Chapter 10 Applications to Natural Resources - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

1 / 38
About This Presentation
Title:

Chapter 10 Applications to Natural Resources

Description:

Two kinds of natural resource models: (i)renewable resources such as fish, food, timber,etc. ... completely uncontrolled. Fishing effort tends to reach ... – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:56
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 39
Provided by: Varghes4
Learn more at: https://www.utdallas.edu
Category:

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: Chapter 10 Applications to Natural Resources


1
Chapter 10 Applications to Natural Resources
  • Objective
  • Optimal management and utilization of natural
  • resources.
  • Two kinds of natural resource models
  • (i)renewable resources such as fish, food,
    timber,etc.,
  • Section 10.2 an optimal forest thinning
    model.
  • (ii)nonrenewable or exhaustible resources such as
  • petroleum, minerals, etc.
  • Section 10.3 an exhaustible resource model.

2
10.1 The Sole Owner Fishery Resource Model
  • 10.1.1 The Dynamics of Fishery Model
  • Notation and terminology is due to Clark (1976)
  • ? the discount rate,
  • x(t) the biomass of fish population at time t
    ,
  • g(x) the natural growth function,
  • u(t) the rate of fishing effort at time t 0
    ? u ? U,
  • q the catchability coefficient,
  • p the unit price of landed fish,
  • c the unit cost of effort.

3
  • Assume growth function g is differentiable and
  • concave,
  • where X denotes the carrying capacity, i.e., the
  • maximum sustainable fish biomass.
  • The model equation due to Gordon(1954) and
  • Schaefer(1957) is
  • The instantaneous profit rate is
  • From (10.1) and (10.2), it follows that x will
    stay in the
  • closed interval 0? x ? X provided x0 is in the
    same
  • interval.

4
  • An open access fishery is one in which
    exploitation is
  • completely uncontrolled. Fishing effort tends to
    reach
  • an equilibrium, called bionomic equilibrium, at
    the level
  • at which total revenue equals total cost. In
    other words,
  • the so-called economic rent is completely
    dissipated.
  • From (10.3) and (10.2),
  • We assume . The economic basis for
    this result
  • is as follows If the fishing effort is
    made, then
  • total costs exceed total revenues so that at
    least some
  • fishermen will lose money, and eventually some
    will
  • drop out, thus reducing the level of fishing
    effort. On the
  • other hand, if fishing effort is
    made, then total

5
  • revenues exceed total costs, thereby attracting
  • additional fishermen, and increasing the fishing
    effort.
  • 10.1.2 The Sole Owner Model
  • The bionomic equilibrium solution obtained from
    the
  • open access fishery model usually implies severe
  • biological overfishing. Suppose a fishing regular
  • agency is established to improve the operation of
    the
  • fishing industry. The objective of the agency is
  • subject to (10.2).

6
10.1.3 Solution By Greens Theorem
  • Solving (10.2) for u we obtain
  • Substitute into (10.3), to obtain
  • where
  • where B is a sate trajectory in (x,t ) space,
    t?0,?).

7
  • Let denote a simple closed curve in the (x,t
    ) space
  • surrounding a region R in the space. Then,
  • let
  • rewrite (10.11) as
  • As in Section 7.2.2 and 7.2.4, the turnpike level
    is
  • given by

8
  • The required second-order condition is
  • Let be the unique solution to (10.12)
    satisfying the
  • second-order condition.
  • The corresponding value of the control which
    would
  • maintain the fish stock level at is
    . In
  • Exercise 10.2 you are asked to show that
  • and also that . In Figure 10.1 optimal
  • trajectories are shown for two different initial
    values

9
Figure 10.1 Optimal Policy for the Sole Owner
Fishery Model
10
  • Economic interpretation
  • where
  • The interpretation of ?(x) is that it is the
    sustainable
  • economic rent at fish stock level x.This can be
    seen by
  • substituting into (10.3),
    where
  • obtained using (10.12), is the fishing effort
    required to
  • maintain the fish stock at level x. Suppose we
    have
  • attained the equilibrium level given by
    (10.2), and
  • suppose we reduce this level to by
    using fishing
  • effort of .

