Simon Cowan - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

1 / 34
About This Presentation
Title:

Simon Cowan

Description:

Requires too much information to be feasible in most cases. 11. Third-degree price discrimination ... Sometime discrimination opens a new market, which has an ... – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:91
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 35
Provided by: nuffie
Category:
Tags: cowan | simon | survey

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: Simon Cowan


1
Price Discrimination
  • Simon Cowan
  • Department of Economics and Worcester College
  • Thursday 4th June, 2009
  • MFE Course on Industrial Organization

2
outline
  • What is price discrimination, when is it
    feasible, why do firms do it?
  • What types of price discrimination are there?
  • What are the welfare effects?
  • Price discrimination and oligopoly
  • Tying and bundling

3
What is price discrimination?
  • Simple definition discrimination means selling
    the same good at different prices
  • Microsoft sets different prices for the Office
    suite
  • Airlines charge different amounts for similar
    tickets
  • More generally price discrimination is present
    when two or more similar goods are sold at prices
    that are in different ratios to marginal costs
    (Varian, 1989, p 598)
  • So a uniform delivered price, e.g. for letters,
    is discriminatory if costs differ
  • If price differences reflect cost differences
    then there is no discrimination

4
When is discrimination feasible?
  • No arbitrage (i.e. no resale)
  • Especially for services
  • Firm has market power
  • Can raise price above marginal cost
  • Market power need not be complete
  • Ability to sort or classify customers

5
Why do firms discriminate?
  • To capture more consumer surplus
  • Usually, at least with monopoly, the firm is
    better off with the ability to discriminate
  • But discrimination does not always raise profits
  • Durable-goods monopoly the firm would like to
    commit to keep prices high, but once the
    high-value customers have purchased the firm
    cannot resist cutting price to the remaining
    lower-value customers. Anticipating this, some
    high-value customers delay purchasing.
  • Discrimination with oligopoly the firm may have
    a unilateral incentive to discriminate, but all
    firms can be worse off if all discriminate as
    competition for particular customers is intense

6
Types of discrimination
  • Pigous 1920 three-fold classification
  • First-degree complete information,
    take-it-or-leave-it offers by the firm
  • Second-degree customer self-selection
  • Menus of tariffs
  • Nonlinear tariffs
  • airline customers can choose when to travel and
    whether to stay a Saturday night or not
  • Third-degree exogenous signal that the firm uses
    to classify customers
  • Educational discounts for software
  • Consultants paying more for conferences than
    academics

7
Simple monopoly pricing
Price
Demand
Monopoly price
Marginal Cost
MR
Quantity
Monopoly volume
8
Monopoly pricing and the price elasticity
  • The monopoly mark-up, at the profit-maximizing
    price, is

9
Can the firm do better?
  • Customers with valuations above the monopoly
    price obtain a surplus
  • If they could be identified then they could be
    charged more (as long as there is no resale)
  • Customers who value the good below the price set
    by the monopolist dont buy at all
  • Can they be persuaded to buy, without at the same
    time cutting the price(s) that existing
    customers pay?

10
The lost surpluses
Price
Surplus of consumers who buy at the monopoly price
Monopoly price
Monopoly profit
Surplus lost because these customers dont buy at
all this is the loss to society from
monopoly the deadweight loss
Marginal Cost
Quantity
Monopoly volume
11
First-degree price discrimination
  • The firm knows the maximum amount that each
    customer is willing to pay, and charges each
    customer this amount
  • Marginal revenue now becomes the (inverse) demand
    function (no need to drop the price on other
    units)
  • De Beers sales of rough diamonds
  • Diamonds sorted into 12,000 categories based on
    size, shape, quality, colour. Offered on a
    take-it-or-never buy from us again basis.
  • With linear demand profits double the firm grabs
    both the triangles as well as the rectangle
  • Social welfare is maximized, but it all goes to
    the firm
  • Requires too much information to be feasible in
    most cases

12
Third-degree price discrimination
  • The firm sorts customers into separate markets
    using an exogenous signal
  • E.g. students, seniors, families, income bracket,
    business v. domestic
  • Monopoly pricing in each separate market
  • Price is higher in less elastic markets (remember
    the elasticity in general is endogenous)
  • Microsoft Office
  • UK price of Office Standard was 329 in 2008
  • USA price was 399.95 (200.98 at the exchange
    rate of 1.99 1)
  • The American Economic Association charges
    according to income for membership
  • Annual income lt 50,000 64
  • 50,000 ? Annual Income ? 66,000 77
  • 66,000 lt Annual income 90
  • Student member (written verification required)
    32

13
Is third-degree price discrimination good for
social welfare?
  • In general the effect is ambiguous
  • The firm gains from extra flexibility
  • Customers offered higher prices lose
  • Customers offered lower prices gain
  • Sometime discrimination opens a new market, which
    has an unambiguously good effect (a weak Pareto
    improvement)
  • anti-retroviral drugs are now available in Africa
    at prices much lower than in North America and
    Europe

