Title: Evidence on PPP
1Evidence on PPP
2Todays Agenda
- Evidence on PPP
- Explaining departures from PPP
- A general model of long-run exchage rates
3Does the Law of One Price Hold?
- There is little evidence to suggest that it holds
in the short-run - The evidence that it holds in the long-run is
stronger but still weak -
4So Why Waste Time Studying PPP?
- There are two reasons
- First while PPP often does not seem to hold,
significant departures from PPP are probably not
sustainable - Second, PPP is a key building block of more
general exchange rate models that are more
realistic than the monetary approach and that
perform better
5Examining the Evidence
- We will now consider the evidence on
- The law of one price
- Absolute PPP
- Relative PPP
- A case study on a high-inflation country
6Hamburger Standard
- The Big Mac Index has been published annually in
the Economist Magazine since 1986 - It measures the variation in the price of a Big
Mac across countries - It was devised as a quirky test of whether
long-run exchange rates were in fact at their
correct level
7Why look at Big Macs?
- The most important reason for looking at Big Macs
is that the quality is almost identical across
countries (homogenous good) - Also Big Macs are sold in over 40 countries
8Bad News for McParity
9What Happens in the Long-Run?
- There are significant differences in the price of
Big Macs - In Malaysia the price of a Big Mac is about half
of what it is in the US - In Switzerland it is 50 higher than the US price
- Subsequent Big Mac surveys have shown no
universal tendency for a narrowing of the 1986
price differentials - So violations of the LOP can be persistent
10700 Years of Evidence
- Froot, Kim and Rogoff (1995) examine annual
commodity price data from England and Holland
over a span of seven centuries - Data price of barley, butter, cheese, eggs,
oats, peas, silver and wheat and pound/shilling
exchange rate dating back to 1273 - Evidence of persistent deviations from the law of
one price over this entire period
11How Do We Test Absolute PPP?
- Given our McParity results, is there any hope for
absolute PPP? - Yes, since the Big Mac may be in some sense
special - To test absolute PPP it is therefore important to
start with a broad reference basket of tradable
commodities after having made careful adjustments
for differences in quality
12Evidence on Absolute PPP
- Frankel has shown that PPP is supported in the
data when annual observations over 100 years are
included in the sample - However Bahmani-Oskoee rejected evidence of
long-run PPP in a sample of industrial countries - In general most studies have concluded that PPP
is way off the mark!
13Relative PPP
- The evidence on relative PPP is a little better
- Relative PPP seems to have held quite well during
the Bretton Woods era but broke down in the 1970s - May be the exchange rate regime has something to
do with it, although Froot et. al. (1995) would
disagree
14Relative PPP US-Canada Annual Data
15Relative PPP US-Canada 5-Year Averages
16Relative PPP US-Canada
- What can we infer from the above two charts?
- There is no evidence of a one-to-one
correspondence between inflation differentials
and the rate of depreciation of the exchange rate - The exchange rate is more volatile than inflation
differentials - In the short-run there is no relationship.
However over longer periods there is some
evidence that the exchange rate tracked inflation
differentials between the two countries - From 1992 this relationship breaks down
17Relative PPP US-Germany Annual Data
18Relative PPP US-Germany 5-Year Averages
19Relative PPP US-Germany
- The exchange rate is highly volatile (in the
post-Bretton Woods period) - There is some evidence of a near one-to-one
correspondence between inflation differentials
and exchange rate movements prior to the 1970s.
Since the 1970s, there is a weak correlation
between these two variables, often punctuated by
long periods of divergence
20Relative PPP Industrialized Countries, Very
Long-Run 1950-2000
average rate of depreciation of the currency
outlier
average inflation differential
21Relative PPP Developing Countries, Very Long-Run
- For developing countries the evidence in favor of
relative PPP often appears stronger, given their
higher inflation experience
average rate of depreciation of the currency
outlier
average inflation differential
22High Inflation Countries
- As the previous slide shows there is stronger
evidence of relative PPP when we focus on high
inflation countries - It turns out that while there can be persistent
departures from PPP, these departures cannot be
too pronounced - PPP will eventually assert itself. Below we
examine some case studies
23Collapse of the Mexican Peso in 1982
- From 1977, prior to 1982 the Mexican peso traded
for about 22.57 pesos per dollar (exchange rate
was fixed) - However, over this time, Mexican inflation was
always higher than US inflation - In January 1982 the exchange rate had crept up to
26.4 pesos. - On February 5th President Lopez announces that
the central bank will defend the peso like a
dog - On February 19th the peg was abandoned
24Collapse of the Mexican Peso in 1982
25Summarizing Evidence
- Little evidence that absolute PPP holds
- Not surprising since the law of one price does
not seem to hold lack of McParity, case in point - Relative PPP does not hold in the short run and
there is weak evidence that it holds in the
long-run in general - Over the very long-run possibly, especially for
high inflation countries relative PPP seems to
hold
26Why the Lack of McParity?
