Two fund separation and linear valuation - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

1 / 92
About This Presentation
Title:

Two fund separation and linear valuation

Description:

we give distributional conditions on the rates of return on assets so that ... Define: given any feasible portfolio, ... We shall proceed by contraposition. ... – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:414
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 93
Provided by: Admin251
Category:

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: Two fund separation and linear valuation


1
Chapter 4
  • Two fund separation and linear valuation

2
Main objective
  • we give distributional conditions on the rates of
    return on assets so that individuals will
    optimally choose to hold portfolios on the
    portfolio frontier.
  • Discuss the Capital Asset Pricing Model.(CAPM)
  • Also discuss the Arbitrage Pricing Theory(APT).

3
4.1 section
  • Two (mutual) fund separation phenomenon
  • Define given any feasible portfolio, there
    exists a portfolio of two mutual funds such that
    individuals prefer at least as much as the
    original portfolio. The phenomenon is termed two
    (mutual) fund separation.
  • E.g. if individuals prefer frontier portfolios,
    they can simply hold a linear combination of two
    frontier portfolios or mutual funds.

4
  • This chapter assume that
  • 1. all assets are risky.
  • 2. asset returns have finite second moments.
  • 3. no two asset returns are perfectly
    correlated, which imply that the
    variance-covariance matrix of asset returns
    exists and is positive definite.
  • Then portfolio frontier exists, and every
    frontier portfolio is uniquely determined in that
    there is a unique set of portfolio weights
    associated with each frontier portfolio.

5
4.2 section
  • The definition of two fund separation
  • a vector of asset rate of returns is
    said to exhibit two fund separation if there
    exist two mutual funds and such that for
    any portfolio q there exists a scalar such
    that
  • for all concave u(.)

6
  • Now termed that the vector of asset rates of
    return, , exhibits two fund separation.
  • We first claim that the separating mutual funds
    and must be frontier portfolios.

7
  • To see this, for any portfolio q,
  • from the definition of two fund separation,
  • This is equivalent to

8
  • By second degree stochastic dominance.
  • Suppose is not a frontier portfolio. The
    there must exist a portfolio that has a
    variance strictly smaller than that of any
    portfolio formed by and .
  • This contradicts the hypothesis that and
    are separating portfolios.
  • Hence and must be on the portfolio
    frontier.

9
4.3 section
  • If there exists two fund separation, any two
    distinct frontier portfolios can be separating
    funds.
  • In particular, we can pick any frontier
    portfolio, and its zero covariance
    portfolio, zc(p), to be the separating portfolios.

10
  • By Sections 3.16 and 3.17, for any portfolio q,
  • Where
  • Note that is
    the rate of return of the dominating portfolio.

11
4.4 section
  • We show that
  • two fund separation
  • First proof the necessity of (4.3.3)
  • proof. As is the return on the dominating
    portfolio, a0 is a solution of the following
    program

12
  • A necessary condition for a0 to be a solution is
  • Suppose does not hold for
    some q. Denote by and
    the cumulative distribution function of
    by F(.).

13
  • As 0 there must exist a real number z
    such that
  • By hypothesis that (4.3.3) does not hold for some
    q. we have (4.4.2) can not be zero for all z.
  • if the equality of (4.4.2) does not hold for all
    z, that is,

14
  • That is,
  • Then
  • Which contradicts the fact that

15
  • Now consider a concave utility function that is
    piecewise linear
  • Where gt0

16
  • Then
  • Which contradicts (4.4.1). Thus (4.3.3) is a
    necessary condition for two fund separation

17
4.5 section
  • Now show that the sufficient for two fund
    separation. That is, the separating portfolios
    are p and its zero covariance portfolio. If q is
    a portfolio, then the dominating portfolio is
  • To see this, let U(.) be any concave utility
    function.
  • Thus (4.3.3) is the sufficient for two fund
    separation

18
4.6 section
  • We will say that a vector of asset returns
    exhibits one fund separation if there exists a
    (feasible) portfolio such that every risk
    averse individual prefers to any other
    feasible portfolio.
  • That is, when one fund separation, there must
    exist a mutual fund such that for any
    portfolio q, for all concave u(.)

