Title: What Drives Merger Waves?
1What Drives Merger Waves?
2Motivation
- The question of what drives waves of merger
activity is an old one. - Recently, authors such as Shleifer and Vishny and
Rhodes-Kropf and Vishwanathan have developed
behavioral models explaining the observed
relation between stock market valuations and
merger activity. - This has refocused the debate as one between
neoclassical and behavioral explanations for
waves
3Research Question
- Is a clustering of mergers at the aggregate level
due to a combination of industry shocks for which
mergers facilitate change to the new environment,
or is it due to market timing?
4Hypotheses
- Neoclassical hypothesis
- Based on the work of Coase (1937), Gort (1969),
Maksimovic and Phillips (2001), Jovanovic and
Rousseau (2001,2002) - Economic disturbance leads to industry
reorganization - Modify to include a role for capital liquidity
- Eisfeldt and Rampini (2003)
- Shleifer and Vishny (1992)
- Once a technological, regulatory or economic
shock occurs, the collective reaction of firms
inside and outside the industry reallocates
industry assets through merger and partial-firm
acquisitions.
5Hypotheses
- Behavioral Hypothesis
- Shleifer and Vishny (2003)
- Bull markets lead groups of bidders with
overvalued stock to use it to buy real assets of
undervalued targets. - Model relies on dispersion in valuations and time
horizons. - Rhodes-Kropf and Viswanathan (2003)
- Rational targets accept bids from overvalued
bidders because they overestimate synergies
during market peaks. - Both models rely on bidder managers timing market
valuations.
6Predictions
- Neoclassical Hypothesis
- Observable shocks will precede waves
- MOP will be either stock or cash
- Both mergers and partial-firm cash transactions
- Credit constraints will be low and/or asset
values will be high
7Predictions
- Behavioral Hypothesis
- Merger waves occur following periods of
abnormally high stock returns or M/B ratios,
especially when dispersion in those metrics is
high - Post-wave returns should be poor
- Post-merger operating performance should be
particularly poor in waves - MOP should be overwhelmingly stock
- Partial-firm transactions for cash should not be
common
8Sample
- I end-up with
- 35 waves from 28 industries (7 of which have 2
waves, one in the 1980s and one in the 1990s) - Average 24-month non-wave period has 7.8 bids
- Average 24-month wave period has 34.3 bids
- How I got there
9Sample
- Start with all merger transactions (gt50mil) on
SDC from 1981 to 2000 - Measure highest 24-month concentration in 1980s
and 1990s for each industry (Fama-French 48
industries) - For each industry, compare that concentration to
the empirical distribution of concentrations from
1000 simulations specific to that industry - If the actual concentration was greater than the
95th percentile concentration in the
distribution, categorize that period as a wave
10Industry Characteristics and Waves
- Operating Environment
- Shocks to Profitability (cash flow/sales), Asset
turnover (Sales/TA), Sales growth, ROA, Employee
Growth, - RD, Capital Expenditures
- Market valuations
- 1- and 3-year returns and s of those returns
- Market-to-book ratios
- Measure all variables in year prior to start of
an industry merger wave
11Univariate Results
- Summary of Table 2
- Shocks to profitability, asset turnover, sales
growth, ROA, employee growth, RD, Capital
Expenditures are all abnormally high - M/B, change in M/B and s(M/B) are all abnormally
high - 3-year return is abnormally high, but 1-year
return, s(3-year return), s(1-year return) are
all not
12Univariate Results
- Deregulation and Capital Liquidity
- Index of deregulatory events
- 4-quarter moving average of the Commercial
Industrial rate spread - Federal reserves SLO survey
- Highly correlated with the question of tightening
or easing credit
13Figure 1 Capital Liquidity, Industry Merger
Waves and Aggregate Merger Activity
14Predicting an Industry Merger Wave
- Logit models
- All 48 industries for the 20-year sample period
- Problem operating shocks are too highly
correlated - Solution 1st principal component from 7 shock
variables - Include on its own and with an interaction for
capital liquidity - Low capital liquidity high CI rate spread or
low M/B
15Table 4 Predicting Merger Waves
16Summary of Logit Models
- On their own, behavioral variables have some
predictive power for merger waves. - However,
- Commonly cited association between stock price
performance and merger waves disappears after
controlling for capital liquidity - Once nested within a neoclassical model of merger
waves, the behavioral variables add little
explanatory power
17Partial-firm (divisional) Acquisitions
- Neoclassical hypothesis predicts that
transactions will occur both at the firm and
divisional level and that the MOP will be both
cash and stock - Mulherin and Boone (2000), Maksimovic and
Phillips (2001), Schlingemann, Stulz and Walkling
(2002), - Behavioral hypothesis cannot explain divisional
transactions for cash, especially when executed
by stock-swap bidders
18(No Transcript)
19Â
Table 5 The Relation between Merger Activity and
Partial-Firm Acquisitions
20Table 5, Panel B
21Summarizing Partial-firm acq. results
- Total firm-level and partial-firm level activity
are highly correlated - Stock-swap only merger activity is correlated
with cash partial-firm level activity - Being a bidder strongly predicts being a buyer in
a partial-firm transaction - Even being a stock bidder strongly predicts being
a cash buyer in a partial-firm transaction
22Long-run returns
- Behavioral hypothesis predicts poor long-run
returns following merger waves. - Extant evidence is mixed (e.g. Loughran and Vijh,
1997 Mitchell and Stafford, 2000) - Use Fama (1998)s calendar time approach
- Create monthly portfolios of treatment firms
- Regress vector of monthly returns on FF 3-factor
realizations
23Table 6 Long-run Returns
24Table 6, Panel B
25Summary of Long-run Return Results
- There is little evidence of abnormally low
returns following merger waves - There is some evidence of poor post-merger
returns for stock bidders in merger waves. This
evidence is not robust to equal-weighted returns.
26Operating Performance
- Inherently noisy tests during merger waves
- Idea is to compare with-merger performance to
performance that would have occurred without the
merger - Pre-merger performance and industry performance
are probably both noisy proxies for performance
without the merger - Consequently, neoclassical hypothesis makes no
prediction about the observed post-merger
performance in a wave - Under the null of the behavioral hypothesis,
post-merger performance in waves should be
particularly poor
27Table 7 Operating Performance Changes following
Mergers
28Summary of Operating Performance Tests
- No evidence that post-merger operating
performance is worse for mergers during waves - Only evidence of a difference for wave vs.
non-wave mergers is better post-merger asset
turnover and M/B
29Summary of Predictions and Findings
30Conclusions
- Comparing the behavioral and neoclassical (with
capital liquidity) hypotheses, the results
consistently support the neoclassical hypothesis - The role of capital liquidity causes industry
merger waves to cluster in time even if industry
shocks do not - The relation between asset values and merger
activity reflects capital liquidity rather than
misvaluation
31Conclusions
- While there is undoubtedly some merger activity
driven by managers timing the market, such
mergers do not cause merger waves. - Aggregate merger waves are caused by the
clustering of shock-driven industry merger waves,
not by attempts to time the market.