Title: Why economics must abandon
1Why economics must abandon
2Not a new call
- Clapham 1922, Sraffa 1926, 1930
- I am trying to find what are the assumptions
implicit in Marshall's theory if Mr Robertson
regards them as extremely unreal, I sympathise
with him. We seem to be agreed that the theory
cannot be interpreted in a way which makes it
logically self-consistent and, at the same time,
reconciles it with the facts it sets out to
explain. Mr Robertson's remedy is to discard
mathematics, and he suggests that my remedy is to
discard the facts perhaps I ought to have
explained that, in the circumstances, I think it
is Marshall's theory that should be discarded.
(Sraffa 1930 93)
3Sraffas argument
- Two key assumptions of short run theory of the
firm - Independent supply and demand curves
- Diminishing marginal productivity
- in practice are mutually inconsistent
- Independent supply and demand curves realistic
when define industry narrowly (e.g., wheat) - but then increased production will result from
industry drawing marginal doses of allegedly
fixed resource from other industries, inputs
lying fallow - Constant returns, constant costs
4Sraffas argument
- If we next take an industry which employs only a
small part of the 'constant factor' (which
appears more appropriate for the study of the
particular equilibrium of a single industry), we
find that a (small) increase in its production is
generally met much more by drawing 'marginal
doses' of the constant factor from other
industries than by intensifying its own
utilisation of it thus the increase in cost will
be practically negligible (Sraffa 1926)
5Sraffas argument
- Diminishing marginal productivity realistic when
industry defined widely (e.g., Agriculture) - Input of fixed resource can be increased only
with difficulty - But then change in output of this industry will
affect income distribution - change in income distribution will affect demand
- impossible to ignore feedback effects between
supply and demand
6Sraffas argument
- If in the production of a particular commodity a
considerable part of a factor is employed, the
total amount of which is fixed or can be
increased only at a more than proportional cost,
a small increase in the production of the
commodity will necessitate a more intense
utilisation of that factor, and this will affect
in the same manner the cost of the commodity in
question and the cost of the other commodities
into the production of which that factor enters
and since commodities into the production of
which a common special factor enters are
frequently, to a certain extent, substitutes for
one another ... the modification in their price
will not be without appreciable effects upon
demand in the industry concerned. (Sraffa 1926)
7Sraffas argument
- Implication of Sraffas argument constant
marginal costs in the short run - In normal cases the cost of production of
commodities produced competitively ... must be
regarded as constant in respect of small
variation in the quantity produced. And so, as a
simple way of approaching the problem of
competitive value, the old and now obsolete
theory which makes it dependent on the cost of
production alone appears to hold its ground as
the best available. (Sraffa 1926) - Sraffas argument largely ignored by profession
- replies focused on his critique of concept of
diminishing returns in long run rather than short
run
8Sraffas argument
- Subsequent papers (Pigou 1922, 1927, 1928
Robertson 1924, 1930 Robbins 1932, Harrod 1934
etc.) accept that - diminishing marginal productivity in the short
run as unarguable - theory of perfect competition watertight
- Ditto any introductory to advanced micro text
today - Even advanced non-PC theory implicitly treats PC
as ideal - Why? The apparently conclusive mathematics
- It is not conclusive
- Recap argument, firstly w.r.t. perfect
competition
9Conventional explanation of PMC
- Unique attributes of PC industry are
- Supply curve exists (sum of MC curves)
- Price set by supply and demand
- MRP for individual firm
Sm point of supply for this D curve
Sum MarginalCost PCSupply Curve PC
Price
MarginalCost Monopoly(not Supply Curve)
Pm
Ppc
D
Marginal Revenue
Qm
Qpc
- Monopoly/Monopolistic competition
- No supply curve
- PgtMC,MR for individual firm and market
Quantity
- How are unique attributes of PC established?
10Conventional explanation of PMC
- Start with market supply and demand curves
- Determine equilibrium quantity and price by
intersection of two curves
Price
Supply
Pe
- Assume this is the price taken as given by PC
firms
Demand
Quantity
Qe
- Show that the MC curve of the PC firm is its
supply curve, assuming demand horizontal
Price
Marginal Cost
Pe
- Aggregate firm supply curves to determine market
supply curve
qe
quantity
11Conventional explanation of PMC
- But potentially circular logic here
Start with market supply curve
Each step depends on the other
Derive individual firm supply curve
- Argument that PC firms profit maximise by setting
PMC should be provable at level of individual
firm alone. - If theory correct, should be provable that any
change in output from qe reduces profit
Over to Mathematica
Skip summary of results
12So Mathematica tell us
- Given linear demand and supply (for simplicity
w.l.o.g.)
