Title: Multilateral Negotiations
1Multilateral Negotiations
- Bargaining with more the two players
2Coalitional bargaining
- Also called, core bargaining the basis of
added value - We may not be able to pin down exactly what will
happen in a negotiation - But we can rule out certain outcomes
- That will allow us to figure out the range of
possible outcomes - Basic idea
- Individuals and Groups should never get less
than their outside option ( what the group could
get if they split off went on their own)
3Basics of multi-party bargaining
- Each person or sub group should never get less
than their outside option - Because they can always split off and go their
own way - No individual or subgroup can get more than their
added value ( the extra surplus their presence
creates) - Because all others can always throw you out!
4The Core with 2 Players
- How does this relate to 2-person bargaining?
- You will never get less than your BATNA,
otherwise youll give up on negotiations and take
your BATNA - Depending on bargaining skill and the other
factors described, youll get more or less of the
surplus. - (If you are evenly matched in skill, delay
costs, and risks of breakdown, youll get half
the surplus. But that is less certain than that
you should never accept less than your BATNA)
5The Core
- Consider the coalition of all players
- An allocation or competitive distribution just
refers to a split of the total payoff available
to all players - An allocation is blocked if some individual or
subgroup is better off separating and going their
own way (i.e. the allocation does not give them
their outside option) - An allocation is in the core if it cannot be
blocked by any individual or coalition
The core is the range of likely bargaining
outcomes
6Airline JV example
- Three airlines, A, B and C are negotiating a
joint venture - By allying themselves, the airlines can offer
business customers unbroken service from Europe,
through the US to Asia (and back) - An airline not joining the JV receives no surplus
(BATNA 0) - Airlines A and C create no surplus alone
- A and B can generate 100m without C
- B and C can generate 150m without A
- If all three work together, a 200m surplus is
generated - Note
- Airline B is critical to the JV
- This should influence what it gets as a result of
negotiations
7Airline example
- What is the range of likely bargaining outcomes?
- Is an equal split likely? No!
- Under an equal split, A, B and C each get 200/3
? 66.7. - B and C get an aggregate payoff of 400/3 ?
133.3. - But, B and C can produce 150 on their own
- Rather than take 66.7 each to join the big JV,
they could form their own JV and get, say, 75
each! - Cant imagine B and C would ever freely agree to
such a deal - Essentially, A and C compete to obtain Bs
productive services - A competitive distribution is one where A and B
together get at least 100 B and C together get
at least 150 and the total 200 is divided up - For example, if B got 150 and neither A nor C
got anything, the stability requirement would be
satisfied, but not the feasibility requirement - On the other hand, B getting the whole surplus of
200 is competitive - So is B gets 50, A gets 50 and C gets 100
- There are many other possibilities, some of which
may be much more likely than others
8Another example
- Suppose that there are three agents.
- Together they can generate 120 in value.
- Individually they can not generate any value.
- Any coalition of 2 agents can generate 100.
- Conclusion there is no stable allocation the
core is empty.
9The empty core problem
- What happens where there is an empty core?
- Solutions
- This can be solved if one party seizes the
initiative and acts first to commit to certain
aspects of the bargain - Change in ownership
- Repeated interactions
10Lessons on multi-party bargaining
- The core sets the range of bargaining outcomes
- No player or sub group gets less than their
outside alternative - No player or sub group gets more than their added
value - But the core may not exist unstable bargaining
- As before, in some cases a player can seize the
initiative and set the rules of bargaining to
favour themselves
11Added Value
- A useful tool in multilateral bargaining
12V the total surplus
- The number of possible transactions in a market
is HUGE - Under arms-length transactions, freely
undertaken, there is no reason for agents to
engage in inefficient deals - Any group of agents engaged in inefficient deals
can do better relative to any feasible
compensation scheme under the inefficient regime
by switching to an efficient deal and splitting
up the additional value among themselves - No agent has a built-in advantage
- No one gets to make take-it-or-leave-it offers
(agents negotiate until everyone is satisfied) - No one has an information advantage (relative to
knowing the available opportunities facing the
various groups) - So, think of the entire market as a team whose
objective is to maximize the aggregate surplus
(just like we did in the 2-agent case) - This maximum quantity of economic value is V
13How is V measured?
- Total Surplus
-
- Economic surplus same idea as 2-agent case
14Cooperative DM Added Value
- Remember To find the actions that maximise
surplus, think of the bargaining players as a big
team or a family, doing whats best for the
group. - Added Value roughly, the economic profit from
you cooperating with the rest of the group - maximise the pie, cooperate
- (Group
- you) a new option! Others
cooperate, but - you dont cooperate with rest of group
no cooperation
15Your added value
- What is your economic contribution to the market?
