Is Free Trade Always Best - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

1 / 20
About This Presentation
Title:

Is Free Trade Always Best

Description:

The first-best remedy of fighting poverty with direct transfers to the poor has ... Is There a Second-Best Argument for Protection? ... – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:164
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 21
Provided by: Econ190
Category:
Tags: always | best | free | trade

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: Is Free Trade Always Best


1
Is Free Trade Always Best?
  • Edward F. Buffie
  • FAO workshop on Staple Food Trade and Market
    Policy Options
  • for Promoting Development
    in Eastern and Southern Africa
  • March 1-2, 2007

2
Ground Rules
  • What is the underlying distortion or market
    imperfection?
  • Does protection/export promotion counteract the
    distortion?
  • Does the argument for protection have a
    satisfactory rejoinder to the first-best solution
    recommended by the Principle of Targeting?
  • Complicated tax-subsidy schemes are impractical.
  • The welfare loss from certain byproduct
    distortions, such as the distortion of consumer
    choice, is quite small (a little triangle).
  • Once administrative costs are thrown into the
    mix, protection can compete for the honor of the
    first-best policy (Buffie, 2001).

3
Food Security/Poverty Reduction
  • Arguments for protection based on concerns about
    food security are suspect.
  • Since most food products are tradable on world
    markets, food security depends mainly on
    purchasing power, not management of domestic
    supply. Food insecurity is a byproduct of
    poverty.
  • The debate usually centers around the impact of
    policy on real income of the poor. Is the notion
    of food security excess conceptual baggage?
  • The first-best remedy of fighting poverty with
    direct transfers to the poor has worked in some
    countries.
  • Decoupled support payments to farmers hurt by
    NAFTA in Mexicos PROCAMPO program.
  • Experience in SSA? Large-scale transfer schemes
    administratively impractical, vulnerable to
    corruption? (Direct cash transfers to 50 of the
    labor force?)

4
Food Security/Poverty Reduction (cont.)
  • Assuming large-scale direct transfers are
    infeasible, the critical issue is how protection
    affects poverty.
  • Typical analysis in the literature is
    inconclusive and unsatisfying.
  • Protection would seem to help the poor because
    poverty is overwhelmingly concentrated in
    agriculture.
  • But higher food prices do little to help poor
    farmers, who often produce mainly for own
    consumption. In addition, they hurt landless
    laborers and the urban poor.
  • Some analyses stop here.
  • Better analyses recognize that unskilled labor in
    agriculture may benefit from higher wages when
    food prices increase. But when the impact on
    other sectors is taken into account, it is not
    clear whether protection of agriculture raises
    overall demand for unskilled labor in the economy
    (McCalla and Nash, 2007, Reforming Agricultural
    Trade for Developing Countries).

5
Food Security/Poverty Reduction (cont.)
  • Knowledge Gap
  • Need more and better analysis of how protecting
    agriculture affects the poor.
  • Static models push the line that growth in
    agriculture does more to reduce poverty than
    growth in other sectors (e.g., Foster and Valdez,
    2003). Reason agriculture is highly
    labor-intensive.
  • With respect to management of the supply chain,
    it is often asserted that protection of food
    crops worsens poverty by attracting resources
    away from more labor-intensive food processing
    and nontraditional export industries (Roberts,
    Buetre, and Jotzo, 2007 McCalla and Nash, 2007).
  • Not clear that the data support this claim.
  • Dearth of analysis based on dynamic models.
  • Dynamics in GTAP, Linkage, and other large CGE
    models either import assumptions about how factor
    supplies and productivity grow or rely on ad hoc
    specifications of saving and investment. Not
    grounded in good theory.
  • First, most of the issues that arise in the
    popular debate over the impacts of trade policy
    are fundamentally comparative static in nature.
    (Hertel and Winters, p.7, Poverty and the WTO
    Impacts of the Doha Development Agenda.)

6
Food Security/Poverty Reduction (cont.)
  • If the policy debate is to be better informed, we
    need input from medium-sized dynamic trade models
    in which private
  • agents solve intertemporal optimization problems.
  • First thoughts on the general structure of the
    dynamic trade model.
  • 4 sectors industry, primary agriculture,
    food-processing/agro-industry, services/nontradabl
    es.
  • 5 factors of production capital, skilled labor,
    unskilled labor, land, and infrastructure.
    Stocks of land and infrastructure treated are
    exogenous.
  • Heterogeneous agents. Capitalists invest only in
    the capital in their own sector.
  • Nature of the labor market? Sectoral wage gaps?
    Degree of intersectoral labor mobility over
    different time horizons?

