General Equilibrium Models of Trade and Open Economies - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

1 / 31
About This Presentation
Title:

General Equilibrium Models of Trade and Open Economies

Description:

cars. CES aggregate Utility from cars. Utility from clothes. Utility from ... of the income elasticities of luxury goods versus necessities) are popular here. ... – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:341
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 32
Provided by: ect5
Category:

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: General Equilibrium Models of Trade and Open Economies


1
General Equilibrium Models of Trade and Open
Economies
  • T.Huw Edwards
  • Department of Economics
  • Loughborough University.
  • February, 2006.

2
The way trade is modelled matters!
  • This is true for all kinds of models of the
    economy, not just for specific models of trade.
  • In some formulations of trade, most final goods
    prices (in the absence of tariff or non-tariff
    barriers) in an open economy are set on World
    markets. This affects all kinds of economic
    policy one economist argues that effectively
    your wages are being set in Beijing.

3
The Heckscher-Ohlin Formulation
  • See Krugman and Obstfeld, International Economics
    (Addison Wesley).
  • The Heckscher-Ohlin (H-O) formulation is the
    standard neoclassical model of international
    trade, and closely linked to the associated
    Stolper-Samuelson Theorem.

4
Assumptions
  • WEAK CASE ASSUMPTIONS
  • Goods are produced with constant returns to scale
    and diminishing returns to substitution.
  • Goods are homogenous, regardless of their
    supplier.
  • Factors are completely mobile between sectors,
    but immobile between countries. Countries differ
    in factor endowments.
  • There is perfect competition.
  • STRONG CASE ASSUMPTIONS
  • Technology is the same across all countries
  • There are no transport costs
  • There is the same number of factors as produced
    goods
  • All countries produce all goods (no
    specialisation).

5
Modelling a H-O economy 1. The single country
model
  • We are assuming the country is a small, open
    economy.
  • Because the country is a price-taker on World
    markets, the domestic price of every good is
    PgPWgtg, where PWg is the World traded price
    (inclusive of transport to the countrys borders)
    and tg is the tariff.
  • This assumption has a great simplifying effect
    for GE modellers. It means that the production
    and consumption sides of the economy are
    effectively SEPARABLE they can usually be
    modelled apart.

6
Two cases
  • The country has n factors of production.
  • The country will never produce more goods than it
    has factors of production. There are therefore
    two situations
  • 1. The Heckscher-Ohlin-Samuelson situation. The
    country produces the same number of goods (n) as
    it has factors.
  • 2. The specialisation situation. The country
    produces less than n goods.
  • Most of the neoclassical trade literature focuses
    on case 1.

7
The HOS model with no specialisation
  • Because we are assuming perfect competition, we
    can write down a Zero Profit Condition for each
    industry, relating the price of each of n goods
    to the wages of each of the n factors (ww1wn).
  • PgPWgtga1gw1a2gw2angwn. Note that a1g is
    the input-output coefficient for use of factor 1
    in producing good g.

8
  • There are also n equations (one for each factor)
    relating use of the factor in each industry to
    the total endowment, Ef. The latter is taken as
    being exogenous.
  • Efaf1Y1af2Y2afnYn.
  • In this case, Yg is the output of industry g.
  • Finally, there are also n2 equations for each of
    the n x n input-output coefficients.
  • The number of unknowns equals the number of
    equations, so the model should solve exactly.

9
  • Key properties of the H-O-S model are that factor
    prices are determined solely by final market
    prices (which depend on World traded prices and
    tariffs) and technology. Changes in factor
    endowments result in a change in the relative
    production of different goods, but NOT in changes
    in relative factor prices, UNLESS there is
    specialisation.
  • Input-output ratios are constant unless there is
    specialisation.

10
2. The multi-country model
  • The above model can be extended to a
    multi-country framework, so long as the number of
    goods equals the number of factors, and each
    country produces each good.

11
Specialisation
12
(No Transcript)
13
A specialised economy
  • The relative change in prices at which a 2 x 2
    economy will become specialised depends upon the
    initial levels of production of the two
    industries, the relative factor intensities of
    the two industries and the elasticity of
    substitution between the two factors.
  • An economy can become specialised for small
    changes in goods prices (due to World price
    change or changes in protection) if it is already
    nearly specialised, or if the elasticity of
    substitution between the factors is high.
  • By contrast, if technology is of the Leontief
    fixed-coefficients variety (Rybczynski) then the
    economy will never become completely specialised.