- And standard definitions of Total Revenue,
Profit, alleged profit maximising levels of
output
- Test alleged monopoly equilibrium
- Enigmatic concise confirmation
- Perfect competition equilibrium
13So Mathematica tell us
- Consider impact of perturbation of dq from
monopoly profit maximisation point on profit
- Profit changes by clearly negative amount,
whatever sign of dq
- Consider impact of perturbation of dq from
perfect competition profit maximisation point on
profit
14Conventional explanation of PMC
- Theory intact if and only if dP/dq0
- but given assumption of atomism, dP/dqdP/dQ
- And
- Profit falls if output rises past where PMC
- Profit rises if output falls below where PMC
- PMC is not a (profit maximising) equilibrium
15Logical errors in conventional theory
- Neoclassical micro assumes no feedback from
individual firm to market price - But feedback necessary if market demand curve
downward sloping - Feedback affects all firms
- aggregate effect sums to same behaviour as single
firm given valid identical cost curves - why should large number of rational agents reach
different conclusion to single rational agent,
given same data? - Consider the Friedman argument
16Profit maximising firms?
- Excellent predictions would be yielded by the
hypothesis that the billiard player made his
shots as if he knew the complicated mathematical
formulas , could make lightning calculations
from the formulas, and could then make the balls
travel in the direction indicated by the
formulas. Our confidence in this hypothesis is
not based on the belief that billiard players,
even expert ones, can or do go through the
process described it derives rather from the
belief that, unless in some way or other they
were capable of reaching essentially the same
result, they would not in fact be expert billiard
players. (Friedman The methodology of positive
economics)
Miltons Pool Hall
Skip summary of results
17Miltons Pool Hall
- Simulation of an industry with
- Fixed linear demand curve
- Constant marginal cost (see later for rising MC)
- Given number of firms
- Each firm starts with randomly determined output
level - Each firm varies own output by randomly
determined amount (ive or -ive) - If new level of profit higher, keeps changing
output in same direction - Otherwise, changes in opposite direction
18Miltons Pool Hall
- Model 1 simple mechanism
- Firm always changes output by same amount
- Model 2 (slightly more) sophisticated mechanism
- Firm tries randomly determined amount, with range
of random variable falling each iteration - In both cases, output and price converge to
monopoly level (MCMR), not perfect
competition level (PMC), regardless of number
of firms
- Market definitions monopoly price 80, PC
price 50
19Miltons Pool Hall the program
No. of firms
Calculate profits
Random adjustments
Calculate new profits
Work out direction of change
For 50 iterations
Make directed random adjustments of diminishing
size
20Miltons Pool Hall the outcome
Market converges to monopoly price regardless of
number of firms
21Simulation Results
- With constant marginal cost
- Number of firms makes no difference
- output converges to monopoly level, not perfect
competition - With rising marginal cost?
- Market definitions monopoly price 90, PC
price 80
22Miltons Pool Hall the outcome (2)
- Price appears to converge to PC level for gt 1 firm
- But
- Are cost functions the same?
23Miltons Pool Hall the outcome (2)
- Apparent difference in behaviour illusory
- Difference in output level price due to
difference in cost functions
24Supply aggregation
- Number of firms does make a difference, but
- cause is difference in total cost functions, not
MRMC for monopoly, PMC for PC - Supply aggregation (so that MC for monopoly
identical to sum of MC for PC) only possible with
horizontal marginal cost
25Supply aggregation
- Monopoly/PC welfare comparison requires identical
MC curves, otherwise
Price
Ppc
Pm
Demand/Price
Marginal Revenue
Qpc
Qm
Quantity
26Supply aggregation
- WLOG, consider n PC firms employing x workers
- MC derived from MP
- identity of MC requires identity of MP
- TP can only differ by a constant
- constant zero if variable factor is labour
- So we have
- n competitive firms
- f PC production function
- g monopoly production function
Euler's equation
27Supply aggregation
Consider ratio
Substitute
28Supply aggregation
- So g a staight line
- Consider f
- Differentiate marginal product a constant,
therefore marginal cost a constant
29Supply aggregation
- Only supply curve for which sum of marginal cost
curves of small firms identical to marginal cost
curve of single firm is constant identical
marginal cost - Static profit maximisation (with identical MC
curves) occurs where PgtMC, MCMR for both
monopoly and competitive industries - Neoclassical theory of the firm thus
- logically flawed
- devoid of content
- Contradictions self-evident once you know to look
30There for all to see
- Conventional welfare comparison of monopoly to PC
has monopoly producing to maximum profit, but PC
producing past that point in the aggregate - PC output past point where market MC market MR
must be produced at a loss, yet no loss shown at
firm level
?
