Title: Education, Productivity and WellBeing
1 Measuring Well-Being and Societal Progress Milan,
JRC/OECD Workshop Series
- Education, Productivity and Well-Being
- Prof. Albert Tuijnman
- EIB Projects Directorate
6
2PURPOSETo comment on the complex
relationships between initial education, lifelong
learning for adults, individual economic returns
and self-perceived well-beingSTRUCTURE1.
Measurement issues2. Findings of a Swedish
longitudinal study3. Policy implications4.
Education and productivity revisited5. Broad
policy implications
3Recurrent Education Well-Being
- Ph.D. thesis published in 1989 Recurrent
Education, Earnings and Well-Being A
Longitudinal Analysis of a Cohort of Swedish
Men Acta Universitatis Stockholmiensis.
Stockholm Almqvist Wiksell. - Aims of the study
- 1. Measurement of cumulative learning over the
life-span - 2. Measurement of life-time earnings (until age
55) - 3. Measurement of self-perceived well-being at
age 56 - 4. Establishing individual economic returns to
recurrent - education at age 56
- 5. Establishing causal network between
education, earnings - and elf-perceived quality of life at age 56
4LATENT INDEPENDENT VARIABLES
- Study used a longitudinal data set spanning
almost 50 years. A structural equation model was
developed, with the following latent independent
variables - 1. Home Background - Father education Age 10
(1938) - - Mother education
- - Father occupation
- - Mother occupation
- - Family income
-
- 2. IQ Standardised Score - Sub-tests A-D Age 10
-
- 3. Youth Education - Years of schooling Ages
15-25 - - Highest obtained level
-
- 4. IQ Standardised Score - Sub-tests A-D Ages
20-25 - 5. Occupational Status Treiman Prestige
Index Ages 26-55
5MEDIATING AND DEPENDENT VARIABLES
-
- Mediating Variables
- 6. Adult Education Cumulative retrospective
measures Ages 26-55 - Four indices
- Independent Variables
- 7. Income Gross declared income from work Ages
26-55 - Annual measure, supplied by the tax
- authorities
- 8. Self-perceived Index based on 12 quality of
life Age 56 - Well-being (QoL) items
-
6KEY FINDINGS
- 1. Net wage effect of initial education
controlling for HB and IQ1-2 peaked at around
ages 38-44 without the measure of cumulative
adult education in the model and at ages 28-32
with adult education specified. -
- 2. Net wage effect of initial education
increasingly mediated by cumulative adult
education and training. -
- 3. Highest obtained level of education
(attainment) much more robust predictor of
life-time earnings than years of schooling - 4. No significant effect of initial ecucation on
QoL at age 56 Weak effects of OCC on QoL
inconsistent and weak effect of earnings on QoL
Weak but significant effect of recurrent
education on QoL, but causation unclear.
7THEORETICAL AND POLICYRAMIFICATIONS
- Theory
- Empirical support for screening theory
- Empirical support for human capital theory
- Empirical support for recurrent education theory
(subsequently relabeled as lifelong learning
theory) - Policy
- OECD education indicators (INES, IALS, EAG, EPA)
- OECD support for quantitative education expansion
- OECD support for lifelong learning policies
- OECD focus on knowledge and basic skills (PISA)
8EDUCATION PRODUCTIVITY
- Prof. Alison Wolfs (provocative) Statement
- Productivity effects of education are exaggerated
- 1. Microeconomic evidence Private retuns
(8-12) - Social returns (6-8)
- 2. Macroeconomic evidence Labour productivity
(3) - Growth effects (ideas, innovation)
- One additional year of schooling raises PR/SR by
6-8 - One additional year of schooling raised total
factor productivity by almost the same amount
(6-8)
9- The evidence on the micro- and macro-economic
returns to increased years schooling is rather
consistent both across countries and over time.
But how valid and reliable is the evidence? - Are productivity effects of schooling
overestimated? - YES, for two main reasons
- VALIDITY - ACLEV ? Years of schooling
- - No controls for HB and IQ
- - Education ? Skills
- - Crucial omitted variable Lifelong learning
for adults
10- RELIABILITY - Cross section data sets, most
often from 1960s to mid-1990s do not reflect
the recent quantitative - expansion of education systems
- - Cumulative lifelong learning for adults
is known to - mediate the diminishing effects of schooling
over - the life-span
- - Some of the schooling effect is direct and
some is - indirect (externalities)
- - Education impacts on other variables
relevant for - productivity and economic growth
- 1. Education begets education
- 2. Intergenerational effects of education
- 3. Health and life expectancy
- 4. Labour force participation
- 5. Political awareness, civic engagement
- 6. Effect on the productivity of other persons
11IN SUMMARY
- Qualified support for Professor Wolfs assertion
that the productivity effects of initial
schooling are over-estimated - Support, at least partially, for Screening Theory
- - But also support for Human Capital Theory, but
only in the perspective of recurrent education
and lifelong learning.
12CONCLUSIONS FOR POLICY
- Past returns are not necessarily a good guide to
future returns - Expansion of initial schooling (years) cannot
continue indefinitely, at some point there will
be diminishing, even negative returns - Initial formal education Focus should shift
from quantitative expansion to more quality
enhancement with a focus on productivity-relevant
competencies and skills - LLL will remain important and needs to be given
strong continued support. But difficult maintain
high policy interest over time. Thus important to
occasionally reinvent the concept - Strengthen the indirect productivity effects of
initial education through complementary actions
in innovation, health and civic engagement
(social capital)
13http//www.eib.orgmoney doesnt make you happy