Elasticities of demand and supply - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

1 / 40
About This Presentation
Title:

Elasticities of demand and supply

Description:

Harvest failures (and bumper crops) are a feature of agricultural markets. ... Conversely, bumper crops induce very large falls in food prices. ... – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:234
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 41
Provided by: Seb126
Category:

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: Elasticities of demand and supply


1
Elasticities of demand and supply
2
The price responsiveness of demand
  • The price elasticity of demand is the
    percentage change in the quantity demanded
    divided by the corresponding percentage change in
    its price.

3
  • Although we later introduce other demand
    elasticities - the cross-price elasticity and
    the income elasticity - the (own)-price
    elasticity is the most often used of the three.
    If economists speak of the demand elasticity they
    mean the price elasticity of demand, as defined
    above.
  • If a 1 per cent price rise reduces the quantity
    demanded by 2 per cent, the demand elasticity is
    2. The minus sign tells us quantity falls when
    price rises. If a price fall of 4 per cent
    increases the quantity demanded by 2 per cent,
    the demand elasticity is 1/2 since the quantity
    change (2 per cent) is divided by the price
    change (-4 per cent). Since demand curves slope
    down, price and quantity changes always have
    opposite signs. The price elasticity of demand
    tells us about movements along a demand curve.
    The demand elasticity is a negative number.

4
Determinants of price elasticity
  • Consider two extreme cases. Suppose the price
    of all cigarettes rises by 1 per cent. The
    quantity of cigarettes demanded will hardly
    respond. People who can easily quit smoking have
    already done so. In contrast, suppose the price
    of a particular brand of cigarettes rises by 1
    per cent, all other brand prices remaining
    unchanged. We expect a much larger quantity
    response. Consumers switch from the dearer brand
    to other brands that also satisfy the nicotine
    habit. For a particular cigarette brand the
    demand elasticity is quite high.
  • Our example suggests a general rule. The more
    narrowly we define a commodity (a particular
    brand of cigarette rather than cigarettes in
    general), the higher will be the price elasticity
    of demand

5
Table 4-1 The demand for football tickets
6
  • The price elasticity of demand for football
    tickets is shown in column (3) of Table 4-1.
    Examining the effect of price cuts of 2.50, we
    calculate the price elasticity of demand at each
    price. Beginning at 10 and 20 000 tickets
    demanded, consider a price cut to 7.50. The
    price change is 25 per cent, from 10 to 7.50,
    the change in quantity demanded is 100 per cent,
    from 20000 to 40000 tickets. The demand
    elasticity at 10 is (100/25) 4. Other
    elasticities are calculated in the same way,
    dividing the percentage change in quantity by the
    corresponding percentage change in price. When we
    begin from the price of 12.50 the demand
    elasticity is minus infinity. The percentage
    change in quantity demanded is 20/0. Any
    positive number divided by zero is infinity.
    Dividing by the 20 per cent change in price,
    from 12.50 to 10.00, the demand elasticity is
    minus infinity at this price.

7
  • We say that the demand elasticity is high if it
    is a large negative number. The quantity demanded
    is sensitive to the price. The demand elasticity
    is low if it is a small negative number and the
    quantity demanded is insensitive to the price.
    'High' or 'low refer to the size of the
    elasticity ignoring the minus sign. The demand
    elasticity falls when it becomes a smaller
    negative number and quantity demanded becomes
    less sensitive to the price.

8
Figure 4-1 The demand for football tickets

9
  • The demand curve for football tickets is a
    straight line with constant slope along its
    entire length a 1 cut in price always leads to
    8000 extra ticket sales. Yet Table 4-1 shows the
    demand elasticity falls as we move down the
    demand curve from higher prices to lower prices.
    At high prices, 1 is a small percentage change
    in the price but 8000 tickets is a large
    percentage change in the quantity demanded.
    Conversely, at low prices 1 is a large
    percentage change in the price but 8000 is a
    small percentage change in the quantity. When the
    demand curve is a straight line, the price
    elasticity falls steadily as we move down the
    demand curve.

10
  • Demand is elastic if the price elasticity is
    more negative than 1. Demand is inelastic if
    the price elasticity lies between 1 and 0. If
    the demand elasticity is exactly 1, demand is
    unelastic.

11
Measuring price elasticities
Table 4-2 UK price elasticities of demand
12
  • Table 4-2 confirms that the demand for broad
    categories of basic commodities, such as fuel,
    food, or even household durable goods, is
    inelastic. As a category, only services such as
    haircuts, the theatre, and sauna baths, have an
    elastic demand. Households simply do not have
    much scope to alter the broad pattern of their
    purchases.
  • In contrast, there is a much wider variation in
    the demand elasticities for narrower definitions
    of commodities. Even then, the demand for some
    commodities, such as dairy produce, is very
    inelastic. However, particular kinds of services
    such as entertainment and catering have much
    more elastic demand.