?
31There for all to see
- Producer surplus shows the fallacy
- Collective gain in producer surplus from reducing
output from PMCgtMR to PgtMRMC obvious
P
S
Loss
PgtMC
Gain
PMC
D
Qe
Qe-DQ
Q
P
Loss
P where MRgtMC
MC
Gain
P where MRMC
- Producer surplus maximised at MRMC level
- PMC only possible with individually and
collectively irrational behaviour
D
MR
Qe
Qe-DQ
Q
32Root of the fallacy
- Models of PC and monopoly identical at firm level
- Sole difference is presence of market marginal
revenue curve in monopoly, absence in PC
Perfect competition
P
S
P gt MRMC
PMC
D
MR
- But market MR curve exists independent of number
of firms in industry
Qe
Qe
P
Monopoly
MC
- Only way to get MRP at firm level is for it to
apply at industry level (horizontal market demand
curve)
P gt MRMC
D
- PC theory based on equating infinitesimals to zero
MR
Qe
33Theoretical consequences
- Supply and demand analysis not viable
- supply curve cant be constructed
- can only show point of supply for given
(aggregate) MC and given demand - increase in demand could lower market price
Monopoly, etc.
Perfect Competition
- Minimum of 3 curves needed to determine
price/quantity
MarginalCost
marginalcost
S1
s2
s1
S2
d2
d1
supplycurve
D2
D1
MR2
MR1
34Theoretical consequences
- Welfare ideals unachievable
- equality of marginal benefits to marginal costs
impossible even under perfect competition - all market structures will have marginal benefits
gt marginal costs in profit maximising equilibrium - market outcomes will not maximise social benefits
- How to interpret price-taking behaviour?
- Firms may take market price as given, but
- price does not equate price and marginal cost
- instead reflects markup in that industry
- For viable firms, price will exceed marginal cost
- But at least MCMR rule maximises profit, right?
- Wrong
35Dynamics of profit maximisation
- Profit maximisation rule invalid in dynamic
setting - MCMR rule tells how to maximise profit w.r.t.
quantity - Real firms more interested in maximising profits
w.r.t. time - Time-based rule requires MR gt MC.
- Time-based analysis shows that profit
maximisation rules too complex to be a guide to
determining output, even if diminishing marginal
returns applies
36Profit maximising firms?
- Neoclassical logic
- Profit a function of quantity
- Price decreasing and cost increasing functions of
quantity
- Maximise profit by setting marginal revenue equal
to marginal cost
- Mathematical logic
- Profit at least a function of quantity and time
- quantity also a function of time
- Dynamic goal maximisation of rate of growth of
profit
37Profit maximising firms?
- Rate of growth of profit is
- Under what circumstances will setting MRMC
maximise the rate of growth of profit?
- Is this condition relevant to a dynamic economy?
- No, it is the definition of a static one
No way!
- Are the values of MR and MC relevant to the
conditions for maximising the rate of growth of
the rate of profit?
38Dynamics of profit maximisation
- Assuming, for the sake of argument, that the rate
of growth of profit has a single maximum, set its
differential to zero
- Assuming, for the sake of argument, that the rate
of growth of the rate of profit is monotonic, the
rate of change of the rate of growth of profit is
zero where (courtesy of Mathematica)
39Profit maximising firms?
- No mathematician in her right mind would advise a
firm to manage this function! - Pulling MC and MR out of this, we derive
40Dynamics of profit maximisation
Mathematica
- Useful rule?
