Title: Luis Servn
1Latin Americas infrastructure gap a
macroeconomic perspective
- Luis Servén
- The World Bank
- ECLAC
- January 2005
2Plan
- The changing policy framework
- The infrastructure gap
- The output cost
- The lessons
3The changing policy framework
- Until the 1970s, the public sector dominated
infrastructure provision in both industrial and
developing countries. - Since the 1980s (earlier in Chile and the UK)
Latin America led the worldwide drive towards
opening up of infrastructure to private
initiative in various forms and extents. - The drive was propitiated by a hardening of
fiscal discipline in response to financial
instability and macroeconomic crises - In most countries, the fiscal retrenchment led
to a sharp contraction of public infrastructure
investment (similarly to the post-Maastritch
fiscal adjustment in the EU)
4The changing policy framework
5The changing policy framework
Latin Americas fiscal adjustment Contribution
of consumption and investment
6The changing policy framework
7The changing policy framework
Latin America Total investment in
Infrastructure (weighted average of 7 countries,
percent of GDP)
8The changing policy framework
Latin America Total investment in
Infrastructure (6 major countries, percent of GDP)
9The changing policy framework
10The changing policy framework
- The private sector response
- Private initiative surged in the 1990s -- but
with diversity across industries (and countries) - Strong response in telecommunications, much less
in transport. - Evidence of public-private complementarity, not
only substitution countries maintaining higher
public investment attracted more private
investment (Chile, Bolivia, Colombia) - The rise in private investment was not enough for
asset accumulation to keep up with other world
regions - The investment fall contributed to widen Latin
Americas infrastructure gap in terms of
quantity and quality -- widened over the 1980s
and 1990s
11The changing policy framework
Brazil the power sector
Investment
Capacity change
12The infrastructure gap
13The infrastructure gap
14The infrastructure gap
15The infrastructure gap
Perceived infrastructure quality (Medians by
region, 2000)
16The output cost
- Why do we care about infrastructure ?
- The availability and quality of infrastructure
services is key for productivity and
profitability - Robust association between infrastructure
availability and aggregate output / growth within
and across countries - Partly driven by reverse causality (growth
encourages demand for infrastructure services) - But there is broad agreement that infrastructure
development has a strong causal effect of on
economic development. - Evidence that infrastructure development helps
reduce income inequality makes it easier for
the poor to access economic opportunities, jobs,
health and education.
17Source Calderón and Servén (2004b)
18Source Calderón, Easterly and Servén (2003)
19Source Calderón and Servén (2004b)
20The output cost
- What is the contribution of infrastructure
services to aggregate output and/or its growth
rate ? - Three main empirical approaches in the
literature - Empirical growth models
- Augmented production (or cost) function
- VARs
- Caveats
- -- technical problems often severe
(identification / reverse causality, spurious
regressions) - -- all else equal the costs of getting there
are not explored large tax rises or cuts in
other expenditures that may have an output cost
21The output cost
- The long-run growth approach
- Adding infrastructure into a standard growth
regression - Infrastructure usually proxied by
telecommunications indicators (e.g., Easterly
2001, Loayza et al 2003) - Calderón and Servén 2004b panel of 100
countries, 40 years - Consider both infrastructure quantity and
quality - Synthetic infrastructure indicator first
principal component of power, roads, telecom
accounts for 80 of their variance. - Endogeneity identification via GMM-IV with (a)
internal instruments (b) demographic variables - Growth contribution of infrastructure quantity
and quality is statistically and economically
significant.
22The output cost
Additional growth in LAC countries due to
increased infrastructure development
Source Calderón and Servén 2004b
23The output cost
- The augmented production function approach
- Unlike VARs and growth regressions, it is a
structural approach - Y F (K, H, Z) K physical capital H human
capital (often omitted) Z infrastructure
capital (power, phone lines, roads) - Productive services assumed proportional to
asset stocks - In actual data, Z often is already included in
K The coefficient on Z captures the return
differential on Z over K - In addition to usual reverse causality problem,
spurious correlation problem when using time
series nonstationarity of Y, K, Z leads to huge
infrastructure coefficient estimates (Aschauer
1990)
24The output cost
- The augmented production function approach
- Calderón and Servén 2005 panel time-series
estimation for 90 countries, 40 years. - Spurious regression problem does not arise here
(due to large N) - Only one long-run relation found resolves
identification problem - Pooled and country-specific estimates permit
assessing heterogeneity across countries /
regions - Synthetic index and disaggregated infrastructure
assets - Results broadly similar to Calderón, Easterly
and Servén 2003 in spite of very different
approach (GMM-IV to deal with identification
first-differencing to deal with nonstationarity)
25The output cost
Estimated (log) infrastructure coefficients (DOLS
estimates, 1960-2001, synthetic index)
Source Calderón and Servén 2005
26The output cost
- Country-specific estimates
- Synthetic Infrastructure Index, GLS--PIC (1,1)
Source Calderón and Servén 2005
27The output cost
- The estimated return on infrastructure assets is
significantly higher than that on other physical
capital in the vast majority of countries. - Infrastructure has significantly lower returns
than other capital only in 3 out of 89 countries
none in LAC - Across LAC countries, some heterogeneity too
- The differential return on overall infrastructure
is significantly higher than average in Peru,
Mexico, Colombia - Differences also across assets e.g., the
differential return on power generation capacity
is significantly lower than average in Paraguay,
but higher in Brazil
28The output cost
Estimated (log) infrastructure
coefficients (DOLS estimates, 1960-2001)
Source Calderón and Servén 2005
29The output cost
The cost of the widening infrastructure gap EAP
vs LAC
Source Based on Calderón and Servén 2005
30The lessons
- (1) Fiscal adjustment, as commonly measured and
enforced, tends to have an anti-investment bias - One (not the only) major factor is the use of
inappropriate fiscal rules targeting liquidity,
the cash deficit and gross public debt rather
than solvency and net worth, which are key to
fiscal sustainability. - Infrastructure projects have a negative short-run
liquidity effect -- it takes time to build the
assets and get the returns. - The focus on fiscal liquidity discourages such
projects even if they are consistent with good
public economics i.e., they enhance solvency.
31The lessons
- (2) Infrastructure investment cuts represent an
inefficient fiscal adjustment strategy - The direct effect of the spending cut is to raise
liquidity and public sector net worth - But there is an opposing indirect effect less
infrastructure means less output and lower fiscal
revenues tomorrow - The indirect effect offsets partly the direct
effect and can even make fiscal adjustment
self-defeating.
32Summary
- Latin Americas infrastructure gap widened in
the 1980s and early 1990s, at a substantial cost
in terms of output and productivity. - A major factor in the process was the investment
slowdown caused by a public investment decline
not offset (except in telecom) by private sector
participation. - The public investment compression reflected a
biased and inefficient fiscal adjustment,
encouraged by rules targeting liquidity and debt
rather than solvency and net worth. - Ensuring adequate room for productive spending
requires fiscal rules that reconcile solvency and
growth.
33End
34The changing policy framework
- Fiscal discipline has led to a public investment
fall not only in developing countries also in
the EU - The fiscal targets imposed in the Maastritch
Treaty contributed to a decline in public
investment across Europe - Out of 9 countries exceeding the Maastritch
deficit limit in 1992, 8 met it in 1997. Public
investment had fallen in all 8 ! - Infrastructure investment fell along with the
total
35The changing policy framework