19
  • By second degree stochastic dominance, have
  • Therefore, write
  • Thus, One fund separation

20
  • Note that
  • 1. one fund separation can be viewed as a
    degenerate case of two fund separation.
  • 2. When all assets have the same expected rate of
    return, the portfolio frontier degenerates to a
    single point, the minimum variance portfolio.
  • 3.The portfolio frontier is thus trivially
    generated by a single mutual fund.
  • 4. A necessary and sufficient condition for one
    fund separation is given by (4.3.3) with

21
4.7 section
  • We shall give concrete examples of distributions
    of rates of return that exhibit two fund and one
    fund separation, respectively.
  • 1. If rates of return are multivariate normally
    distributed and have nonidentical expectations,
    two fund separation obtains.

22
  • By
  • As any linear combination of normal random
    variables is itself normal,
  • It follows that , , and are
    normal random variables.
  • Recall section 3.17
  • Have

23
  • Consequently,
  • We have thus shown that two fund separation
    obtains.
  • 2. When returns have identical expectations,
    multivariate normality implies one fund
    separation.

24
  • Let denote the return on the minimum
    variance portfolio. For any feasible portfolio q,
    we can always write
  • We know
  • Hence we know
  • Then yields
  • This establishes that one fund separation obtains.

25
4.8 section
  • In this and the next section, we will show that
    when two fund separation obtains and markets for
    risky assets are in equilibrium, the equilibrium
    relation among asset returns is linear.
  • First give a definition of a market portfolio.

26
  • Let be individual is initial wealth , and
    let be the proportion of the initial wealth
    invested in the j-th security by individual i.
  • The total wealth in the economy is
  • Where I is the total number of individuals in the
    economy


27
  • In equilibrium, the total wealth is equal
    to the total value of securities.
  • For markets to clear, we must have
  • Dividing by , we have
  • That is, the market portfolio weights are a
    convex combination of the portfolio weights for
    individuals.

28
4.9 section
  • We claim that when two fund separation obtains
    and in market equilibrium, the market portfolio
    is a frontier portfolio.
  • Next from section 3.16 that if p is a frontier
    (but not mvp) and q is any feasible portfolio, we
    have

29
  • Hence, if the market portfolio is not the minimum
    variance portfolio (mvp), we get
  • Where
  • Since any risky asset is itself a feasible
    portfolio, also have
  • For all j1,2,, N . Therefore the equilibrium
    relation among asset returns is linear.

30
4.10 section
  • Let us rewrite relation (4.9.3)
  • When (i.e. the market
    portfolio is an efficient portfolio, zc(m) is
    inefficient)
  • Note that the equilibrium expected rate of return
    on a risky asset depends upon the covariance of
    its rate of return with the rate of return on the
    market portfolio.

31
  • Figure

security market line
32
  • When 0

security market line
33
4.11 section
  • In this section, we shall analyze a special case
    of two fund separation and show that the market
    portfolio is an efficient portfolio.
  • Thus a relation like (4.10.1) is valid in
    equilibrium.
  • Let us assume that individuals utility functions
    are increasing and strictly concave.
  • Also assume that the rates of return on assets
    are multivariate normally distributed.
  • We show first that each individual will choose to
    hold an efficient portfolio.

34
  • The expected utility of individual is choice is
  • Where denotes a standard normal random
    variable.
  • Defining

35
  • Differentiating
  • Where
  • That is, individual i prefers a higher expected
    rate of return, ceteris paribus.

36
  • Also get
  • Where
  • So a strictly risk averse individual prefers a
    portfolio with a lower standard deviation,
    ceteris paribus.

37
  • Now we show that individuals will choose to hold
    efficient portfolios.
  • Totally differentiation
    (indifference curves)
  • Seeing figure.

38
  • Figure
  • Thus an individual will choose the point of
    tangency. Then his strictly positively sloped
    indifference curves imply that he will choose an
    efficient portfolio.

39
  • We know that all individuals hold efficient
    portfolios. Therefore, the market portfolio is an
    efficient portfolio.
  • Furthermore , we have for any feasible portfolio
  • This is known as the Zero-Beta Capital Asset
    Pricing Model which was developed by Black(1972)
    and Lintner(1969).

