Why economics must abandon - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

1 / 54
About This Presentation
Title:

Why economics must abandon

Description:

– PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:61
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 55
Provided by: debunking
Category:

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: Why economics must abandon


1
Why economics must abandon
  • its theory of the firm

2
Not a new call
  • Clapham 1922, Sraffa 1926, 1930
  • I am trying to find what are the assumptions
    implicit in Marshall's theory if Mr Robertson
    regards them as extremely unreal, I sympathise
    with him. We seem to be agreed that the theory
    cannot be interpreted in a way which makes it
    logically self-consistent and, at the same time,
    reconciles it with the facts it sets out to
    explain. Mr Robertson's remedy is to discard
    mathematics, and he suggests that my remedy is to
    discard the facts perhaps I ought to have
    explained that, in the circumstances, I think it
    is Marshall's theory that should be discarded.
    (Sraffa 1930 93)

3
Sraffas argument
  • Two key assumptions of short run theory of the
    firm
  • Independent supply and demand curves
  • Diminishing marginal productivity
  • in practice are mutually inconsistent
  • Independent supply and demand curves realistic
    when define industry narrowly (e.g., wheat)
  • but then increased production will result from
    industry drawing marginal doses of allegedly
    fixed resource from other industries, inputs
    lying fallow
  • Constant returns, constant costs

4
Sraffas argument
  • If we next take an industry which employs only a
    small part of the 'constant factor' (which
    appears more appropriate for the study of the
    particular equilibrium of a single industry), we
    find that a (small) increase in its production is
    generally met much more by drawing 'marginal
    doses' of the constant factor from other
    industries than by intensifying its own
    utilisation of it thus the increase in cost will
    be practically negligible (Sraffa 1926)

5
Sraffas argument
  • Diminishing marginal productivity realistic when
    industry defined widely (e.g., Agriculture)
  • Input of fixed resource can be increased only
    with difficulty
  • But then change in output of this industry will
    affect income distribution
  • change in income distribution will affect demand
  • impossible to ignore feedback effects between
    supply and demand

6
Sraffas argument
  • If in the production of a particular commodity a
    considerable part of a factor is employed, the
    total amount of which is fixed or can be
    increased only at a more than proportional cost,
    a small increase in the production of the
    commodity will necessitate a more intense
    utilisation of that factor, and this will affect
    in the same manner the cost of the commodity in
    question and the cost of the other commodities
    into the production of which that factor enters
    and since commodities into the production of
    which a common special factor enters are
    frequently, to a certain extent, substitutes for
    one another ... the modification in their price
    will not be without appreciable effects upon
    demand in the industry concerned. (Sraffa 1926)

7
Sraffas argument
  • Implication of Sraffas argument constant
    marginal costs in the short run
  • In normal cases the cost of production of
    commodities produced competitively ... must be
    regarded as constant in respect of small
    variation in the quantity produced. And so, as a
    simple way of approaching the problem of
    competitive value, the old and now obsolete
    theory which makes it dependent on the cost of
    production alone appears to hold its ground as
    the best available. (Sraffa 1926)
  • Sraffas argument largely ignored by profession
  • replies focused on his critique of concept of
    diminishing returns in long run rather than short
    run

8
Sraffas argument
  • Subsequent papers (Pigou 1922, 1927, 1928
    Robertson 1924, 1930 Robbins 1932, Harrod 1934
    etc.) accept that
  • diminishing marginal productivity in the short
    run as unarguable
  • theory of perfect competition watertight
  • Ditto any introductory to advanced micro text
    today
  • Even advanced non-PC theory implicitly treats PC
    as ideal
  • Why? The apparently conclusive mathematics
  • It is not conclusive
  • Recap argument, firstly w.r.t. perfect
    competition

9
Conventional explanation of PMC
  • Unique attributes of PC industry are
  • Supply curve exists (sum of MC curves)
  • Price set by supply and demand
  • MRP for individual firm

Sm point of supply for this D curve
Sum MarginalCost PCSupply Curve PC
Price
MarginalCost Monopoly(not Supply Curve)
Pm
Ppc
D
Marginal Revenue
Qm
Qpc
  • Monopoly/Monopolistic competition
  • No supply curve
  • PgtMC,MR for individual firm and market

Quantity
  • How are unique attributes of PC established?