- A certain amount of surplus can be produced
without you - Denote this amount V-you
- Since V is efficient, V-you must be less than V
- With you, V is possible
- Hence, the amount of value you contribute is V
V-you - We call this difference your added value
- Denote this avyou
- Note V-you is the maximum surplus all other
agents can produce if you refuse to transact with
them
16What is your Added Value?
17You cant get more than avyou !
- Why will the other agents never agree to deal in
which your a payoff surpasses your added value? - Because, rather than agreeing to a deal in which
?you gt avyou, the other agents can - Tell you to sd-off,
- produce V-you, and
- Share it in such a way that they are all better
off - To put it differently, any distribution in which
?you gt avyou fails the stability requirement
because -
18Implication limit their added value!
- A key aspect of modern strategy
- try to limit the added values of other agents
- make them dispensable!
- If the other agents added values are small
relative to yours, you may have the opportunity
to appropriate a much larger share of the pie - In fact, if they are sufficiently small, you may
be guaranteed an economic profit (payoff above
your BATNA) - Suppose
- You must get ?you gt BATNAyou! (why?)
19Competitive Advantage
- Can the Added Value framework tell us something
about what gives a firm a competitive advantage - What is competitive advantage?
20Our definition of competitive advantage
- ? Competitive alternatives guarantee
appropriation above next-best alternative (in the
context of the firm liquidation value)
Firms Appropriation
Total Surplus
Value tocompetitors
Aggregate End-User Value less Economic
Resource Cost
Appropriation through super-competitive means
(bargaining)
Appropriation guaranteed by competition
Appropriation available from next-best alternative
21Example 1 Pure Bargaining
- Suppose you have one firm, F1, and one buyer, B1.
- The firm can produce 1 unit at zero cost
- The buyer only wants to buy 1 unit with WTP 1
- F1 and B1 both have AVs of 1
- But the most F1 can guarantee itself through
competition is 0. - E.g., B1 makes a TIOLI offer to F1
22Example 2 Pure Competition
- Outside options
- B1 can buy product from another for 0.50.
- F1 can liquidate assets for 0.50
- TS WTP WTS 0
- Minimum F1 can guarantee itself is 0.50 which is
equal to its (new) WTS - No competitive advantage.
23Example 3 Capacity Constraints
- F1 has one unit of capacity
- B1 and B2 value one unit each at 1
- Outcome
- F1 sells to one buyer
- Can guarantee itself a price of 1 as B1 and B2
compete with one another - F1 has a competitive advantage
24Example 4 No capacity constraints
- F1 can produce 2 or more units
- B1 and B2 value one unit each at 1
- Outcome
- F1 sells to both buyers
- Cannot guarantee a profit above 0.
- F1 does not have a competitive advantage
25Summary
- Competitive advantage means you can appropriate
surplus even if you are not a good negotiator. - Need positive AV to appropriate surplus through
bargaining - Positive AV is no guarantee of appropriating
surplus - Need also to limit the AV of others and create
competition - If others AV is limited then have a competitive
advantage
26Monopoly
- What is a monopoly and is it bad?
27What is a monopoly?
- A monopoly is a market with a single producer.
- All of the substitutable products are controlled
by the same player.
28Examples
- Trains
- Water service
- Australia Post?
- Large employer in a small town
- Quality monopolies Sony Trinitron, Nintendo
Entertainment System - Microsoft
29Its All in the Cards
- I have 10 red cards
- 10 students each have 1 black card
- A red card and a black card together are worth
10 (paid by the Dean) - Who will get what?
30Its Mostly in the Cards
- We get another chance to play the game
- But I find there are 3 red cards missing
- Pie is smaller by 30
- Is everyone worse off?
31Application Several Customers
- Assume that there is a monopolist seller and
three buyers. - Also assume that there is sufficient capacity to
cover all three customers. - Sellers costs are 2 per unit.
- Each buyer has a WTP of 8.
32Surplus Created
- What is total surplus in this market?
-
8 - 2 8 - 2 8 - 2
Produce sell
Surplus 3 x 6 18
Seller and buyers
No trade
0
If the seller has capacity to produce 3 (or more)
units, does it capture all of the surplus?
33Added Value of a Buyer
- What is the Added Value of Buyer 1?
