Title: The Sustainability of Health Spending Growth
1The Sustainability of Health Spending Growth
- Glenn Follette
- Louise Sheiner
- Federal Reserve Board
2Historically, spending growth on health has
exceeded that of consumption
3Health Spending Projections
- Since 1970, per capita health spending has grown
an average of 2-1/2 percentage points faster than
per capita GDP. - Obviously, health spending cannot continue to
grow faster than consumption (or GDP) forever. - Until 2001, Medicare Trustees assumed per capita
health care spending growth would slow to the
rate of per capita GDP growth. - Since 2001, Trustees have assumed that per capita
health care spending growth would slow to a rate
1 percentage point faster than per capita GDP.
This has been called the assumption of 1
percentage point excess cost growth.
4Sustainability of Excess Cost Growth from a
Macroeconomic Perspective
- Any rate of excess cost growth will eventually
crowd out all of GDP and will be unsustainable. - One rationale for the Trustees assumptions for
the next 75 years is that, even with such cost
growth, real per capita non-health consumption
continues to grow, although slower than per
capita GDP. No absolute crowd-out of non-health
consumption. - Note that what matters for real crowd-out is the
share of health spending in consumption - In particular, crowd-out occurs when the share of
health spending in consumption is equal to the
ratio of the growth rate of income divided by the
growth rate of health spending.
51 percent excess cost growth and 1.5 percent per
capita GDP growth, crowd-out starts to occur when
health spending reaches 60 of consumption
6With 1.5 percent excess cost growth, crowd-out
starts when health spending reaches 50 of
consumption.
7With 2.0 percent excess cost growth, crowd-out
begins at 43 of consumption.
8Crowding out criteria suggests 1 percent excess
growth is upper bound over the century
- Under baseline macroeconomic projections, health
spending reaches 40 of consumption by 2080 just
getting close to real crowd-out. - With 1.5 percent excess cost growth, health
spending would reach 67 of consumption
crowd-out has begun. - With 2 percent excess cost growth, health
spending would reach 93 of consumption
non-health consumption is declining rapidly.
9Sustainability of Excess Cost Growth from a More
Microeconomic Perspective
- On average, real consumption continues to grow
even with 1 percent excess cost growth. But, is
this true across groups? - Low-income might already spend a larger share of
income on health spending, which would lead to
earlier crowd out. - Elderly or others with high medical expenses
might also already have larger share of income on
health spending. - Projection of 1 percent excess cost growth
assumes that only force driving health care cost
growth in future will be exogenous technological
growth. - Implicitly assumes that insurance markets and
public sector involvement in health care remain
stable. Is this reasonable? Or will increases
in health spending itself engender changes in
public and private insurance?
10Health Spending by Income Quintile
11Health Spending as a Share of Income
12Private health spending as a share of income has
been relatively flat
13(No Transcript)
14Simulations
- We took 2002 data of the distribution of income
and public and private health spending for
elderly and non-elderly - We projected them forward to 2080 using 1 percent
excess growth, maintaining 2002 public share of
health spending adjusted for Medicare drug
benefit
15Simulation Results
- Under 1 percent excess cost growth assumption,
private shares of spending increase over time,
but most quintiles do not reach the point where
private health spending is 60 of income and
starts to crowd out other consumption. - This is because the public share of health
spending is very high, particularly for elderly.
- Note that, even under these conditions, many
individuals will face real crowd-out, because we
dont have perfect insurance (i.e., private
health spending will still rise if you get sick).
16Health Care Spending as a Share of Income
17Caveats
- Note that this exercise does not take into
account the taxes necessary to finance the large
rise in public health spending built into the
baseline. - If these taxes were to be levied predominantly on
top 2 or 3 quintiles, then health spending might
still not crowd out other spending. - But if these taxes were more evenly distributed,
then lower-income groups would likely face real
crowd out (since increased taxes would crowd out
non-health spending).
18History of Public Response
- History indicates that there will be more
pressure on public spending than this. Public
spending tends to increase as health spending
burden increases. - One reasonable view of recent history is that
public spending increases to keep private
spending constant as a share of income. - Another approach is to examine the relationship
between the public share of spending and the
total burden on health spending.
19Private share of income stays relatively constant
while public role grows
20Public share is larger when health spending is a
higher share of income
21Simulation Public Share Rises Above Baseline
- To get an idea of the potential costs were this
trend to continue, we simulate two alternatives - Alternative A We raise public spending to keep
private spending for elderly and non-elderly
constant at 2002 level. - Alternative B We estimate public spending via a
regression analysis of past trends. - Chart shows the additional government spending
necessary for these alternatives. - Alternative A By 2030 and thereafter, public
health spending would be 50 percent higher than
baseline. - Alternative B By 2030, public health spending
would be 16 percent higher than baseline by
2080 it would be 30 percent above baseline.
22(No Transcript)
23Structure of Insurance
- One striking fact is that the share of
out-of-pocket spending as a share of income has
been very flat over time. - This has been accomplished by a significant
decline in the share of health spending that is
financed through out-of-pocket payments. - A lower out-of-pocket share of health spending
might be a reasonable response to increasing
health costs A constant share might make health
care unaffordable and/or provide too little
insurance. - Implicit baseline assumptions out-of-pocket
payments constant share of health spending. - Alternative assumption out-of-pocket shares
continue to decline over time. Under this
assumption, out-of-pocket spending as a share of
health spending is halved by 2050, and about 40
percent by 2080. - Assuming price elasticity of health spending is
.2, alternative assumption would raise spending
by 3 in 2030, 9 in 2050, and 12 in 2080. - This increase in health spending would raise
public spending by the same percentages.
24Out-of-pocket expenses have been stable as a
share of income, except among poor elderly
(Medicare drug benefit will help reverse this)
25Out-of-pocket share of health spending has
declined
26Conclusions
- From a macroeconomic perspective, 1 percent
excess cost growth is feasible although
difficult. - From a microeconomic perspective, 1 percent seems
more problematic. - Because public share of spending is so large,
most income groups will not face crowd out
non-health consumption. - However, federal health spending, already
difficult to sustain in baseline, will likely
face additional demands. - Also, higher health costs will likely raise
demands for more complete insurance, giving rise
to further health spending pressures (or making
it even harder to achieve 1 percent).