- Big Macs are not directly tradable
- Government regulations differ
- Product differentiationthere are probably fewer
substitutes for Big Macs in some countries - Differences in wages
27Why Might We Expect Deviations From PPP in
General?
- Transport costs and restrictions on trade
- Imperfect competition
- Inflation data reported in countries are based on
different commodity baskets
28Trade Barriers and Nontradables
- Trade barriers and transport costs make it
expensive to move goods between countries. This
weakens the link between exchange rates and goods
prices - For some goodsnontradablestransport costs are
so large that they cannot be traded
internationally - The existence of nontradables allows systematic
deviations from PPP
29Imperfect Competition and Government Regulations
- The law of one price states that higher prices in
one country will generate arbitrage
opportunities. These arbitrage opportunities
will spark a flow of goods and services from the
low-price country to the high-price country until
the price differentials are eliminated - Implicit in this argument is the assumption that
markets are competitive and that governments do
not regulate prices
30Government Regulations Price Controls
- If the government places a price ceiling for
instance, there will be persistent departures
from PPP
31Imperfect Competition
- When markets are imperfectly competitive prices
might not equalize across two markets - A firm may charge two separate prices in two
markets based on demand conditionsthis is called
price discrimination
32Example Nissans Sunderland Plant
- In the early 1990s a Nissan automobile built in
Sunderland, England, could be purchased in
England for 16,215. The same carmanufactured
in Sunderlandcould be purchased in Japan for
13,375, despite the cost of shipping the car
10,600 miles - In this case Nissan is able to price discriminate
because it is so much more costly for the
individual to ship a car from England to Japan - Thus transport costs and imperfectly competitive
market structures together further weaken the
linkages between national price levels and
exchange rates
33Example Nissans Sunderland Plant
UK Market
Japan Market
price of cars in
price of cars in
16,215
13,375
MC
DJp
DUK
quantity
quantity
MRUK
MRJp
34International Differences in the Reference Basket
of Commodities
- There are international differences in what
consumers consume - Norwegians for instance may have a strong
preference for reindeer meat - Japanese have a preference for sushi
- While the average Indian has a preference for
lentils - Consequently a high weight will be put on
reindeer meat in Norway, in Japan a high weight
will be placed on fish and in India a high weight
will be placed on lentils. Thus the reference
commodity basket to measure purchasing power will
vary across countries
35Implications for Absolute PPP
- The implications of this will be that the price
of a typical basket of commodities purchased by
consumers in the US will not be directly
comparable to the price of a typical basket of
commodities consumed in India, Japan, or Norway - A fair test of absolute PPP therefore should not
be based on the price indexes constructed in each
nation
36Implications for Relative PPP
- However if all US prices increase by 10 and the
dollar depreciates against foreign currencies by
10, relative PPP will be satisfied, even though
each reference basket in each country is so
different - Thus we might expect relative PPP to fair better.
However, the problem is that prices of all goods
usually do not go up in unison. Often there are
changes in relative prices
37Price Level Differences and Incomes
- A striking empirical regularity is that price
levels, when expressed in a single currency, tend
to be higher in richer countries than in poorer
countries - A dollar goes further in India than in the US
- International differences in the prices of
nontraded goods appears to be a major
contributing factor
38Price Levels and Real Incomes, 1992
39Balassa-Samuelson Effect
- So why are prices of nontradables so much lower
in poor countries - One explanation was offered by Bela Balassa and
Paul Samuelson that is not inconsistent with the
law of one price - Two Key Assumptions
- Labor forces of poor countries are less
productive than the labor forces of rich
countries in the tradable sectors - Labor forces are equally productive in the
nontradables sector
40How Reasonable Are the Assumptions?
- The assumptions are actually not bad, since the
tradable goods often entail highly capital
intensive production methods that lead to sharp
differences in productivity across rich and poor
countries - By contrast nontradables are often services, like
haircuts, that do not need heavy capital
investment and the latest technologies - It is probably fair to say that a hairdresser in
India is just as productive as a hardresser in
the US
41Implications of Productivity Differences in
Tradables
- The assumption that there exists productivity
differences in the tradable goods sector has
strong implications for the price of labor in the
nontrable sectors and consequently for prices of
nontradable goods and services
42An Example India
- Suppose India makes a traded good (cars) as well
as a nontraded good (haircuts) - The price of cars is given by the world market at
36,000 per car (so by assumption the law of one
price holds)
43continued
- It takes 9 workers 1 year to make one car
- Suppose all the revenue from the sold cars goes
to the workers - This means that each year a worker receives
36,000/94,000
44continued
- How much money should hairdressers make?