8 - 2 8 - 2 8 - 2
Sell to 1
AV1 18 - 12 6
Seller and buyers
Dont sell to 1
8 - 2 8 - 2
If the seller has capacity to produce 3 (or more)
units, each buyer has an added value of 6?
34Value Created
- AV of each buyer 6
- AV of monopolist 18
- ? What is the range that the price of goods can
take, in each transaction? - The monopolist derives no bargaining power from
monopoly its like one buyer facing one seller,
for each unit. - ? If prices split the difference, the price will
be 5 and the monopolist will earn 9 3 ? 5 -
3 ?2
8
2
35Limited Supply
- Now suppose that the monopolist can only produce
two units. Cost per unit is still 2. - What is total value in this market?
- (8 - 2) 2 12
- What is the added value of a buyer?
- (8 - 2) x 2 (8 - 2) x 2 0!
- the Added Value of buyers has fallen drastically
- According to the core, the monopolist may earn
12 rather than 9.
36Competition Among Buyers
- Potential competition from buyer 3
- 3 is the excluded buyer (s)he would like to
replace 1 or 2 - If either 1 or 2 leave the game, the seller can
still sell to 3 - No buyer is needed to sell a unit each buyer
has zero added value. - However, the presence of excluded buyer 3 is very
valuable to the monopolist she pushes 1 and 2s
added value to zero, and they earn less.
37CORE Bargaining
- CORE bargaining players never get more than
their added value - ? What do the buyers get if monopolist sells 2
units to 3 buyers, each with WTP of 8?
- Any one buyer has zero added value if he does
not buy from the monopolist, another buyer will - ? get nothing
- ? P ? 8
38How much capacity?
- Usual trade-off is about uncertainty or
variability in sales - Underbuild - lose sales
- Overbuild - pay for unused capacity
- Added-value trade-off
- Underbuild - limit customers added value
- Overbuild - every customer is powerful
39Good vs Bad Monopoly
- Bad monopoly power refers to the practice of
firms restricting output (or otherwise destroying
value) in order to diminish buyers added value. - If a monopolist can capture most of the value
without destructive strategies, this is bad for
its buyers, but good for society. - Name some good and bad monopolies
40Water and Diamonds
- Nothing is more useful than water but it will
purchase scarce anything scarce anything can be
had in exchange for it. A diamond, on the
contrary, has scarce any value in use but a very
great quantity of other goods may frequently be
had in exchange for it. - Adam Smith, Wealth of Nations, 1776.
- In 1776, diamonds were relatively rare.
41Why are diamonds so expensive?
- Relative scarcity caused high value
- Created incentives to find new deposits. This
was done over the next two centuries. - There is now an abundance of diamonds.
- Why do they cost so much? DeBeers ...
42The DeBeers Monopoly
- Almost all of the worlds diamonds sold through
DeBeers distribution system or Central Selling
Organization (including Russia). - DeBeers restricts supply invites a selected
number of dealers. If they try and speculate they
are not invited back. - DeBeers manages demand through marketing.
- How much longer will the monopoly persist?
43Conditions for Monopoly Power
- When can a firm exercise monopoly power?
- Credibly restrict output (DeBeers)
- Reputation for output reductions (Disney)
- Insufficient plant (Nintendo)
- When cant a firm exercise monopoly power?
- Banking, unions
44Lessons for a monopoly
- A monopoly needs to consider the costs and
benefits of limiting supply - Benefits
- Get bigger slice of the pie
- Prestige value
- May gain free publicity
- May encourage customers to buy slower moving
parts of range
45Lessons for a monopoly
- A monopoly needs to consider the costs and
benefits of limiting supply - Costs
- Reduces total pie
- May effect customer relationship and future sales
- May create general buyer ill will
- Leaves a hole in the market that may encourage
entry
46Multiple buyers and sellers
- Three sellers, 1, 2 and 3,
- Capacities one unit only
- Costs shown
- BATNAs 0
- Three buyers, A and B and C,
- Each buyer views sellers products as identical
- But, they have different WTPs
- So, A will pay up to 7 for a unit of product
from any firm - Buyers value 1 unit only
47Surplus-maximising deal
- Figure this out using marginal thinking
- Does it create surplus to produce one unit?
- Arrange value-maximising transaction
- In this case, it is Seller 1 and Buyer B 7
- If so, does it create more surplus to produce a
second unit? - Here there are only 3 units otherwise can keep
going - Useful approach Graph WTP in descending and WTS
in ascending order
48WTP and WTS with many buyers and sellers
- It is surplus-maximising for
- A and B to produce and sell two units to 1 and 2
- 3 and C do not transact
10
B
8
A
S3
6
C
4
S2
2
S1
Quantity
49Surplus V
1 sells to B surplus 7 2 sells to A surplus
3 V 10
10
B
8
A
3
6
C
4
2
2
1
50Competitive Distribution (CD)
- How do you find a competitive distribution?