10
Conventional explanation of PMC
  • Start with market supply and demand curves
  • Determine equilibrium quantity and price by
    intersection of two curves

Price
Supply
Pe
  • Assume this is the price taken as given by PC
    firms

Demand
Quantity
Qe
  • Show that the MC curve of the PC firm is its
    supply curve, assuming demand horizontal

Price
Marginal Cost
Pe
  • Aggregate firm supply curves to determine market
    supply curve

qe
quantity
11
Conventional explanation of PMC
  • But potentially circular logic here

Start with market supply curve
Each step depends on the other
Derive individual firm supply curve
  • Argument that PC firms profit maximise by setting
    PMC should be provable at level of individual
    firm alone.
  • If theory correct, should be provable that any
    change in output from qe reduces profit

Over to Mathematica
Skip summary of results
12
So Mathematica tell us
  • Given linear demand and supply (for simplicity
    w.l.o.g.)
  • And standard definitions of Total Revenue,
    Profit, alleged profit maximising levels of
    output
  • Test alleged monopoly equilibrium
  • Enigmatic concise confirmation
  • Perfect competition equilibrium
  • Is true if and only if

13
So Mathematica tell us
  • Consider impact of perturbation of dq from
    monopoly profit maximisation point on profit
  • Profit changes by clearly negative amount,
    whatever sign of dq
  • Consider impact of perturbation of dq from
    perfect competition profit maximisation point on
    profit
  • Profit changes by

14
Conventional explanation of PMC
  • Theory intact if and only if dP/dq0
  • but given assumption of atomism, dP/dqdP/dQ
  • Therefore
  • And
  • Profit falls if output rises past where PMC
  • Profit rises if output falls below where PMC
  • PMC is not a (profit maximising) equilibrium

15
Logical errors in conventional theory
  • Neoclassical micro assumes no feedback from
    individual firm to market price
  • But feedback necessary if market demand curve
    downward sloping
  • Feedback affects all firms
  • aggregate effect sums to same behaviour as single
    firm given valid identical cost curves
  • why should large number of rational agents reach
    different conclusion to single rational agent,
    given same data?
  • Consider the Friedman argument

16
Profit maximising firms?
  • Excellent predictions would be yielded by the
    hypothesis that the billiard player made his
    shots as if he knew the complicated mathematical
    formulas , could make lightning calculations
    from the formulas, and could then make the balls
    travel in the direction indicated by the
    formulas. Our confidence in this hypothesis is
    not based on the belief that billiard players,
    even expert ones, can or do go through the
    process described it derives rather from the
    belief that, unless in some way or other they
    were capable of reaching essentially the same
    result, they would not in fact be expert billiard
    players. (Friedman The methodology of positive
    economics)

Miltons Pool Hall
Skip summary of results
17
Miltons Pool Hall
  • Simulation of an industry with
  • Fixed linear demand curve
  • Constant marginal cost (see later for rising MC)
  • Given number of firms
  • Each firm starts with randomly determined output
    level
  • Each firm varies own output by randomly
    determined amount (ive or -ive)
  • If new level of profit higher, keeps changing
    output in same direction
  • Otherwise, changes in opposite direction

18
Miltons Pool Hall
  • Model 1 simple mechanism
  • Firm always changes output by same amount
  • Model 2 (slightly more) sophisticated mechanism
  • Firm tries randomly determined amount, with range
    of random variable falling each iteration
  • In both cases, output and price converge to
    monopoly level (MCMR), not perfect
    competition level (PMC), regardless of number
    of firms
  • Market definitions monopoly price 80, PC
    price 50

19
Miltons Pool Hall the program
  • Random initial amounts

No. of firms
Calculate profits
Random adjustments
Calculate new profits
Work out direction of change
For 50 iterations
Make directed random adjustments of diminishing
size
20
Miltons Pool Hall the outcome
Market converges to monopoly price regardless of
number of firms
21
Simulation Results
  • With constant marginal cost
  • Number of firms makes no difference
  • output converges to monopoly level, not perfect
    competition
  • With rising marginal cost?
  • Market definitions monopoly price 90, PC
    price 80

22
Miltons Pool Hall the outcome (2)
  • Price appears to converge to PC level for gt 1 firm
  • But
  • Are cost functions the same?

