EUR 0.906 1.931 0.566 -0.088
(0.863) (0.260) (0.371) (0.738)
?(emp) ?(emp) 0.149 0.231 0.798 0.825
(0.083) (0.056) (0.204) (0.279)
Observations Observations 10 14 13 10
GBP GBP 0.357 -0.644 0.281 1.151
Robust standard errors in parentheses
plt0.01, plt0.05, plt0.1
58(No Transcript)
59Appendix 3 For countries without weekly reserve
data, we can interpolate between months to take
advantage of high-frequency exchange rate data
- giving enough observations per year to allow the
use of more sophisticated econometric techniques
that estimate endogenously the dates at which
parameters shift. - Application to China
- (next slide)
- reinforces conclusion RMB shifted back to peg
9/15/08 (through March 09)
60Identifying Break Points in Chinas Exchange Rate
Regime With weekly exchange rate data and
monthly reserve data(interpolations are made to
get weekly reserve data)
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6)
VARIABLES 1/6/2005- 7/15/2005 7/29/2005- 4/27/2007 5/4/2007- 11/16/2007 11/23/2007- 9/8/2008 9/15/2008-12/8/2008 12/15/2008-3/11/2009
US dollar 1.000 0.893 0.596 0.685 0.965 0.929
(0.000) (0.030) (0.101) (0.066) (0.091) (0.058)
euro 0.000 0.046 0.087 0.241 0.128 0.037
(0.000) (0.025) (0.077) (0.050) (0.082) (0.049)
Jpn yen -0.000 0.014 0.063 0.059 -0.065 0.010
(0.000) (0.013) (0.038) (0.022) (0.025) (0.021)
?emp 0.000 0.034 0.129 0.185 0.165 0.042
(0.000) (0.024) (0.060) (0.052) (0.125) (0.063)
Constant -0.000 0.000 0.000 0.000 -0.000 0.000
(0.000) (0.000) (0.001) (0.000) (0.001) (0.000)
Observations 28 92 29 42 13 13
Korean won -0.000 0.047 0.254 0.015 -0.027 0.023
R-squared 1.000 0.979 0.929 0.990 0.999 0.999
Note plt0.01, plt0.05, plt0.1 Robust
standard errors in parentheses
61Appendix 4 Monte Carlo studyon fabricated
currency regimes
- Two kinds of flexibility
- Leaning ½ -way against the wind of EMP
fluctuations (Table 8.1) - Or else constrained to remain in a 5 band
(Table 8.2) - Two anchors
- peg
- Basket 1/3 , 1/3 , 1/3
- The synthesis technique generally gives the right
answer.
62Monte Carlo exchange rate under simulated
basketband regime(with parameters from Papual
New Guinea)
63Appendix 5 -- One concern endogeneity of the
exchange market pressure variable
- One would prefer to observe changes in the
international demand for the home currency known
to originate in exogenous shocks. - In the case of countries that specialize in the
production of mineral or agricultural
commodities, there is a ready-made IV changes
in the price of the commodity on world markets. - Accordingly, Tables 3 repeat the synthesis
estimation technique, but for the commodity
producers it uses changes in the world price of
the commodity in question as an IV for changes in
EMP.
64To address endogeneity of EMP, we use commodity
prices as IV
- Malaysian ringgit (Table 2.11 ) OLS.
- Only in 1996-99 is there evidence of exchange
rate flexibility (Asia crisis ). - During 2000-03 there is a perfect peg to the
(coefficient R2 both 1). - In 2004-07 the peg is still fairly strong, but
here the weight of the US falls to .6, partially
replaced by the Singapore (weight .4) . - IV prices of tin semiconductors (Table 3.6)
- Again, a perfect peg during 2000-03,
- followed by shift to a basket consisting of an
average of the US the Singapore .
65Recurrent finding IV estimate on EMP is higher
than OLS estimate (but lower in significance)
- Floaters IV estimates for Canadian , as with
A, show flexibility parameters in each
sub-period higher than they were under OLS, but
surprisingly insignificant statistically. - IV also raises flexibility coefficient for
Intermediate regimes - Thailand (Table 3.11) IV price of rice
- W.Samoa (Table 3.12) IV price of coconuts.