40
4.12 section
  • The above analyses, we have assumed that there is
    no riskless asset.
  • These next three sections are devoted to the case
    where there is a riskless asset.
  • Suppose first the expected rate of return on the
    minimum variance portfolio exceeds the riskless
    rate,
  • i.e.,

41
  • We know that the rate of return on any feasible
    portfolio q can be expressed as
  • With
  • We claim that
  • two fund
    separation.

42
  • We prove the necessity part first.
  • Suppose that two fund separation holds.
  • Thus two separating portfolios must be frontier
    portfolios and can be chosen to be portfolio e
    and the riskless asset.
  • Similar to section 4.4 then show that
  • For all portfolios q.

43
  • As is nonstochastic and we can always pick q
    to be any risky asset j, it follows that
  • It is implied by two fund separation when a
    riskless asset exists.

44
  • The sufficiency part follows easily from the
    arguments of section 4.5.
  • Thus implies two fund separation
    when a riskless asset exists.
  • Similar also show that when gtA/C
  • two fund separation
  • where

45
4.13 section
  • Assume that two fund separation holds.
  • When A/C and risky assets are in
    strictly positive supply, the tangent portfolios
    must be the market portfolios of risky assets in
    equilibrium.
  • Hence, using(3.19.1), we know
  • For any portfolio q in the market equilibrium.
  • This is the traditional Capital Asset Pricing
    Model (CAPM) independently derived by
    Lintner(1965), Mossin(1965), and Sharoe(164).

46
  • When A/C, the story is a little different.
  • We claim that the riskless asset is in strictly
    positive supply and the risky assets are in zero
    net supply in equilibrium.
  • Note that the relation(3.19.1) holds independent
    of the relationship between and A/C

47
4.14 section
  • In this section we will show that when investors
    have strictly increasing and concave utility
    functions, the risk premium of the market
    portfolio must be strictly positive when the
    risky assets are in strictly positive supply and
    the presence of two fund separation.

48
  • We first claim that an investor will never choose
    to hold a portfolio whose expected rate of return
    is strictly lower than the riskless rate when his
    utility function u(.) is strictly increasing and
    concave.
  • Let be the random return of a portfolio chosen
    by u(.) such that
  • Note that
  • This contradicts the hypothesis that the
    individual chooses to hold the portfolio with a
    random rate of return

49
  • when the risky assets are in strictly positive
    supply and the presence of two fund separation.
  • When A/C , an individual puts all his wealth
    into the riskless asset and holds a
    self-financing portfolio.
  • this contradicts that the risky assets are in
    strictly positive supply
  • Thus A/C

50
  • When gtA/C, then no investor holds a strictly
    positive amount of the market portfolio.
  • This is inconsistent with market clearing.
  • Thus in equilibrium, it must be the case that
    ltA/C and the risk premium of the market
    portfolio is strictly positive.
  • The half line in the standard deviation-expected
    rate of return space composed of efficient
    frontier portfolios and the riskless asset is
    termed the Capital Market Line.

51
  • We note that in the above proof when there exists
    a riskless asset, an investor will never choose
    to hold a portfolio having an expected rate of
    return strictly less than the riskless rate we
    only used the fact that an investor can always
    invest all his money in the riskless asset.
  • Hence the conclusion holds even when
    short-selling portfolio is not allowed.

52
  • When investors choose to hold efficient frontier
    portfolios and the riskless asset is in strictly
    positive supply, we have
  • For any feasible portfolio and

53
  • When the riskless borrowing is allowed at a rate
    strictly higher than the riskless lending rate,
    we have
  • For any feasible portfolio and
  • Where and denote the riskless lending rate
    and borrowing rate, respectively.
  • These relations is termed the constrained
    borrowing versions of the CAPM

54
4.15 section
  • In this and the next section, we will discuss two
    simple situations where we can explicitly write
    down how the risk premium of the market portfolio
    is related to investors optimal portfolio
    decisions.
  • First, suppose that there exists a riskless asset
    with a rate of return and that the rates of
    return of risky assets are multivariate normally
    distributed.