14
Price discrimination opens a new market
Price
If required to sell at the same price in both
markets, the firm will just set the best price
for Market 1 and not bother to sell in Market 2
Demand in 1
Market 2
Price in Market 1
Aggregate demand
Marginal Cost
Quantity
Monopoly volume
15
What about when new markets are not opened?
  • Schmalensee (AER, 1981) a necessary condition
    for discrimination to raise welfare is that total
    output rises
  • Misallocation effect Inefficient distribution of
    the given output across markets with
    discrimination
  • Output effect An output increase is good for
    welfare when prices exceed marginal cost

16
With linear demand functionsoutput is constant,
so welfare falls
  • Suppose q1 1 p1 and q2 2 p2 c 0
  • Discriminatory prices and quantities
  • Profit in 1, p1(1 p1), is maximized with p1
    0.5, q1 0.5
  • Profit in 2, p2(2 p2), is maximized with p2
    1, q2 1
  • With non-discriminatory pricing, the profit
    function is
  • p(1 p 2 p) p(3 2p) for p 1 and
  • p(2 p) for p gt 1
  • Best non-discriminatory price is p 0.75 and
  • q1 q2 3 2?0.75 1.5
  • Total output is the same with and without
    discrimination when demand functions are linear

17
A generalization
  • Define the curvature (or convexity) of demand as
    ? ? pq?(p)/q?(p)
  • The non-discriminatory price is pN
  • Call the low-price market L and the high-price
    market H
  • For a very large set of demand functions a
    sufficient condition for social welfare to fall
    with discrimination is
  • ? H(pN) ? ? L(pN)
  • The linear example is a special case
  • So a necessary condition for discrimination to
    raise welfare is that
  • ? L(pN) gt ? H(pN)
  • Cowan (2008) gives additional conditions

18
Second-degree two-part tariffs
  • Conventional pricing is known as linear pricing
  • Price per unit p, total payment for q units
    pq
  • The total payment is proportional to the quantity
  • Tariffs need not be linear
  • A two-part tariff is the simplest form of
    nonlinear pricing
  • Total payment fixed fee price ? quantity
    T(q) A pq
  • E.g. utility tariffs, gym membership, warehouse
    clubs, railcards to obtain discounts, mobile
    phone tariffs
  • Such tariffs are used to extract additional
    consumer surplus

19
Individual two-part tariffs
  • If the firm knows each customers demand function
    (and therefore their consumer surplus) then
    individual two-part tariffs Ai, pi can be used
  • The profit-maximizing strategy is to set the same
    marginal price, equal to marginal cost, for all
    i pi c
  • The lump-sum fees are individual, Ai, and are set
    to extract each consumers surplus
  • Equivalently the firm sets total payment-quantity
    bundles Ti, qiAi cqi(c), qi(c)
  • This is first-degree discrimination again

20
second-degree nonlinear pricing
  • Now assume the firm cannot identify each
    customers type
  • Large customers are willing to pay more than
    small customers, and want to buy more
  • First-degree discrimination is not
    incentive-compatible
  • The firm offers alternative bundles that
    specify the quantity and total payment. Customers
    can choose.
  • The key is to extract as much profit as possible
    from the large customers, while still selling to
    the small customers
  • This is done by making the package for the small
    customers sufficiently unattractive for large
    customers

21
First-degree discrimination is not
incentive-compatible
With first-degree discrimination the
large customer pays B D E for qH while the
small customer pays B for qL. When given a
choice the large customer will pay B for qL,
giving a surplus of D. Profit 2B. More
profitable offer a choice between B, qL and
B E, qH Profit 2B E
Price
D
B
E
c
Quantity
qL
qH
22
Dupuit and incentive compatibility
  • On railway tariffs and classes (1849)
  • It is not because of the few thousand francs
    which would have to be spent to put a roof over
    the third-class carriages or to upholster the
    third-class seats that some company or other has
    open carriages with wooden benches...What the
    company is trying to do is prevent the passengers
    who pay the second-class fare from travelling
    third-class it hits the poor, not because it
    wants to hurt them, but to frighten the
    rich...And it is again for the same reason that
    the companies, having proved almost cruel to
    third-class passengers and mean to second-class
    ones, becomes lavish in dealing with first-class
    passengers. Having refused the poor what is
    necessary, they give the rich what is
    superfluous.
  • Source Tirole, p 150

23
Nonlinear pricing distorting the quantity to
capture more surplus
Price
Now the firm offers q at B x, and qH at B E
y . Profits rise by y x. Optimal q balances
marginal y against marginal x. The large customer
consumes the efficient quantity, but the quantity
for the small customer is distorted below qL.
D
B
y
E
x
c
Quantity
qL
qH
q
24
Optional two-part tariffs a simple form of
nonlinear pricing
total payment
tariff designed for households
tariff designed for business customers
Business customer chooses here
Household chooses here
volume of calls
25
Damaging goods
  • Another way to encourage customers to self-select
    is to damage ones good, in order artificially to
    provide a range of qualities
  • The Intel 486 chip came in two versions
  • The main version had the math-coprocessor working
  • The secondary version had the math-coprocessor
    switched off
  • IBM sold a printer which came in two versions
  • The main version worked at 12 pages per minute
  • The other version included an instruction to slow
    down the rate of printing, so that it printed 8
    pages per minute
  • Otherwise the printers were identical