11
  • The immediate marginal revenue, MR, from this
    action
  • is
  • However, this causes a decrease in the
    sustainable
  • economic rent which equals
  • Over the infinite future, the present value of
    this
  • stream, i.e., the marginal cost MC, is
  • Equating MR and MC, we obtain (10.13), which is
    also
  • (10.12).

12
  • When the discount rate is zero, equation (10.13)
  • reduces to
  • so that it will give the equilibrium fish stock
    level
  • for ? 0, which maximizes the instantaneous
    profit rate
  • ?(x) . This is called in economics the golden
    rule level.
  • When ? ?, we can assume that ?'(x) is bounded.
  • From (10.13) we have pqx- c 0, which gives
  • The latter is the bionomic equilibrium attained
    in the
  • open access fishery solution see (10.4).

13
  • The sole owner solution satisfies
    . If
  • we regard a government regulatory agency as the
    sole
  • owner responsible for operating the fishery at
    level ,
  • then it can impose restrictions, such as gear
  • regulations, catch limitations,etc., which
    increase the
  • fishing cost c.
  • If c is increased to the level , then the
    fishery can
  • be turned into an open access fishery subject to
    those
  • regulations, and it will attain the bionomic
    equilibrium
  • at level .

14
10.2 An Optimal Forest Thinning Model
  • 10.2.1 The Forestry Model
  • t0 the initial age of the forest,
  • ? the discount rate,
  • x(t) the volume of usable timber in the forest
    at time t,
  • u(t) the rate of thinning at time t,
  • p the constant price per unit volume of
    timber,
  • c the constant cost per unit volume of
    thinning,
  • f(x) the growth function, which is positive,
    concave,
  • and has a unique maximum at xm we assume
    f(0)0,
  • g(t) the growth coefficient which is positive,
  • decreasing function of time.

15
  • Form for the forest growth is
  • where ? is a positive constant. f is concave in
    the
  • relevant range and that . They use
    the growth
  • coefficient of the form
  • where a and b are positive constants.
  • The forest growth equation is
  • Objective function is
  • The state and control constrains are
  • (10.16) implies no replanting.

16
10.2.2 Determination of Optimal Thinning
  • Forestry problem has a natural ending at a time T
    for
  • which x(T )0.
  • To get the singular control solution triple
    , we
  • must observe that and will be functions
    of time.
  • From (10.19), we have
  • which is constant so that . From (10.18),

17
  • Then, from (10.13),
  • gives the singular control.
  • Since g(t) is a decreasing function of time, it
    is clear
  • from Figure 10.2 that is a decreasing
    function of
  • time, and then by (10.22), . It is
    also clear that
  • at time , given by
  • which in view of f(0)1, gives
  • For ,the optimal control at t0 will
    be the impulse
  • cutting to bring the level from to
    instantaneously.
  • To complete the infinite horizon solution, set

18
Figure 10.2 Singular Usable Timber Volume
19
Figure 10.3 Optimal Policy for the Forest
Thinning Model when
20
10.2.3 A Chain of Forests Model
  • Similar to the chain of machines model of Section
    9.3.
  • We shall assume that successive plantings,
    sometimes
  • called forest rotations, take place at equal
    intervals.
  • This is similar to the assumption (9.39) employed
    in the
  • machine replacement problem treated in Sethi
    (1973b).
  • Let T be the rotation period, during the nth
    rotation, the
  • dynamics of the forest is given by (10.13) with
  • t?(n-1)T,nT and x (n-1)T0.

21
Figure 10.4 Optimal Policy for the Chain of
Forests Model when
22
  • Case 1
  • Note that in the second
    integral is an
  • impulse control bringing the forest from value
    to 0
  • by a clearcutting operation differentiate
    (10.25) with
  • respect to T, equate the result to zero,
  • If the solution T lies in , keep it
    otherwise set .

