Title: The economics of nonhorizontal merger guidelines
1The economics of non-horizontal merger guidelines
- Nikos Vettas
- Professor, Athens University of Economics and
Business, Greece and - Member, European Advisory Group in Competition
Policy (Chief Economist Group, DG-Competition) - Research Fellow, Centre for Economic Policy
Research, London - Athens, June 2 2007
2The issue non-horizontal merger guidelines
- Non-horizontal mergers
- - vertical
- - conglomerate
- EU guidelines?
- Compare to Horizontal merger guidelines
- Compare to US non-horizontal guidelines
-
-
3European Commission public consultation
- Draft merger guidelines circulated February 2007
- Public consultation
- - started February 13, 2007
- - ended May 12, 2007
- Commissioner Neelie Kroes providing clear and
predictable guidance for businesses - DG - Enterprise and Industry The
Efficiency-Enhancing Effects of Non-Horizontal
Mergers (RBB Economics report) -
-
4EAGCP preliminary paper (advisory note)
- ? EAGCP (Economic Advisory Group in Competition
Policy) - ? Mergers subgroup
- Marc Ivaldi (University of Toulouse)
- Bruce Lyons (University of East Anglia)
- Monika Schnitzer (University of Munich)
- John Van Reenen (London School of Economics)
- Frank Verboven (University of Leuven)
- Nikos Vettas (Athens University of Economics and
Business) - Xavier Vives (IESE Business School, Barcelona)
- ? First set of (ten) general principles Spring
2006 - First, on key economic differences between
horizontal mergers and NHM. - Second, on what the guidelines should achieve.
- ? Personal views
51. The competitive impact of NHM is fundamentally
different from that of HM.
- The presumption in a horizontal merger is that it
directly leads to increased market power and an
ability to raise prices - If the merging parties have market power, a
horizontal merger will typically remove the
competitive pricing restraints parties place on
each other. - This is not the case for a non-horizontal merger.
- Horizontal mergers are among substitutes,
non-horizontal mergers are among complements. - Enhancing efficiency is expected.
- Principle backed both by economic theory and some
empirical evidence. - The competitive effects of non-horizontal mergers
will depend on characteristics of the situation
examined. - Important NHM parties often have previous
contractual relationships, in which case the
competitive change following a merger will be
muted. Parties to a horizontal merger typically
do not have prior contracts. -
62. NHM have indirect impact on competition.
- A horizontal merger can harm competition by its
direct impact on the incentive to raise price. - A non-horizontal merger has no direct impact on
pricing. - It may still cause competitive harm through a
change in supply or procurement policy, or the
way in which a product range is offered to
consumers. Then, cost or demand of rivals is
affected and their pricing changes. - The merged firm sometimes has the incentive to
soften price competition in the downstream market
in order to protect its upstream profits. This
situation may be difficult to track, since the
downstream firm has no incentives to complain. - The effect of non-horizontal mergers on
competitive conditions tends to be limited, since
NHM parties often have previous contractual
relationship, e.g. that limits buyer or supplier
switching, whereas HM parties usually do not have
prior contract. - Indirect effects of non-horizontal mergers can
potentially impede effective competition, but
they require a particularly careful analysis in
order to justify a likelihood of harm. -
73. Non-horizontal mergers take many forms and
produce a variety of effects.
- There are canonical models for horizontal
merger (Bertrand with differentiated products or
Cournot with homogenous products and capacity
constraints). Much more difficult to analyze
non-horizontal mergers, there are many possible
effects. - The Chicago School (no harm) models for NHM
specify conditions under which there is no loss
of competition due to a non-horizontal merger. - Monopoly profits can be taken only once along a
vertically linked chain - Vertical integration can reduce distortions by
eliminating double marginalization. - Vertical integration often results to production
and organization efficiencies. - Note the same reasoning applies to mergers
between complements. - The Chicago approach relies on particular
assumptions. In practice, the appropriate theory
of competitive harm must be carefully tuned to
the merger in question. -
84. Market power in an existing market is a
pre-requisite for competitive harm from
foreclosure.
- This well-established fact provides an essential
filter for screening out spurious concerts. - Market power is a necessary, but not sufficient
condition for foreclosure. - When there is market power at both stages of the
vertical chain, vertical integration helps to
avoid double marginalization (that often exists
in absence of sophisticated contracts) and thus
results to efficiency gains. - Even in the presence of market power, merging
firms need not have the incentive to take actions
that would reduce the market available to rivals
and even if this is a likely consequence, it need
not result in consumer harm. -
9The main vertical externality double
marginalization
10Remarks
- Double marginalization with linear pricing, we
obtain final prices that are too high for the
final consumers and also for the sellers. - Worse than VI monopoly.
- Distortion increasing with the number of stages
- This problem can be resolved with
- - vertical integration
- - nonlinear pricing a two-part tariff
- Who sets the prices? Bargaining?