- If labor markets are competitive then
hairdressers should also make 4,000 - Suppose that in one year one hairdresser can do
100 haircuts, that means each haircut should cost
40
45An Example USA
- Suppose the US also makes cars and provides
haircuts - The price of a car is 36,000 (this is because we
assume that the law of one price holds for
tradable goods)
46continued
- US workers in the car industry are more
productive than Indian workers. Specifically
suppose that it takes 4 workers 1 year to make
one car - Again we suppose all the revenue from the sold
cars goes to the workers - This means that each year a worker receives
36,000/49,000
47continued
- If labor markets are competitive then
hairdressers should also make 9000 - By assumption hairdressers in the US are as
productive as hairdressers in India, hence in one
year one hairdresser can do 100 haircuts, that
means each haircut should cost 90
48continued
- Consequently a reference commodity basket
consisting of one car and 100 haircuts will cost
40,000 in India, but 45,000 in the US because
the price of nontradables is higher - The price of nontradables is higher because
workers in the nontradable sector in the US are
paid more
49Balassa-Samuelson Effect Summary
- Prices of traded goods are equalized by goods
arbitrage - If rich countries tradable sectors are more
productive, then wages will be higher in these
countries - Higher wages in turn generate higher prices for
nontradable goods - This implies that productivity growth in the
tradable sector will lead to a higher price level
even if the price of tradable goods do not change
50Explaining Departures in PPP
- There is mixed evidence on PPP. However it is
fair to say that it does not hold generally - We can identify the reasons why PPP fails
- Price rises in nontradable goods, government
regulations, or market imperfections could be
important factors - Below we will examine two cases where PPP has
failed to hold
51Hong Kongs Surprisingly High Inflation
- Since 1983 the Hong Kong dollar has been fixed at
HK7.37 per US dollar - However over that period Hong Kongs inflation
has averaged 6.38 while US inflation has
averaged 3.27 - Clearly relative PPP has not held
52continued
53continued
- What can explain the different inflationary
outcomes in the two countries? - Unlike many countries Hong Kong has few
restrictions on trade or regulations on price - In recent years however, there has been high
inflation in the price of services and
nontradables and steep increases in rent - By comparison there has been relatively moderate
inflation in tradables
54The Steady Rise of the Yen
- Between 1950 and 1971 the Japanese yen was fixed
at 360 per dollar, since then the yen has risen
sharply in value. The current spot exchange rate
is 120 per dollar. A 300 appreciation against
the dollar - PPP would imply that this was because US
inflation was three times as high as Japans
inflation. In fact between 1972 and 2000 the
inflation rate in Japan averaged 4.1, the
corresponding figure for the US was 5.2
55continued
- So what explains the amazing appreciation of the
yen? - The answer is suggested by the Balassa-Samuelson
effect - Richard Marston found that productivity growth in
Japans tradable goods far outpaced productivity
growth in nontradables - Between 1973-1983 productivity growth in
tradables exceeded nontradables by 73.2, the
corresponding figure for the US was 13.2
56continued
- Productivity growth in tradables has raised wages
throughout the economy - This has produced significant inflation in the
nontradables - Thus the relative price of nontraded goods in
terms of traded goods has risen over time in
Japan, and it has done so more quickly than in
the US
57A More General Model of Long-Run Exchange Rates
- PPP clearly fails to hold on many occasions, but
often we can explain why this is the case - In light of this it is appropriate to amend our
long-run theory of exchange rates that allows for
departures in PPP for reasons that we have
examined
58Real Exchange Rate
- As a first step to developing our extended theory
of long-run exchange rates we will reintroduce
the real exchange rate - Recall that real exchange rate is defined as
?ePf/P - In a nutshell the real exchange rate is the
dollar price of a basket of foreign goods divided
by the dollar price of a basket of US goods
59Real Exchange Rate Appreciation/Depreciation
- PPP ? ?1. However PPP does not always hold
- What does it mean if ? gt 1 or ? lt 1?
- If ? gt 1 then a basket of foreign goods is more
expensive than a basket of US goods - If ? lt 1 then a basket of foreign goods is
cheaper than a basket of US goods - In general when ? ? foreign goods become more
expensive relative to US goodsthis is called a
real depreciation of the dollar - When ? ? foreign goods become less expensive
relative to US goodsthis is called a real
appreciation of the dollar
60Allowing For Departures in PPP
- We can rearrange our expression for ? and obtain
e?P/Pf - According to the monetary approach to the
exchange rate ?1 hence eP/Pf however now we
want to allow departures from PPP - The above expression implies that
- For a given real exchange rate, changes in money
demand or supply affect the exchange rate as in
the monetary approach - Changes in the real exchange rate also affect the
long-run nominal exchange rate
61Determinants of the Long-Run Exchange Rate
- A shift in relative money supply
- A shift in relative money growth rates
- Any non-monetary changes that affect the real
exchange rate - This could be for instance an increase in
productivity in the tradables sector as was the
case for Japan
62High Inflation Countries and PPP
- Earlier we saw that relative PPP seems to hold
quite well for high inflation countries. Based
on what we have learnt we can now speculate why
this is the case - High inflation is the outcome of monetary changes
and not structural shifts such as increase in
productivity - Thus in high inflation countries monetary factors
are more prominent