- Of course not too complex, and firm cant know
dq/dt anyway but regardless, neoclassical rule - invalid if dq/dtgt0
- would cause lower rate of growth of profits if
followed in practice. - Supports Sraffas 1926 argument MC MR
irrelevant to firms output decisions
41Dynamics of profit maximisation
- Founders of neoclassical analysis realised that
concepts of statics and short run inadequate
proper analysis should be dynamic. - Only reason to imagine a static economy was to
make analysis tractable - Marshall ...dynamics includes statics... But
the statical solution is simpler... it may
afford useful preparation and training for the
more difficult dynamical solution and it may be
the first step towards a provisional and partial
solution in problems so complex that a complete
dynamical solution is beyond our attainment.
(1907, in Groenewegen 1996 432)
42Dynamics of profit maximisation
- Jevons If we wished to have a complete solution
... we should have to treat it as a problem of
dynamics. But it would surely be absurd to
attempt the more difficult question when the more
easy one is yet so imperfectly within our power.
(1871 1911 93) - J.B. Clark on the future of economics A point
on which opinions differ is the capacity of the
pure theory of Political Economy for progress.
There seems to be growing impression that, as a
mere statement of principles, this science will
fairly soon be complete It is with this view
that I take issue. The great coming development
of economic theory is to take place, I venture to
assert, through the statement and solution of
dynamic problems (Clark 1898)
43Dynamics of profit maximisation
- Statics has clearly led to misleading and
irrelevant advice re profit maximisation - Dynamic answer different to static one
- This is a common result in mathematics
- Static and dynamic results only coincide when
relevant system is stable - Stable in this context means a no-growth
economy - Unstable means growing economy, and MCMR
irrelevant - So if economists cant provide guidance for firms
from a priori theory of cost and revenue
functions, what can it do?
44What can economics do?
- Become an empirical discipline ask firms what
they actually do - Dominant tendency in economics is a priori
analysis work out what must be from prior
axioms - A pre-Galilean approach to science
- Why not experiment/survey?
- Numerous researchers have done so, and found that
MC/MR analysis irrelevant to real firms - Andrews, Bishop, Downie, Eiteman, Eiteman and
Guthrie, Haines, Hall Hitch, Lee, Means,
Tucker, the Oxford Economic Research Group,
(see Lee 1998 for full details), Blinder et al
1998
45Actual firms behaviour
- Empirical researchers found
- average costs of production declined as output
rose - marginal costs were always well below their
average costs, and substantially smaller than
marginal revenue, and - concept of a demand curve (and therefore its
derivative marginal revenue) was simply
irrelevant.
46Actual firms behaviour
- Eiteman Guthrie (1952) showed factory managers
graphs indicating possible different cost curve
relations - Outcome was
- Businessmen viewed the economists concepts of
perfect competition and monopoly as virtual
nonsense and the product of the itching
imaginations of uninformed and inexperienced
armchair theorizers. (Lee 1998, citing Tucker)
47Actual firms behaviour
- Major reason why economic a priori did not apply?
- Engineers designed factories so as to cause the
variable factor to be used most efficiently when
the plant is operated close to capacity. Under
such conditions an average variable cost curve
declines steadily until the point of capacity
output is reached. A marginal cost curve derived
from such an average cost curve lies below the
average cost curve at all scales of operation
short of capacity, a fact that makes it
physically impossible for an enterprise to
determine a scale of operations by equating
marginal cost and marginal revenues. (Eiteman
1947) - As Sraffa put it
48Actual firms behaviour
- Business men, who regard themselves as being
subject to competitive conditions, would consider
absurd the assertion that the limit to their
production is to be found in the internal
conditions of production in their firm, which do
not permit of the production of a greater
quantity without an increase in cost. The chief
obstacle against which they have to contend when
they want gradually to increase their production
does not lie in the cost of production-which,
indeed, generally favours them in that
direction-but in the difficulty of selling the
larger quantity of goods without reducing the
price, or without having to face increased
marketing expenses. (Sraffa 1926) - See also Kalecki 1937 Principle of increasing
risk
49Profit maximising firms?