55
  • Section 1.18 shows that
  • Where
  • Using the definition of a covariance,
  • Under normally distributed, have

Steins lemma
56
  • By steins lemma,
  • Defining the i-th investors global absolute risk
    aversion
  • Dividing by summing across i.

57
  • We get
  • Where
  • Note that is the harmonic mean of
    individuals global absolute risk aversion.
  • We can interpret to be the
    aggregate relative risk aversion of the economy
    in equilibrium.

58
  • Relation (4.15.4) implies that
  • Substituting (4.15.5) into (4.15.4) gives the
    familiar CAPM.

(4.15.4)
(4.15.5)
59
4.16 section
  • For example
  • Now assume that utility functions are quadratic
  • Easy obtain CAPM

60
4.17 section
  • In the context of the CAPM, a risky assets beta
    with respect to the market portfolio is a
    sufficient statistic for its contribution to the
    riskiness of an individuals portfolio.
  • Risky assets whose payoffs are positively
    correlated with those of the market portfolio
    have positive risk premiums.
  • In such event, the higher the asset beta, the
    higher the risk premium.
  • The intuition of this relationship can be
    understood as follows. Seeing p103.

61
4.18 section
  • Recall from previous analyses, two fund
    separation implies that there exists a linear
    relation among expected returns of assets.
  • In equilibrium, the coefficients of the linear
    relation are identified to be related to the
    betas of asset returns with respect to the
    return on the market portfolio.
  • As saying that the rate of return on an risky
    asset is generated by a one factor model plus a
    random noise whose conditional expectation given
    the factor is identically zero.
  • We will give mult-factors model in following
    section

62
4.19 section
  • We consider a sequence of economies with
    increasing numbers of assets.
  • In the n-th economy, there are n risky assets and
    a riskless asset.
  • The rates of return on risky assets are generated
    by a K-factor model
  • Where
  • And
  • Where are rates of return on portfolios
  • Using matrix notation, we can write as

63
4.20 section
  • We first note that if
  • then there exists an exact linear relation among
    expected rates of return on assets in the n-th
    economy, if one cannot create something out of
    nothing.
  • This follows since the returns on risky assets
    are completely spanned by the K factors
    (portfolios) and the riskless asset.

64
  • Formally, consider a portfolio of the K factors
    and the riskless asset, , with
  • Where is the proportion invested in the
    riskless asset and is the proportion
    invested in the k-th factor.

65
  • The rate of return on this portfolio is
  • Note that the factor components of the rate of
    return on replicate those of asset j.

66
  • We show that must be equal to
  • We shall show that if this is not the case,
    something can be created out of nothing.
  • Suppose that

67
  • We establish a portfolio by investing one dollar
    in and shorting one dollars worth of
    security j. this portfolio costs nothing. Its
    rate of return, however, is
  • Which is riskless and strictly positive. Hence
    something has been created out of nothing, or
    there exists a free lunch.

68
  • Reversing the above arguments for the case
    we thus have
  • From
  • Obtain
  • That is, there exists an exact linear relation
    among expected asset reurns.

69
4.21 section
  • When the are not zeros, the story is a
    little complicated.
  • Formally, in economy n, a portfolio of the n
    risky assets and riskless asset is an arbitrage
    portfolio if it costs nothing.
  • An arbitrage opportunity (in the limit) is a
    sequence of arbitrage portfolios whose expected
    rates of return are bounded below away from zero,
    while their variances converge to zero.
  • That is, it almost a free lunch.

70
  • We wish to show that if there is no arbitrage
    opportunity, then a linear relation among
    expected asset returns will hold approximately
    for most of the assets in a large economy.
  • We first claim that
  • For most of the asset in large economies.

71
  • To see this, we fix , however small. Let
    N(n) be the number of assets in the n-th economy
    such that the absolute value of the difference
    between the two sides of (4.21.1) is greater than
  • Without loss of generality, assume that

72
  • If we can show that there exists such that
    for all n, we are done.
  • This follows since there will be at most assets
    that satisfy(4.21.2) for arbitrarily large n and
    can be arbitrarily small.
  • We shall proceed by contraposition.