- Only problem if market power at both stages.
11Adding horizontal strategic competition
12Multiple downstream
13Common Agency / bottlenecks
14Other structures
155. Stronger efficiency arguments for
non-horizontal mergers than for horizontal
mergers.
- Modern theory of firm and empirical evidence
inform us that firm as an institution exists due
to incomplete contracts and transaction costs,
which make it more efficient to carry out certain
activities coordinated within a firm as opposed
to through markets. - If complete contracts could be written (at low
cost), the need to organize economic activities
within firms would be limited. However, contracts
that specify a precise outcome for each possible
future contingency are too expensive. - The efficient range of activities carried out
within a firm may change over time. A
non-horizontal merger may be efficiency-enhancing.
- The downside of a decision error that prohibits a
merger is likely to be much greater for NHM than
for horizontal mergers. -
16Example specific investments
- Assurance of quantity, quality and time of supply
- Specific production
- Specific assets danger of opportunistic behavior
(hold-up) implies below optimal investment
incentives (Coase, vertical boundaries of the
firm Williamson Grossman-Hart) - Solution? VI? Long-term contracts? Short-term
contracts? - Single sourcing (exclusivity) vs. multiple
sources.
176. NHM Guidelines could enhance the accuracy and
predictability of decisions.
- Major difficulties inherent in writing detailed
guidelines. - Difficulties based on the very nature of
non-horizontal mergers and the multiplicity of
forms they may take. - Difficulties are reflected on the current state
of the academic literature. - Having a suitable set of principles to deal with
NHM is important. - They will contribute towards predictability of
decisions and consistency. - Predictability is important, especially to
businesses and their advisors. - Case handlers need guidance.
- Good guidance will be useful for authorities
beyond DG-Competition. -
187. Guidelines should focus on competitive effects
resulting in benefit or harm to consumers (and
not to competitors).
- Efficiencies that lead to reduction in prices or
to more attractive product offering may lead to
reduction of competitors market share, but are
to be welcomed as consumer benefit. - Elimination of double-marginalization can create
an incentive to reduce customer prices. - Not always a double margin to be eliminated, even
in the presence of imperfect competition, because
parties have an incentive to contract around this
source of inefficiency. - Pre-merger contracts are very relevant and
important in this context. - Depending on the particular type of market
structure under investigation studies, double
marginalization does not necessarily reduce the
profits of the firms involved. -
197. (and not to competitors).
- Particularly important to recognise the benefits
of anticipated customer price reductions because
competitors anticipating lost market share have a
strong incentive to complain loudly to the
Commission. - An expectation of consumer harm needs very
careful support. -
208. Guidelines should indicate the methodology of
analysis and the relevant evidence.
- For actions harmful to consumers, both the
ability and the incentive of merged firms to take
such actions should be established. - Each particular scenario of harm should rely on a
package of pre-requisites, e.g. market share,
product differentiation, feasibility of bundling,
margins. - Other useful information to be considered
existing contracts, sales practices, procurement
methods, natural experiments. - The assessment of the effects of a vertical
merger must not presume consumer harm and then
look for countervailing efficiencies. In other
words, the model used to analyze a vertical
merger must allow for potential efficiencies from
the start and not for competitive harm only. -
219. Guidelines should distinguish more likely
from less likely competitive harm whenever
possible.
- Qualitative guidance may be provided on the
relative risks of different types of harm (e.g.
there is usually far greater concern if
foreclosure results in exit, as opposed to
changes in market share). -
- Safe harbours might be indicated, at least in
relation to the pre-requisite of market power. - If none of the firms involved in a merger has
significant market power in any of the markets,
then there is almost always no need for a
competition authority to scrutinize this
particular merger. - If after a vertical merger the upstream market is
supplied by vertically integrated firms only,
there is a risk that upstream firms could sustain
higher prices for the upstream products, forcing
(not vertically integrated) downstream firms to
raise their final prices. Hence the number of
firms acting in the different markets plays a
crucial role. - Overall, the scale of likelihood should tie
appropriately with the required standard of proof
for the Commission. -
2210. Non-horizontal Guidelines should be
consistent with other Guidelines / Notices /
Green Papers.
- The horizontal merger guidelines can be
interpreted to define existing market power in
the context of a non-horizontal merger case (even
though those guidelines deal directly with
changes to market power, not the existence of
market power). - There might be some important links to Article
82, as firms may find ways to establish vertical
relationships among themselves (e.g. long-term
specific contracts) that possibly replicate part
of what would be achieved via a merger. - There should also be consistency with notices on
vertical restraints. -
23Concluding remarks
- On the role of guidelines.
- On the role of competition policy (in the general
mix of economic policy). - Competition, free market!
- Rules to be clear and application of policy
should be transparent, consistent, efficient and
predictable. - Regulatory cost as an entry cost.
- Entry! Innovation!
-