14
  • If the economy is specialised, so it produces
    fewer goods than the number of factors, then it
    is still possible to determine the relative
    factor wages.
  • These will now vary according to factor
    endowments.
  • However, the general equilibrium model structure
    is different. Effectively, factor wages vary to
    change the input-output coefficients within the
    one industry to equate factor use with factor
    endowments.
  • It is not easy to incorporate both the HOS and
    the specialised economy model within a single
    code.

15
A fixed factor the Ricardo-Viner model
  • One way to make the H-O model more conservative
    (and realistic) is to introduce a fixed factor.
  • This may be a totally sector-specific factor
    (land).
  • Alternatively, a factor may not be mobile between
    sectors. Or a proportion of a factor is assumed
    to be immobile (for example, many models assume
    x of the capital stock in each industry is fixed
    in the short-run, and y gt x is fixed in the
    long-run).

16
  • Introducing a fixed factor reduces the rate at
    which the economy tends towards complete
    specialisation.
  • It also reduces the effect of traded prices on
    all factor wages (an effect derived in two papers
    by Mussa and Mayer, both JPE, 1974).
  • Factor wages are sensitive to endowments.
  • See Edwards and Whalley, NBER paper 9265, Oct
    2002.

17
The Armington Formulation
  • The Armington model is the most popular general
    equilibrium formulation.
  • It is seen as less extreme in its predictions
    than the HOS model.
  • It is also more easily reconciled with the
    observable behaviour of economies.
  • It does not suffer from the problem of complete
    specialisation (or at least, rarely).
  • The downside of the Armington formulation is that
    it is seen as relatively ad hoc by theorists.
  • Armington models require the production and
    consumption sides of the economy to be modelled
    simultaneously.

18
Armington key assumptions
  • Goods are produced subject to diminishing returns
    to substitution and constant returns to scale.
  • There are also diminishing returns to
    substitution in consumption.
  • WITHIN each country there is perfect competition.
  • HOWEVER, goods within an industry produced by
    different countries are assumed to be
    QUALITATIVELY different, and are imperfect
    substitutes.

19
A typical Armington Structure
  • Factors of prodn

Nation 3s Type of cars
Nation 2s type of cars
CES aggregation
Nation 1s type Of cars
CES aggregate Utility from cars
CES Aggregate Overall Utility In Nation 1
Utility from clothes
Utility from food
20
  • Note how this structure involves 3 levels of
    nested CES functions
  • Factors are aggregated to produce goods
  • Goods from different source nations are
    aggregated together
  • Finally different classes of goods are aggregated
    together to produce overall utility.

21
Typical elasticities of substitution
  • Aggregation of factors
  • Often between 0.5 and 1 (factors are
    complements). If 1, a Cobb-Douglas production
    structure is used (which is simpler).
  • Materials inputs often use fixed (Leontief)
    coefficients.
  • Aggregation of national varieties
  • Elasticities are usually higher. Say 1.25 in the
    short run or 2-4 in the longer term. Sometimes
    depends on the commodity.
  • Top level choice between goods
  • Elasticities are often close to unity. A
    Cobb-Douglas function, or even a Stone-Geary
    linear expenditure system (which takes more
    account of the income elasticities of luxury
    goods versus necessities) are popular here.
  • IT IS USUAL TO CARRY OUT SENSITIVITIES WITH
    DIFFERENT SUBSTITUTION ELASTICITIES.

22
  • Where the elasticities of substitution between
    nations are high, the properties of the model are
    similar to a Heckscher-Ohlin model. Often, in
    these cases, we will introduce sectorally-fixed
    factors (a la Ricardo-Viner) for reasons of
    greater realism.
  • When elasticities of substitution are lower,
    properties are quite different. In particular
    there are
  • Strong optimal subsidy effects of tariffs (use of
    monopoly power on World markets). A country can
    change its terms of trade.
  • Tax export effects for other taxes.

23
Single- or Multi-Country Armington Models
  • Armington Models with a number of different
    countries are often used to examine regional
    trade agreements (trade creation versus trade
    diversion effects). Usually, the selection of
    countries is chosen with particular relevance to
    the regional agreement in question. Other
    countries are lumped together as Rest of the
    World.
  • Where the model is more concerned with internal
    tax policies, then a single-country Armington
    structure is appropriate. Import demand is
    modelled as above (taking the Rest of the World
    prices as given, but the exchange rate as
    variable). Export demand is assumed to have a
    single, downward sloping demand curve for each
    commodity.