26
Oligopoly no discrimination
  • Hotelling model, consumers uniformly distributed
    along 0, 1
  • Firm A located at 0, price pA firm B at 1, pB
  • Consumer at x pays pA tx when buying from A, pB
    t(1 x) from B. t unit transport cost
  • When pA tx pB t(1 x) the consumer at x is
    indifferent
  • qA x ½ (pB pA)/2t
  • qB 1 x ½ (pA pB)/2t
  • ?A (pA c)½ (pB pA)/2t
  • ?B (pB c)½ (pA pB)/2t
  • Bertrand-Nash equilibrium in prices pA pB c
    t
  • Profit per firm is t/2

27
Oligopoly Discrimination I
  • Now both firms know the location of each
    consumer, i.e. x, and can offer individual prices
  • Consider a consumer located near A with x lt ½
  • Given the price that B offers, pB(x), A could
    offer a price that gives just as good a deal
    defined by
  • pA(x) tx pB(x) t(1 x)
  • So pA(x) pB(x) t(1 2x) gt pB(x)
  • The firms compete for this customer until the
    less-favoured firm, B, just makes zero profit,
    i.e. pB(x) c
  • At this point A can win by pricing a penny lower
    than the price implied by the equally good deal
    equation to find this set pB(x) c in the
    equation, giving pA(x) c t(1 2x)

28
Oligopoly Discrimination II
  • The discriminatory price schedules are
  • pA(x) c t(1 2x) for x 0.5
  • pA(x) c for x gt 0.5
  • pB(x) c for x lt 0.5
  • pB(x) c t(2x 1) for x ? 0.5
  • Apart from the consumers at 0 and 1, every
    consumer pays less when there is price
    discrimination
  • Profits per firm drop from t/2 to t/4 with
    discrimination

29
Prices and profits
c t
c t
c
0
1
0.5
30
Oligopoly discrimination III
  • The model has assumed best-response asymmetry,
    so the firms do not share the same view about
    which market will have the higher price once
    discrimination is allowed
  • I want to price high in my back-yard, while you
    want to price low in my back-yard
  • Alternatively there may be best-response
    symmetry e.g. when the demand functions for each
    firm in a large market are both higher than those
    in a small market
  • In this case price rises in the large market and
    falls in the small market

31
Tying
  • If you buy my machine you must also buy spare
    parts from me (even though spare parts could be
    supplied by a competitive market)
  • Printers and cartridges
  • Enables the firm to make more profit from large
    users (spare parts priced above marginal cost)
  • Effectively a two-part tariff price for the
    good and a price for the spare parts

32
Bundling
  • Selling two goods in fixed proportions
  • Selling both channels separately
  • p(Sport) 8 Profit 16
  • p(Doc) 10 Profit 20
  • Total profit 36
  • Bundle price is 20 profit 40
  • Negative correlation of valuations makes bundling
    profitable
  • Moving closer to first-degree discrimination
    (with which profit would be 45)

33
Summary
  • Price discrimination is very common, and takes
    many forms
  • The main aim of the discrimination analyzed here
    is to extract more surplus from consumers
  • This usually has ambiguous welfare effects
  • Discrimination is of antitrust concern,
    particularly in intermediate goods markets, when
    it is a sign of something else
  • excessive market power
  • predatory pricing
  • market foreclosure and exclusion

34
Reading, with annotations
  • J. Tirole, Theory of Industrial Organization,
    1988, Ch 3 excellent textbook survey
  • H. Varian, Ch 10 in Handbook of Industrial
    Organization, Vol 1, edited by R. Schmalensee and
    R. Willig, 1989 the main survey of monopolistic
    discrimination
  • M. Motta, Competition Policy, CUP, 2004, Ch 7.4
    (discrimination), 7.3.2.2 (tying) emphasis on
    competition policy implications
  • L. Stole, Ch 34 in Handbook of Industrial
    Organization, Vol 3, edited by M. Armstrong and
    R. Porter, 2007, especially Section 3.4,
    available at http//econpapers.repec.org/bookchap/
    eeeindchp/3-34.htm very comprehensive on
    discrimination and competition.
  • S. Cowan (2008) When does third-degree price
    discrimination reduce social welfare, and when
    does it raise it?, Department of Economics
    Discussion Paper No. 410, http//www.economics.ox.
    ac.uk/index.php/papers/details/when_does_third_deg
    ree_410/ new results on the welfare effects of
    third-degree discrimination
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)
About PowerShow.com