73
  • Suppose that there does not exist a finite
    such that for all n.
  • Then there must exist a subsequence of
  • denoted by,
    such that when
  • We construct a sequence of arbitrage portfolios
    as follows.
  • First, construct arbitrage portfolios
    that have no factor risk in economy .

74
  • The rate of return for the j-th arbitrage
    portfolio is
  • where

75
  • Next, form a portfolio of these arbitrage
    portfolios with a constant weight, on
    each.
  • The resulting portfolio is still an arbitrage
    portfolio with an expected rate of return
  • And a variance

76
  • Since as , the variance
    of the sequence of arbitrage portfolios converge
    to zero, while their expected rates of return are
    bounded below away from zero by .
  • Thus there exists an arbitrage opportunity, a
    contradiction.
  • We hence conclude that there must exists a finite
    such that for all n.

77
4.22 section
  • Now using the fact proven above that for a given
    , however small, there exist at most
    risky assets such that
  • We know
  • For all but at most risky assets in any
    economy.
  • Thus, for economies with the number of assets
    much larger than , a linear relation among
    expected asset returns holds approximately for
    most of the assets.
  • This relation is the Arbitrage Pricing Theory
    (APT) originated by Ross (1976)

78
4.23 section
  • For the APT to make predictions in an economy
    with a finite number of assets, would like to
    bound the deviation from the APT linear relation
    for any asset.
  • Using equilibrium rather than arbitrage
    arguments, therefore called equilibrium APT
  • Suppose that there are N risky assets in the
    economy, indexed by j1,2,N, and a riskless
    asset.
  • These risky assets are in strictly positive
    supply.
  • The rate of return on the riskless asset is

79
  • The rates of return on risky assets are generated
    by a K-factor model
  • With
  • We also assume that the random variables
  • are independent and that are rates of
    return on portfolios.

80
  • We assume that agents have utility functions that
    are increasing, strictly concave, and absolute
    risk aversion
  • From section 4.20 that, when
  • Or equivalently
  • Our purpose here is to bound the deviation of
    from the right hand side of (4.23.3), in market
    equilibrium, when is not identically zero.

81
4.24 section
  • Consider a portfolio of the K factors and the
    riskless asset having a rate of return
  • An arbitrage portfolio is constructed by
    investing one dollar in the above portfolio and
    shorting one dollars worth of risky asset j.
  • This arbitrage portfolio has a rate of return
  • i.e.

82
  • Let be individual is initial wealth, let be
    individual is time-1 random wealth.
  • Then is the unique solution to the
    following problem
  • The first order necessary condition for
    to be an optimum is

83
  • Using , the above relation can be
    written as
  • Now we claim that, for all j such that

84
  • To see this, note that risky assets are in
    strictly positive supply. Suppose risky asset j
    with is held in a strictly positive
    amount in equilibrium by individual i.
  • By the strict concavity of and the assumption
    that is independent of all other random
    variable,
  • We know that

85
  • Then (4.24.3)holds for j by the fact that the
    above arguments can be applied to all j such that
    . Thus we have that (4.24.3) holds for all
    such js.
  • As a consequence of the above analysis, we can
    also conclude that if , then asset j is
    held in a strictly positive amount by all
    individuals.

86
2.25 section
  • Now fix risky asset j with . Let
    be the dollar amount invested in
    the risky asset j by individual i.
  • Define
  • Taylors expansion
  • Where all the other random variables are
    independent and is a random variable whose
    value lies between and .

87
  • By the assumption that 1, we have
  • Therefore
  • We claim that

88
  • To see this, we first note that since
  • Where the second inequality follows from the
    concavity of

89
  • Next, we observe that
  • by
  • Therefore

90
  • Now we obtain
  • Note also that, since , by the
    conditional Jensens inequality, we have

91
  • Finally, by
  • We have
  • Or equivalently,

92
  • Let the total market value of asset j be denoted
    by
  • In equilibrium there exists an i such that
    , where I is the number of individuals in the
    economy.
  • We thus have
  • Where we gives an explicit bound of the deviation
    of from the APT relation.
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)
About PowerShow.com