23
  • Case 2
  • In the Vidale-Wolfe advertising model of Chapter
    7, a
  • similar case occurs when T is small the solution
    for
  • x(T) is obtained by integrating (10.13) with u 0
    and
  • x0 0. Let this solution be denoted as x(t).
    Here
  • (10.24) becomes
  • differentiate (10.27) and equate to zero, we get
  • If the solution lies in the interval keep
    it otherwise
  • set The optimal value T can be obtained
    by
  • computing J(T) from both cases and selecting
  • whichever is larger.

24
Figure 10.5 Optimal Policy for the Chain of
Forests Model when
25
10.3 An Exhaustible Resource Model
  • We discuss a simple model taken from
    Sethi(1979a).
  • This paper analyzes optimal depletion rates by
  • maximizing a social welfare function which
    involves
  • consumers surplus and producers surplus with
  • various weights. Here we select a model having
    the
  • equally weighted criterion function.

26
  • 10.3.1 Formulation of the Model
  • Assume that at a high enough price, say?p , a
  • substitute, preferably renewable, will become
    available.
  • p(t) the price of the resource at time t ,
  • q f(p) is the demand function,i.e., the
    quantity
  • demanded at price p
    and
  • where is
    the price at which
  • the substitute completely replaces the
    resource. A
  • typical graph of the demand function is
    shown in
  • Figure 10.6,
  • c G(q) is the cost function G(0)0, G(q)gt0
    for q gt0,
  • Ggt0, and G? 0 for q ? 0, and G(0)lt .
    the latter
  • assumption makes it possible for the
    producers to
  • make positive profit at a price p below
    ,

27
  • Q(t) the available stock or reserve of the
    resource at
  • time t ,
  • ? the social discount rate, ? gt0 ,
  • T the horizon time, which is the latest time
    at which
  • the substitute will become available
    regardless of
  • the price of the natural resource, T gt0.
  • Let
  • for which it is obvious that
  • Let
  • denote the profit function of the producers, i.e,
    the
  • producers surplus.

28
  • Let be the smallest price at which is
    nonnegative.
  • Assume further that is a concave function
    in the
  • range as shown in Figure 10.7. In the
    figure the
  • point pm indicates the price which maximizes
    .
  • We also define
  • as the consumers surplus, i.e., the area shown
    shaded
  • in Figure 10.6. This quantity represents the
    total excess
  • amount consumers would be willing to pay,i.e,
  • consumers pay pf(p), while they would be willing
    to pay
  • Note pdq pf'(p)dp

29
Figure 10.6 The Demand Function
30
  • The instantaneous rate of consumers surplus and
  • producers surplus is the sum .
    Let denote
  • the maximum of this sum, i.e., solves
  • In Exercise 10.14 you will be asked to show that
  • The optimal control problem is
  • subject to
  • and . Recall that the sum
    is
  • concave in p .

31
Figure 10.7 The Profit Function
32
10.3.2 Solution by the Maximum Principle
33
  • The right-hand side of (10.41) is strictly
    negative
  • because flt0 , and G ? 0 by assumption. We
    remark
  • that using (10.32) and (10.39),
    and hence the
  • second-order condition for of (10.32) to give
    the
  • maximum of H is verified.
  • Case 1 The constraint Q(T) ? 0 is not binding
  • ?(t) ? 0 so that

34
  • Case 2
  • To obtain the solution requires finding a value
    of ?(T)
  • such that
  • where
  • The time t, if it is less than T, is the time at
    which
  • which, when solved for t, gives the second
    argument
  • of (10.45).

35
  • One method to obtain the optimal solution is to
    define
  • as the longest time horizon during which the
  • resource can be optimally used. Such a must
    satisfy
  • and therefore,
  • Subcase 2a The optimal control is
  • Clearly in this subcase, t and
  • in Figure 10.8.

36
  • Subcase 2b Here the optimal price
    trajectory is
  • where ?(T) is to be obtained from the
    transcendental
  • equation
  • in Figure 10.9

37
Figure 10.8 Optimal Price Trajectory for
38
Figure 10.9 Optimal Price Trajectory for
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)
About PowerShow.com