- (Feasibility) Maximise surplus
- (Stability) Ensure that each coalition is given
sufficient value - Could use linear programming (through Excel)
- Or rely on market clearing prices
51Easier to graph and use market-clearing prices
- Prices are market-clearing when they result in
- No excess supply (too many sellers)
- No excess demand (too many buyers)
- In this setup, market-clearing prices generate
competitive distributions!
52Market clearing prices ? CD
- At a price of 6,
- distribution of value is
Feasibility Satisfied?1 ?2 ?3 ?A ?B
?C 10
A few stability requirements
Actual payoffs ?
53Market-clearing prices
- MCP ? CD in this special case
- Sequence of bilateral deals (no market depth
i.e., suppliers, distributors) - Homogeneous goods, heterogeneous agents
- Any price between 5 and 6 generates a CD
- At 5 (lowest competitive price)
- Buyers appropriate their highest competitive
value - Sellers appropriate their lowest
- At 6 (highest competitive price)
- Buyers appropriate their lowest competitive value
- Sellers appropriate their highest
- Important the maximum surplus an agent can
appropriate is not always equal to their added
value - If other agents have sufficiently attractive
alternatives to dealing with you, attaining your
added value may not be possible - Using market-clearing prices in this setup always
gives accurate answers regarding the range of
surplus an agent can attain - Check to see that at a price above 6 or below
5, the implied CD is no longer competitive
54Outcome with multiple buyers and sellers
- Result Competition from the excluded buyer and
seller limits range of possible prices - If either buyer pays more than 6, excluded
seller 3 will jump in with an offer to sell for a
little less - ? price will be pushed down below 6
- If any seller gets less than 5, excluded buyer C
will jump in with an offer to pay a little more - ? price will be pushed up above 5.
- ? buyers will be paying similar prices (i.e.,
between 5 6) - This is different from the result with a
monopolist - With a monopolist, buyers can pay different
prices, based on their WTP - But with competition, the presence of excluded
sellers puts a ceiling on prices
55Perfectly competitive market
- Same setup as before, with a small change to
buyer C - This market is perfectly competitive!
- To demonstrate, show that there is one market
clearing price! - The resulting CD is unique
56Graphical analysis
Feasibility Satisfied?1 ?2 ?3 ?A ?B
?C 10
Only one market clearing price!
New Stability requirements
B
9
?B 3
A
?3 0
7
?A 1
3
6 5
?2 2
?1 4
C
?C 0
Actual payoffs ?
4
2
2
1
57Interesting
Compare added values with CD in perfectly
competitive market
B
9
?B 3
A
?3 0
7
?A 1
3
6 5
?2 2
?1 4
C
?C 0
4
2
2
1
58Useful fact adding up ? perfect comp.
- Any time the avs add up to V
- The market is perfectly competitive
- In the unique CDV, every agent gets exactly their
av - In such situations, agents are full
appropriators - Each agent gets exactly what he contributes
- CDV entirely determined by competitive forces
- PCM does not imply zero economic profit!
- It can be that all agents get zero surplus
- But it is not necessarily so
- This property holds for any unstructured,
multi-party bargaining situation (i.e., of the
type described in this lecture not just the
special case of bilateral homogeneous goods most
recently discussed above)
59Understanding undergraduate SD
- As more and more buyers and sellers join the
market, there is less and less gap between the
WTP of different buyers and the WTS of different
sellers - Lining up the buyers according to their WTP
starts to look like a smooth line, not a
staircase - With many buyers sellers, there is almost no
variation in the possible prices that can be
negotiated - If a seller tries to get a higher price, lots of
sellers willing to sell for less - If a buyer tries to get a lower price, lots of
buyers willing to pay more - ? the law of one price in a big market,
most transactions take place at very similar
prices. - Ex Foreign exchange markets
60WTP and WTS with 5 buyers and 5 sellers
61WTP and WTS with many buyers and sellers
- With many buyers sellers, there is almost no
variation in the possible prices that can be
negotiated
At a deeper level, the law of one price is
really an implication of perfect competition,
which does not require huge markets to obtain!
62Summary
- Examining multilateral bargaining requires
careful quantitative analysis - Can use some rules (e.g., market clearing) to
sometimes simplify the problem - The main interest is in what actions might change
negotiations