Title: Licensing and Competition:
1Licensing and Competition FTC/DOJ
Views Presentation to LES Washington, DC
Chapter May 20, 2003 Presented by Walt
Bratic Shirley Webster
2Agenda
- History of Views on IP and Competition
- Overview of FTC/DOJ Hearings
- Patent Pools
- Grantbacks
- Cross-Licenses
- Standard Setting
- Tying
- Refusals to License
3History of Views on IP and Competition
- Early 1900s Patent Rights viewed as paramount,
overcoming all antitrust concerns - Patents a government endorsed exception to
antitrust laws - Market Power inferred from existence of a patent
- This immunity from antitrust scrutiny decreased
over time
4History of Views on IP and Competition
- 1970 Nine No Nos (per se prohibitions)
- Grantbacks
- Royalty payment unrelated to sales volume of
patented product - Patent Pools (Mandatory Package Licensing)
- Tying of unpatented supplies
- Restrictions on sales of unpatented products made
by a patented process - Post-sale restrictions on resale by purchasers of
patented products - Tie-outs (restrictions on licensees ability to
sell products that compete with patented product) - Licensee veto power over licensors grant of
future licenses - Specifying prices a licensee could charge upon
resale of licensed products
5History of Views on IP and Competition
- Current view both patent law and antitrust law
have the goal of encouraging innovation, industry
and competition - 1995 Antitrust Guidelines for the Licensing of
Intellectual Property - Same general antitrust principles applied to IP
as to conduct involving any other form of
property - Intellectual Property NOT assumed to create
market power - Intellectual Property Licensing generally
pro-competitive
6History of Views on IP and Competition
- Rule of Reason Analysis
- Is restraint likely to adversely affect
competition? - If so, do pro-competitive benefits or
efficiencies outweigh anticompetitive effect - What is the relevant product and geographic
market - Market Power the ability to profitably
maintain prices above, or output below,
competitive levels for a significant period of
time.
7Overview of FTC/DOJ Hearings
- Hearings held in 2002 to explore the
interrelationships between competition and patent
policy - Both IP law and antitrust law seek to promote
innovation and enhance consumer welfare but
questions exist as to the proper balance to
achieve goal - Role of the Federal Circuit
8Overview of FTC/DOJ Hearings
- Antitrust Community
- Antitrust Laws eliminate monopolies and
encourage competition - IP Laws reward creators and inventors with
limited monopoly - IP Community
- IP Rights protect investment, encourage RD
- However,
- Patent Thicket Is it a problem?
- Increasing number of patents too many?
9Overview of FTC/DOJ Hearings
- Topics of interest in hearings included
- Interrelationships between competition and patent
policy - Standard setting
- Patent pools
- Cross-licensing
- Unilateral refusals to license
- Proliferation of patents
- Changing scope of patents
- Role of the Federal Circuit
10Patent Pools
11Patent Pool - Definition
- Sometimes referred to as Mandatory Package
Licensing - Agreements among two or more owners of different
items of intellectual property to license third
parties, and one another
12Patent Pools Pro- or Anti-Competitive
- May provide competitive benefits
- One Stop Shopping
- Integrate complementary technologies
- Reduce transaction costs
- Clear blocking position
- Avoid costly infringement litigation
13Patent Pools Pro- or Anti-Competitive
- May restrict competition
- Reduce competition among IP rights within the
pool - Reduce competition between products incorporating
the pooled patents - Reduce innovation among parties to the pool
- Collective price or output restraints may be
deemed unlawful
14- Business Review Letters on Patent Pools
- MPEG-3 June 26, 1997
- DVD (Philips, Sony and Pioneer) December 16,
1998 - DVD (Hitachi, Matsushita, Mitsubishi, Time
Warner, Toshiba, and Victor) June 10, 1999 - 3G November 12, 2002
15Patent Pool -- How to be pro-competitive
- Integrate Complementary Patent Rights
- License Essential Patents
- Necessarily or practically infringed in order to
comply with standard - Determination of essentiality by independent
expert - Open pool to any owner of an essential patent
willing to license on the programs terms and
conditions
16Patent Pool -- How to be pro-competitive
- Retain Independent Patent Expert to Determine
Essentiality - Do Not Restrict Licensing to the Pool
- Allow licensing directly with each entity that
has patents in the patent pool (separately from
pool) - Allow licensing of individual patents (no
requirement to license all patents included in
the pool)
17Patent Pool -- How to be pro-competitive
- Royalty Rates
- Royalty should be small relative to the total
costs of manufacturing the product - Offer fair, reasonable, and non-discriminatory
terms to Licensors and all other licensees of the
pool - Offer most-favored-nations clause to allow
licensee to opt for more favorable royalties
offered another licensee, if licensee agrees to
any additional benefits to Licensor included in
terms and conditions for that royalty rate
18Patent Pool -- How to be pro-competitive
- Grantbacks
- Licensees grantback obligation to be limited to
essential patents - Licensee to grant non-exclusive licenses to
essential patents on fair, reasonable and
non-discriminatory terms - Open pool to any owner of an essential patent
19Cross Licenses
20Cross Licenses
- Considered similar to patent pools
- Many of the same considerations apply in the
analysis of pro- and anti-competitive effects
21Standard Setting
22Examples of Standard Setting Organizations
23- Benefits of Standard Setting
- Consumers more likely to embrace new product
(reluctance to repeat VHS/Beta format problems) - Allows multi-industry coordination of products
- Efficiency in technological advancement as
companies share the risks and costs of new
product development
24- Patent Rights in Standard Setting
- Standards that rely on IP may be argued to
present a danger to competition - Inclusion of a patent in a standard can provide
that technology with market power that it
previously lacked - Refusal to issue standard because only one or a
small number of manufacturers patent or make
product can also limit competition
25Dell Computer
- Unfair competition under Sec. 5 of Federal Trade
Commission Act - Dells failure to disclose patents as required by
a standard-setting groups rules and later
attempt to enforce patent rights against users of
a standard adopted by the group found to be a
violation. - In re Dell Computers 931-0097 (F.T.C. 1996)
- Dell entered into a consent order agreeing not to
seek royalties, but the FTC stated, the relief
in this case should not be read to impose a
general duty to search The order should not be
read to create a general rule that inadvertence
in the standard-setting process provides a basis
for enforcement action.