7
Learning Effects and Infant Industry Arguments
  • The classic infant industry argument (IIA)
    asserts that firms become more efficient as they
    become
  • more experienced.
  • During the infancy/learning phase, firms suffer
    losses when competing at free trade prices.
  • After firms grow up and join the adult world,
    they can compete profitably without protection.
  • Mill-Bastable Criterion If the present value
    gains reaped after the industry is mature exceed
    the present value losses incurred during the
    infancy phase, then the IIA is potentially valid.
  • Underlying imperfection in financial markets
    For some reason, firms cannot borrow to cover
    temporary losses during the learning phase.
  • Quite plausible. Banks face severe moral hazard
    and adverse selection problems. Many borrowers
    lack marketable collateral.
  • Are banks excessively risk averse in SSA?

8
Learning Effects and Infant Industry Arguments
(cont.)
  • Is There a Second-Best Argument for Protection?
  • Is protection justified if the laissez-faire
    equilibrium is not constrained Pareto-efficient
    and the government cannot lend
  • to the targeted firms? Not necessarily.
  • Precommitment to temporary protection may be
    critical.
  • -- Despite brave announcements to the
    contrary, the government may be reluctant to
    remove protection for
  • firms that cannot compete at free trade
    prices.
  • -- Learning is probably not deterministic.
    If firms expend real resources to learn and
    suspect that the
  • government is soft, then there is an
    incentive to balance the gains from learning
    against the costs of losing
  • protection (Matsuyama, 1990 Tornell,
    1991).

9
Learning Effects and Infant Industry Arguments
(cont.)
  • Is There a Second-Best Argument for Protection?
    (cont.)
  • If learning effects are external to the firm,
    protection may be justified even when financial
    markets operate perfectly.
  • The external effect gives rise to multiple
    equilibria and a coordination problem (Krugman,
    1991). The coordination problem can be resolved
    by imposing a tariff that makes it profitable for
    each firm to produce even when all other firms do
    not.
  • Imperfect information about the potential
    viability of the industry may be the source of
    the externality (Hoff, 1997).
  • -- Initial entrants provide information
    through the success/failure of their venture that
    reduces uncertainty for
  • future entrants. (Note Initial entrants
    cannot appropriate the social value of the
    information they generate.
  • Once it becomes known that success is
    possible, new firms enter rapidly and compete
    away rents by
  • bidding up wages.)
  • -- The social value of information that
    reduces uncertainty is greatest in the poorest
    LDCs where the costs of
  • bearing risk are high.

10
Learning Effects and Infant Industry Arguments
(cont.)
  • Empirical Evidence on Learning Effects
  • Is there any evidence of learning effects that
    might justify temporary protection or temporary
    export
  • promotion?
  • Mixed, mainly anecdotal evidence of learning in
    import-competing industries.
  • Most of the recent literature has concentrated on
    testing for learning in export industries. Key
    issue Does the greater productivity of
    exporters reflect self-selection or learning by
    exporting (LBE)?
  • Majority of studies do not find evidence of LBE.
  • But there is support for LBE in a minority of
    studies, including those done for SSA.
  • Only two studies (Clerides, Lach, and Tybout,
    1998 Alvarez and Lopez, 2006) investigate
    learning externalities.

11
Raising Revenue for Public Sector Investment
  • Given the limited number of tax handles, the
    relatively low administrative costs of trade
    taxes, and the high social return to public
    investment in social and physical infrastructure,
    there is a sound case for including tariffs in
    the set of optimal taxes levied to finance
    government expenditure.
  • Aid-for-trade can, of course, lessen the need to
    use tariffs as a revenue-raising device.

12
Factor Market Distortions
  • Imperfections that cause underemployment and
    misallocation of labor across sectors
  • Unions, payroll taxes, and minimum wage laws that
    make labor more expensive in the formal sector
    than in other sectors.
  • Efficiency wages in agro-industry and other
    branches of the formal sector.
  • Wage premium need not reflect a compensating
    differential for working harder in the formal
    sector. The nature of the monitoring technology
    matters. (Why isnt the wage gap eliminated by
    competition from lower-paid workers in the
    informal sector? Answer the promise to work
    hard at a lower wage is not credible.)
  • Absence of well-defined land tenure conflates the
    return to work in agriculture with rents from
    land. This impedes intersectoral labor mobility
    -- if you move away, you lose your claim to the
    land and the rents in confers.