13
Using price elasticities
  • Price elasticities of demand are useful in
    calculating the price rise required to eliminate
    a shortage (excess demand) or the price fall to
    eliminate a surplus (excess supply). One
    important source of surpluses and shortages is
    shifts in the supply curve. Harvest failures (and
    bumper crops) are a feature of agricultural
    markets. Because the demand elasticity for many
    agricultural products is very low, harvest
    failures produce large increases in the price of
    food. Conversely, bumper crops induce very large
    falls in food prices. When demand is very
    inelastic, shifts in the supply curve lead to
    large fluctuations in price but have little
    effect on equilibrium quantities

14
Price, quantity demanded, and total expenditure
  • Other things equal, the demand curve shows how
    much consumers of a good wish to purchase at each
    price. At each price, total spending by consumers
    is the price multiplied by the quantity demanded.
    We now discuss the relation between total
    spending and price, and show the relevance of the
    price elasticity of demand.

15
Short run and long run
  • The price elasticity of demand varies with time
    in which consumers can adjust their spending
    patterns when prices change. The most dramatic
    price change of the last 50 years, the oil price
    rise of 1973-74, caught many households with a
    new but fuel-inefficient car. At first, they may
    not have expected the higher oil price to last.
    Then they may have planned to buy a smaller car
    with greater fuel economy. But in countries like
    the US few small cars were yet available. In the
    short run, households were stuck. Unless they
    could rearrange their lifestyles to reduce car
    use, they had to pay the higher petrol prices.
    Demand for petrol was inelastic.

16
  • Over a longer period, consumers had time to
    sell their big cars and buy cars with better fuel
    economy, or to move from the distant suburbs
    closer to their place of work. Over this longer
    period, they could reduce the quantity of petrol
    demanded much more than initially.
  • The price elasticity of demand is lower in the
    short run than in the long run when there is more
    scope to substitute other goods. This result is
    very general. Even if addicted smokers can't
    adjust to a rise in the price of cigarettes,
    fewer young people start smoking and gradually
    the number of smokers falls.

17
  • How long is the long run?
  • The short run is the period after prices change
    but before quantity adjustment can occur. The
    long run is the period needed for complete
    adjustment to a price change. Its length depends
    on the type of adjustments consumers wish to make.

18
The cross-price elasticity of demand
  • The cross-price elasticity of demand for good i
    with respect to changes in the price of good j is
    the percentage change in the quantity of good i
    demanded, divided by the corresponding percentage
    change in the price of good j.

19
Table 4-6 Cross-price and own-price
elasticities of demand in the UK
20
  • Table 4-6 shows estimates for the UK. Own-price
    elasticities for food, clothing, and travel are
    given down the diagonal of the table, from top
    left (the own-price elasticity of demand for
    food) to bottom right (the own-price elasticity
    of demand for travel). Off-diagonal entries in
    the table show cross-price elasticities of
    demand. Thus, 0.1 is the cross-price elasticity
    of demand for food with respect to travel. A 1
    per cent increase in the price of travel
    increases the quantity of food demanded by 0.1
    per cent.
  • The own-price elasticities for the three goods
    lie between 0.4 and 0.5. For all three goods
    the quantity demanded is more sensitive to
    changes in its own price than to changes in the
    price of any other good.

21
The effect of income on demand
  • Finally, holding constant the own price of a
    good and the prices of related goods, we examine
    the response of the quantity demanded to changes
    in consumer incomes. For the moment we neglect
    the possibility of saving. Thus a rise in the
    income of consumers will typically be matched by
    an equivalent increase in total consumer spending.

22
  • The budget share of a good is its price times
    the quantity demanded, divided by total consumer
    spending or income
  • The income elasticity of demand for a good is
    the percentage change in quantity demanded
    divided by the corresponding percentage change in
    income.

23
Normal, inferior, and luxury goods
  • The income elasticity of demand measures how
    far the demand curve shifts horizontally when
    incomes change. Figure 4-5 shows two possible
    shifts caused by a given percentage increase in
    income. The income elasticity is larger if the
    given rise in income shifts the demand curve from
    DD to D"D" than if the same income rise shifts
    the demand curve only from DD to D'D'. When an
    income rise shifts the demand curve to the left,
    the income elasticity of demand is a negative
    number, indicating that higher incomes are
    associated with smaller quantities demanded at
    any given prices.

24
  • A normal good has a positive income elasticity
    of demand. An inferior good has a negative income
    elasticity of demand.
  • We also distinguish luxury goods and necessities.
  • A luxury good has an income elasticity above
    unity. A necessity has an income elasticity below
    unity.
  • All inferior goods are necessities, since their
    income elasticities of demand are negative.
    However, necessities also include normal goods
    whose income elasticity of demand lies between
    zero and one.

25
Inflation and demand
  • Elasticities measure the response of quantity
    demanded to separate variations in three factors
    -the own price, the price of related goods, and
    income. Chapter 2 distinguished nominal
    variables, measured in the prices of the day, and
    real variables, which adjust for inflation when
    comparing measurements at different dates. We end
    this chapter by examining the effect of inflation
    on demand behaviour.