- Most recent survey work by Blinder et al 1998
- Over 89 per cent of respondents indicated that
marginal costs either declined or stayed
constant with changes in output (sometimes
involving discrete jumps). Finally, only four of
200 enterprises had both elastic demand curves
and increasing marginal costs. (Downward Lee
2001, reviewing Blinder) - Fixed costs appear to be more important in the
real world than in economic theory. (Blinder) - Economists no longer have an excuse to ignore
this research
50Conclusion
- Neoclassical economics has at its core a theory
of firm behaviour which is - mathematically erroneous
- misleading guide to profit maximisation in a
dynamic economy - contradicted by empirical research
- Economics needs a theory of firm behaviour which
is - Empirically grounded
- Dynamic, and cognisant of uncertainty
- Best existing alternative is Post-Keynesian
theory of the firm (Lee 1998) - much more remains to be done
- but to start, we must abandon erroneous beliefs
51Conclusion
- As Samuelson said in summarising the Capital
Controversies of the 1960s - If all this causes headaches for those nostalgic
for the old time parables of neoclassical
writing, we must remind ourselves that scholars
are not born to live an easy existence. We must
respect, and appraise, the facts of life.
(Samuelson 1966)
52Acknowledgements
- Geoff Fishburn
- conjectural variation argument
- John Legge
- perturbation analysis proof of non-profit-maximisi
ng conjecture - producer surplus analysis
53References
- Bishop, R.L., (1948). 'Cost discontinuities,
declining costs and marginal analysis', American
Economic Review 38 607-617. - Clapham, J.H., (1922a). 'Of empty economic
boxes', Economic Journal, 32 303-314. - Clapham, J.H., (1922b). 'The economic boxes - a
rejoinder', Economic Journal, 32 560-563. - Clark, J.B. (1898). 'The future of economic
theory', Quarterly Journal of Economics, 13
1-14). - Eiteman, W.J., (1947). 'Factors determining the
location of the least cost point', American
Economic Review 37 910-918. - Eiteman, W.J., (1948). 'The least cost point,
capacity and marginal analysis a rejoinder',
American Economic Review 38 899-904. - Eiteman, W.J. And Guthrie, G.E., (1952). 'The
shape of the average cost curve', American
Economic Review 42 832-838. - Groenewegen, P., (1995). A soaring eagle Alfred
Marshall 1842-1924, Edward Elgar, Cheltenham. - Haines, W.W., (1948). 'Capacity production and
the least cost point', American Economic Review
38 617-624. - Harrod, R.F., (1934). Doctrines of Imperfect
Competition, The Quarterly Journal of Economics,
48 442-470 - Kalecki, M., 1937, "The principle of increasing
risk", Economica, 440-447. - Keen, S., (2001). Debunking Economics, Pluto
Press Zed Books, Sydney. - Langlois, C., (1989). 'Markup pricing versus
marginalism a controversy revisited', Journal of
Post Keynesian Economics 12 127-151.
54References
- Lee, F., (1996). 'Pricing and the business
enterprise', in C.W. Whalen (ed.), Political
Economy for the 21st century, ME Sharpe, Armonk. - Lee, F., (1998). Post Keynesian Price Theory,
Cambridge University Press, Cambridge. - Marshall, A., (1907 1961). Principles of
economics. Macmillan, London. - Means, G.C, (1972). 'The administered-price
thesis reconsidered', American Economic Review
62 292-306. - Pigou, A.C., (1922). 'Empty economic boxes - a
reply', Economic Journal, 36 459-465. - Pigou, A.C., (1927). 'The law of diminishing and
increasing cost', Economic Journal, 41 188-197 - Pigou, A.C., (1928). 'An analysis of supply',
Economic Journal, 42 238-257. - Robertson D.H., (1924). 'Those empty boxes',
Economic Journal, 34 16-31. - Robertson D.H., (1930). 'The trees of the
forest', Economic Journal, 44 80-89. - Robbins, L. (1928). 'The representative firm',
Economic Journal, 42 387-404. - Samuelson, P., (1966). 'A Summing Up', Quarterly
Journal of Economics, 80 568-583. - Shove, G.F., (1930). 'The representative firm and
increasing returns', Economic Journal, 44
93-116. - Sraffa, P. (1926). 'The Law of returns under
competitive conditions', Economic Journal, 40
538-550. - Sraffa, P. (1930). 'The trees of the forest - a
criticism', Economic Journal, 44 89-92. - Shepherd, W.G., (1984). ''Contestability' vs.
competition', American Economic Review, 74
572-587. - Sato, K., (1979). 'A note on capital and output
aggregation in a general equilibrium model of
production', Econometrica 47 1559-1568.