26Rambus v. Infineon
- Rambus accused of fraud from failure to disclose
patent applications in a meeting of a standard
setting body - Federal Circuit 2003 Duty of disclosure as a
JEDEC participant applies only to patents
containing claims reasonably necessary to
practice proposed standard and arises only when
work formally begins on proposed standard. Duty
to disclose did not cover a participants future
plans or intentions. Since Rambus withdrew from
participation before proposals on the DDR-SDRAM
standard had been submitted and before formal
consideration of the standard had begun, no duty
of disclosure had arisen.
27Rambus FTC Complaint
- Commission challenges a pattern of
anticompetitive acts and practices undertaken by
Rambus over the past decade through which Rambus
has engaged in unfair methods of competition
related to DRAM - Rambuss anticompetitive scheme involved
participating in JEDEC without letting it be
known that Rambus had a patent and patent
applications ultimately adopted in the relevant
standards. Once the standards became widely
adopted, Rambus proceeded to enforce its patents
against companies manufacturing memory products
in compliance with the standard. - This conduct has caused or threatened to cause
substantial harm to competition.
28Tying
29Tying
- Requiring a licensee to purchase or use unwanted
products or services in order to receive a
desired IP license - Concern is projection of market power from
market of licensed IP to other market - There must be a showing of market power for
concerns to arise
30Refusals to License
31Refusals to License
- Courts have held that failure to license a
patent, standing alone, is not an antitrust
violation - Refusals to license can rise to the level of an
antitrust violation if - Part of a scheme to acquire or maintain an
unlawful economic monopoly or - Concerted action among two or more independent
parties
32Summary of Current Positions on Nine No-Nos
33Patent Pools
- May provide competitive benefits
- Integrate complementary technologies
- Reducing transaction costs
- Clearing blocking positions
- Avoid costly infringement litigation
- Can restrict competition
- Reducing incentive to innovate
- Reducing competition within pool
- Reducing competition for pooled patents
34Tying of Unpatented Supplies
- Without a showing that the patent actually
conveys market power, antitrust concerns do not
arise
35Royalties not Reasonably Related to Sales of the
Patented Product
- Royalties based on other measures, such as units
produced by the licensee may be found to be more
efficient - Any antitrust concern depends on the presence of
market power
36Mandatory Grantbacks
- Grantbacks may be pro-competitive and will be
evaluated under a rule of reason - Grantbacks may adversely affect competition if
they reduce the licensees incentives to engage
in RD, and limit incentive to innovate - Whether the licensee has market power in a
relevant market is important to the agencies
analysis
37Licensee Veto Power over Licensors Grant of
Further Licenses
- Absent showing of market power or foreclosure,
this type of restriction may have a net
pro-competitive effect
38Restrictions on Sales of Unpatented Products Made
by Patented Process
- These restrictions are unlikely to raise concerns
to the extent that - the licensee and the licensor would not be actual
or potential competitors absent the licensing
relationship, or - the licensor does not have market power
39Tie-Outs
- Anticompetitive concerns are unlikely to arise
unless patentee has market power in the relevant
market for the patent or patented product, under
the patent misuse statute
40Restraints on Distribution
- Restrictions on single use only label license
or prohibition on resale are subject to Rule of
Reason analysis
41Resale Price Maintenance
- Only one of the Nine No-Nos remaining as a per
se violation - According to Section 5.2 of the IP Licensing
Guidelines, it is per se illegal for a patentee
to fix the minimum resale price for a good that
has been fully sold to dealers.