26
Elasticity of supply
  • Whereas the analysis of demand elasticities is
    quite tricky, the analysis of supply elasticities
    is refreshingly simple. We really need only keep
    track of the supply response to an increase in
    the own price of a good or service. The
    elasticity of supply measures the responsiveness
    of the quantity supplied to a change in the price
    of that commodity.
  • Supply change in quantity supplied
  • elasticity change in price

27
Who realty pays the tax?
  • By spending and taxing, the government affects
    resource allocation in the economy. By taxing
  • cigarettes, the government can reduce the amount
    of cigarettes smoked and thereby improve health.
    By taxing fuel it can discourage pollution,
    though it may incur the wrath of lorry drivers
    and motorists. By taxing income earned from work,
    the government affects the amount of time people
    want to work. Taxes loom large in the workings of
    a mixed economy and have a profound effect on the
    way society allocates its scarce resources.

28
Consumer choice and demand decisions
29
Demand by a single consumer
  • The budget constraint
  • A consumer's income and the market prices of
    goods define her budget constraint.
  • The budget constraint describes the different
    bundles that the consumer can afford.
  • Consider a student with a weekly budget
    (income, allowance, or grant) of 50 to be spent
    on meals or films. Each meal costs 5 and each
    film 10. What combination of meals and films can
    she afford? Going without films, she can spend
    50 on 10 meals at 5 each. Going without meals,
    she can buy 5 cinema tickets at 10 each. Between
    these two extremes lie many combinations of meals
    and films that together cost exactly 50. These
    combinations are called the budget constraint.

30
  • The budget constraint shows the maximum
    affordable quantity of one good given the
    quantity of the other good being purchased.

31
  • The marginal rate of substitution of meals for
    films is the quantity of films the consumer must
    sacrifice to increase the quantity of meals by
    one unit without changing total utility.
  • Consumers prefer more to less. An extra meal
    increases utility. To hold utility constant when
    a meal is added, the consumer must sacrifice some
    of the other good (films). The marginal rate of
    substitution tells us how many films the consumer
    could exchange for an additional meal without
    changing total utility.

32
  • Suppose the student has 5 films and no meals.
    Having already seen 4 films, she does not enjoy
    the fifth film much. With no meals, she is very
    hungry. The utility of this bundle is low being
    so hungry, she cannot enjoy films anyway. For the
    same low amount of utility she could give up a
    lot of films for a little food.

33
  • This common-sense reasoning about tastes or
    preferences is very robust. It can become a
    general principle, the third assumption we need
    to make about consumer tastes. It is the
    assumption of a diminishing marginal rate of
    substitution.
  • Consumer tastes exhibit a diminishing marginal
    rate of substitution when, to hold utility
    constant, diminishing quantities of one good will
    be sacrificed to obtain successive equal
    increases in the quantity of the other good.

34
Utility maximization and choice
  • The budget line shows affordable bundles given
    a consumer's market environment (his budget and
    the price of different goods). The indifference
    map shows his tastes. To complete the model, we
    assume the consumer chooses the affordable bundle
    that maximizes his utility.
  • To find which point on the budget line
    maximizes utility we examine the consumer's
    tastes. Our glutton should pick a point with more
    meals and less films than the point our film buff
    selects. We first show how to use indifference
    curves to find the bundle the consumer chooses.
    Then we confirm that our model of consumer choice
    captures the different behaviour of the glutton
    and the film buff.

35
Adjustment to price changes
  • The substitution effect of a price change is
    the adjustment of demand to the relative price
    change alone. The income effect of a price change
    is the adjustment of demand to the change in real
    income alone.

36
The market demand curve
  • The market demand curve is the sum of the
  • demand curves of all individuals in that market.
  • At each price, we find out how much each
    consumer demands. Adding the quantities demanded
    by all consumers at that price, we get the total
    quantity demanded at each price, the market
    demand curve. Since, as price is reduced, each
    person increases the quantity demanded, the total
    quantity demanded must also increase as price
    falls. The market demand curve also slopes
    downwards.
  • The market demand curve is the horizontal
    addition of individual demand curves. With prices
    on the vertical axis and quantities on the
    horizontal axis, we must add together individual
    quantities demanded at the same price.

37
Complements and substitutes
  • Income and substitution effects are used to
    understand the effects of a price change.
    Whatever the direction of the income effect, with
    only two goods the substitution effect is always
    negative. The pure relative price effect leads
    the consumer to substitute away from the good
    whose relative price has risen towards the good
    whose relative price has fallen. Abstracting from
    income effects, goods are necessarily substitutes
    for one another in a two-good world.

38
  • Even with many goods, there is always a
    substitution effect away from goods whose
    relative price has risen. However, substitution
    may not be towards all other goods. Consumers
    substitute away from goods consumed jointly with
    the good whose price has risen.

39
Transfers in kind
  • A transfer is a payment, usually by the
    government, for which no corresponding service
    is provided by the recipient. A transfer in kind
    is the gift of a good or service.

40
  • THE END
  • for today..
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)
About PowerShow.com