24
Trade Closure
  • In GENERAL EQUILIBRIUM models, trade is usually
    assumed to balance.
  • The price of one good (or factor) in one region
    is set as the denominator for the model, and
    normalised at unity.
  • Modellers often assume the trade balance remains
    at its level in the base year. Alternatively,
    adjustments may be made for changes in
    international aid etc. Or all countries may be
    assumed to move to complete balance in trade.
  • Remember, the balances of consumers, government
    and the external sector must sum to zero.
  • In PARTIAL EQUILIBRIUM models, the exchange rate
    is assumed to be fixed and trade balance is
    ignored.

25
CAPITAL MOBILITY
  • Some models allow for capital to be mobile
    between countries.
  • Often the way this is done is to assume a fixed
    capital stock Worldwide, but allow it to move
    between countries to equate interest rates across
    all countries.
  • If capital flows into a country, we need to
    remember that interest, profits and dividend will
    be paid to foreigners. These should therefore be
    deducted from exports in the trade balance.

26
Dynamic CGE models
  • Dynamic CGE models are closer in spirit to macro
    models (particularly if they also have sticky
    prices and money).
  • They take account of savings, investment and
    exchange rate overshooting effects. This sort of
    effect implies an Armington trade structure, or
    something similar.
  • They usually have forward-looking expectations.
    In practice this is often treated as meaning
    perfect certainty, so the model is solved
    forwards to an end-point. The tricky bit is
    getting plausible terminal conditions.
  • These models tend to be hard to solve, and are
    often very sensitive to choice of terminal
    conditions.
  • Multi-country models are usually too large to
    solve as anything other than static models.
  • Broadly speaking, people need to choose between a
    multi-country model of trade, with regional and
    sectoral effects modelled in detail, or a dynamic
    model with more macroeconomic adjustments but
    less regional and sectoral detail. HORSES FOR
    COURSES!

27
Other formulations Dixit-Stiglitz
  • A separate note on Dixit-Stiglitz models is
    available on the resources site.
  • Dixit-Stiglitz models are much harder to program
    and solve, compared to Armington, but generally
    suggest that trade has much deeper effects on the
    whole economy.
  • These models assume that all firms produce
    differentiated products, and that there are
    economies of scale at the firm level.
  • Consumers have a love of variety. This is
    modelled by aggregating together all firms
    output with a CES aggregation, with an elasticity
    of substitution greater than unity.

28
  • The CES aggregation of produce of an industry is
    therefore across all firms, not just across
    countries.
  • In the short run, the number of firms in each
    country is fixed. In many ways, this model is
    similar to Armington, except that changing
    openness to trade may lead to changes in profit
    markups. In general, greater openness?more
    competition?lower profit markups (and less
    deadweight loss). This is more true the smaller
    and the less open the economy is to start with.

29
  • In the long-run the number of firms in an
    industry varies to ensure monopolistic profits
    just cover the fixed cost of entry.
  • In this case, opening up to trade produces a
    further gain, insofar as some firms close,
    leading to scale economies.
  • Individual countries may lose.
  • Where firms produce inputs, and there are love
    of variety effects in intermediates, the model
    may well have multiple equilibria.

30
Heterogeneous Firms Models
  • These are probably the latest development in GE
    models. They assume that not all firms are
    equally efficient.
  • Critically, firms only find out how efficient
    they are after they have entered the industry and
    produced at a minimum economic scale for a fixed
    period of time.
  • After that time, firms below a reservation level
    of efficiency close, while the more efficient
    remain open.

31
  • Trade shocks can produce batting-order effects,
    raising efficiency among the surviving firms in
    declining industries (see Edwards, International
    Review of Applied Economics, forthcoming April?
    2006). Greater trade openness generally leads to
    rising efficiency for this reason.
  • If there are costs to entering foreign markets,
    then only efficient firms will export. The
    opening up of export markets may provide a
    selection mechanism in favour of the most
    efficient firms (recent work by Ghironi and
    Melitz and by Bernard, Schott and Redding
    confirms this).
  • THIS TYPE OF MODEL IS MUCH MORE COMPLICATED, BUT
    RICHER IN ITS EFFECTS ACROSS THE WHOLE ECONOMY.
    HETEROGENEOUS FIRM MODELS SHOULD NOT YET BE
    CONSIDERED TRIED AND TESTED.
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)
About PowerShow.com