Title: Perfect Deterrence: Implications and Conclusions
1Perfect Deterrence Implications and Conclusions
- Frank C. Zagare
- Department of Political Science
- University at Buffalo, SUNY
- Buffalo, NY 14260
2Perfect Deterrence Theory
- Aim is to specify necessary and sufficient
conditions - Perfect Deterrence Theory grows out of joint work
first with Kugler and later with Kilgour - It focuses on parity relationships which Organski
and Kugler show is necessary for major power
conflicts
3Critical Questions
- When does deterrence work?
- When do limited conflicts occur?
- When is a conflict spiral likely?
- What are the best crisis management strategies?
- What defense postures are efficacious deterrents?
4Deterrence Theory An Alternative
Conceptualization
- Deterrence works best when the underlying
structure of the game resembles Prisoners
Dilemma - In PD, players have mutually credible threats
- In a sequentially played game with PD-like
preferences, the status quo is the unique subgame
perfect, Pareto-efficient, Nash equilibrium
5Perfect Deterrence Theory (1)
- Explores the strategic implications of credible
threats given capable threats (i.e., parity - Unlike Classical Deterrence Theory, Perfect
Deterrence Theory allows the credibility of end
game threats to vary - Subsumes conditions presumed by Powell, Gauthier,
Brams, etc.
6Perfect Deterrence Theory (2)
- Applies as well to nuclear and non-nuclear
situations - More useful for examining extended deterrence
situations than standard models - Logically consistent and empirically plausible
7Capability A Necessary Condition
- Capability is the ability to hurt.
- In Perfect Deterrence Theory, capability emerges
as a necessary condition for deterrence success - The lack of a capable threat is sufficient for
deterrence failure - Contrary to some theorists, a capable threat is
not sufficient for success
8Deterrence Success and Failure Sufficient
Conditions
- Deterrence can break down in a number of ways,
even when a Defenders threat is capable - Multiple equilibria almost always exist, making
sufficient conditions for deterrence success
almost impossible to specify - Deterrence is, therefore, tenuous almost
anything can happen under any conditions
9What Makes Deterrence Success More Likely (1)
- A highly valued status quo is a major determinant
of deterrence success - Neglected in all studies of deterrence breakdown
(e.g., Lebow and Stein) and underplayed in most
empirical studies (e.g., Huth and Russett) - Neglect introduces a case selection bias
10What Makes Deterrence Success More Likely (2)
- Credibility is the critical variable. It is,
however, neither necessary nor sufficient for
deterrence to succeed. Deterrence can succeed
when a defenders threat lacks credibility and
fail when it does not.
11What Makes Deterrence Success More Likely (3)
- In Perfect Deterrence Theory credibility is
defined in terms of a players belief that its
opponent prefers to carry out a threat - Believability Credibility Rationality
- Rationality subgame perfection
12Credibility (1)
- Defenders credibility is an important
determinant of deterrence success - Extended deterrence is most likely when a
defenders sub-strategic and strategic level
threats are highly credible - But a challengers credibility may actually be
the key
13Credibility (2)
- When challengers threat is not very credible,
defender will be undeterred from resisting,
regardless of its credibility - In consequence, deterrence succeeds because
challengers threat lacks credibility, not
because of the characteristics of defenders
threat - Empirical studies that focus on the
characteristics of a defenders threat miss this
important dimension of extended deterrence
relationships
14Major Finding of Incomplete Information Models
- The conditions of war and peace generally exist
simultaneously - Parity is dangerous so dont proliferate
- Overkill capability has limits
- Commitment tactics should be avoided
15Major Finding of Incomplete Information Models
(continued)
- Conditionally cooperative stratagems (tit-for-tat
policies) appear to be the most efficacious
mechanisms for avoiding conflict and war - Defense postures like Massive Retaliation that
depend entirely on escalatory threats are
ineffective deterrents. And when Challenger is
likely hard, they are useless.
16Major Findings (continued)
- Limited conflicts and even escalation spirals are
low probability events. They are outcomes that
are not anticipated by the players rather they
are the consequence of gambles taken by
players who have incomplete information about
their opponents preferences (intentions).
17Perfect Deterrence Theory Empirical Expectations
(1)
- Initiators of interstate conflict should
generally be stronger than their opponents (Bueno
de Mesquita) - Satisfaction with the status quo should be
associated with deterrence success (Reed,
Rousseau et al.)
18Perfect Deterrence Theory Empirical Expectations
(2)
- Tit-for-tat strategies should be associated with
increased probability of deterrence success
(Huth) - Firm-but-flexible negotiating styles should be
associated with increased probability of
deterrence success (Huth)
19Perfect Deterrence Theory Empirical Expectations
(3)
- Reciprocity should dominate interstate
interactions, as states seek to establish
credible threats (Stimulus-Response Model) - One-sided victories should be the most frequently
observed outcome once deterrence breaks down
(MID-data)
20Perfect Deterrence Theory General Comments(1)
- Converges with best empirical studies
- Speaks to efficacy of various deployment
strategies (i.e., all-or-nothing and limited war
stances) - Specifies conditions for limited conflicts and
escalation spirals - Explains why proliferation is unsafe
21Perfect Deterrence Theory General Comments(2)
- Supports downsizing of forces (i.e., minimum
deterrence) - Consistent with no-first-use deployments
- Consistent with arms reduction initiatives