13
Factor Market Distortions (cont.)
  • Factors that cause under-investment
  • Share tenancy
  • Communally-owned land
  • Insecure, unclear property rights
  • Taxation of profits
  • Lack of credit for smallholders
  • Sens isolation paradox . . . the market
    cannot express the collective demand for
    investment to benefit the future. (Feldstein,
    1964)

14
Factor Market Distortions (cont.)
  • Implications for Policy
  • Principle of Targeting Attack the distortions
    directly with suitable employment and investment
    subsidies financed by taxes that do not interfere
    with free trade.
  • Labor market imperfections favor protection of
    manufacturing and agro-industry.
  • Agro-industry generally pays higher wages than
    traditional agriculture (World Bank, 2006,
    Agricultural Growth for the Poor).
  • Abundant casual evidence that exporters pay
    higher wages to both skilled and unskilled labor
    than non-exporters.
  • Market imperfections that cause underinvestment
    operate to varying degrees in all sectors.

15
Factor Market Distortions (cont.)
  • In combination, underemployment and
    underinvestment argue for an escalated structure
    of protection and export promotion that lowers
    the real price of imported capital goods and
    intermediate inputs.
  • Support for this conjecture in the solutions for
    optimal trade policy presented in Buffie (2001).
  • Variance in protection/export promotion across
    sectors (primary agriculture vs. agro-industry
    vs. other manufacturing) likely to be less when
    distributional objectives are taken into account.
    See Buffie (2001).
  • Need optimal policy solutions or at least a sense
    of the tradeoffs that accompany different policy
    packages in dynamic trade models with a more
    detailed representation of the agricultural
    sector.
  • An escalated structure of protection plus export
    promotion does not necessarily imply that the
    economy is less open or that there is less trade
    than under free trade. The policy package alters
    the composition of trade fewer imports of
    consumer goods, but more exports and more imports
    of intermediate inputs and capital goods.

16
A Customs Union for Agriculture?
  • Analysis of the welfare outcome usually focuses
    on three effects
  • Trade creation vs. trade diversion (Viner).
  • More competition, higher output per firm, and
    lower unit costs in industries where increasing
    returns to scale exist.
  • Distribution of gains and losses within the
    customs union (CU).
  • If the CU improves allocative efficiency, will
    intra-union transfer payments be needed to ensure
    that all members benefit?
  • In SSA another effect is important
  • Impact on government revenue and the ability to
    finance high-return investments in social and
    physical infrastructure.

17
A Customs Union for Agriculture? (cont.)
  • Trade Creation vs. Trade Diversion
  • Textbook treatments are deceiving in that,
    following Viner, they assume the countrys trade
    partners in the union operate with
    infinitely-elastic supply curves.
  • This ensures that intra-union imports completely
    displace imports from outside the union. Hence
    the CU generates some trade creation that might
    offset trade diversion.
  • But with positively-sloped supply curves,
    intra-union imports may not completely displace
    imports from the outside.
  • -- If they do not, then the CU reduces
    efficiency. It results only in trade diversion.
  • Zero trade creation is a serious concern in the
    African context.
  • Land is an important quasi-fixed factor. Given
    this, the shortage of credit, and numerous severe
    infrastructural bottlenecks, is it naïve to hope
    for an elastic supply response?
  • Volume of intra-regional trade is generally very
    low. Is this true for the most important
    agricultural products?

18
A Customs Union for Agriculture? (cont.)
  • Intra-Regional Distribution of Gains and Losses
  • Distribution of intra-regional trade is very
    lopsided.
  • Kenya and S. Africa are the only countries that
    export a substantial amount to the region.
    Neither country, however, imports much from the
    region.
  • Is this also true of intra-regional trade in
    agriculture? (Maybe not. Isnt S. Africas
    agricultural sector relatively small?)
  • If it is, then Kenya and S. Africa, the two most
    developed countries in the region, will reap
    gains as
  • beneficiaries of trade diversion while
    everyone else suffers losses. In short, the CU
    operates like a
  • scheme where everyone hands over their
    tariff revenue to Kenya and S. Africa.

19
A Customs Union for Agriculture? (cont.)
  • Impact on Trade Tax Revenue
  • Trade taxes constitute a significant share of
    total revenue in many countries.
  • Limited replacement ( 33) of lost trade tax
    revenue in low-income LDCs (Baungaard and Keen,
    2005).
  • Public investment in infrastructure is likely to
    bear the brunt of adjustment to the revenue loss.
    The welfare costs of this are sure to exceed any
    small triangle welfare gains that might
    materialize should the benefits of trade creation
    exceed the losses from trade diversion.

20
A Customs Union for Agriculture? (cont.)
  • Bottom Line
  • Maybe it is best to go slow on regional
    integration until major supply-side constraints
    have been alleviated and regional
  • trade is a greater proportion of total trade.
  • Enhances the likelihood that the CU will generate
    some trade creation.
  • Reduces the welfare costs associated with lower
    revenue from trade taxes.
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)
About PowerShow.com