23
Miltons Pool Hall the outcome (2)
  • Apparent difference in behaviour illusory
  • Difference in output level price due to
    difference in cost functions
  • An aggregation problem

24
Supply aggregation
  • Number of firms does make a difference, but
  • cause is difference in total cost functions, not
    MRMC for monopoly, PMC for PC
  • Supply aggregation (so that MC for monopoly
    identical to sum of MC for PC) only possible with
    horizontal marginal cost

25
Supply aggregation
  • Monopoly/PC welfare comparison requires identical
    MC curves, otherwise

Price
Ppc
Pm
Demand/Price
Marginal Revenue
Qpc
Qm
Quantity
26
Supply aggregation
  • WLOG, consider n PC firms employing x workers
  • MC derived from MP
  • identity of MC requires identity of MP
  • TP can only differ by a constant
  • constant zero if variable factor is labour
  • So we have
  • n competitive firms
  • f PC production function
  • g monopoly production function

Euler's equation
27
Supply aggregation
  • Differentiate w.r.t. n

Consider ratio
Substitute
28
Supply aggregation
  • Integrate w.r.t. u
  • Take exponentials
  • So g a staight line
  • Consider f
  • f same straight line
  • Differentiate marginal product a constant,
    therefore marginal cost a constant

29
Supply aggregation
  • Only supply curve for which sum of marginal cost
    curves of small firms identical to marginal cost
    curve of single firm is constant identical
    marginal cost
  • Static profit maximisation (with identical MC
    curves) occurs where PgtMC, MCMR for both
    monopoly and competitive industries
  • Neoclassical theory of the firm thus
  • logically flawed
  • devoid of content
  • Contradictions self-evident once you know to look

30
There for all to see
  • Conventional welfare comparison of monopoly to PC
    has monopoly producing to maximum profit, but PC
    producing past that point in the aggregate
  • PC output past point where market MC market MR
    must be produced at a loss, yet no loss shown at
    firm level

?
?
31
There for all to see
  • Producer surplus shows the fallacy
  • Collective gain in producer surplus from reducing
    output from PMCgtMR to PgtMRMC obvious

P
S
Loss
PgtMC
Gain
PMC
D
Qe
Qe-DQ
Q
P
Loss
P where MRgtMC
MC
Gain
P where MRMC
  • Producer surplus maximised at MRMC level
  • PMC only possible with individually and
    collectively irrational behaviour

D
MR
Qe
Qe-DQ
Q
32
Root of the fallacy
  • Models of PC and monopoly identical at firm level
  • Sole difference is presence of market marginal
    revenue curve in monopoly, absence in PC

Perfect competition
P
S
P gt MRMC
PMC
D
MR
  • But market MR curve exists independent of number
    of firms in industry

Qe
Qe
P
Monopoly
MC
  • Only way to get MRP at firm level is for it to
    apply at industry level (horizontal market demand
    curve)

P gt MRMC
D
  • PC theory based on equating infinitesimals to zero

MR
Qe
33
Theoretical consequences
  • Supply and demand analysis not viable
  • supply curve cant be constructed
  • can only show point of supply for given
    (aggregate) MC and given demand
  • increase in demand could lower market price

Monopoly, etc.
Perfect Competition
  • Minimum of 3 curves needed to determine
    price/quantity

MarginalCost
marginalcost
S1
s2
s1
S2
d2
d1
supplycurve
D2
D1
MR2
MR1
34
Theoretical consequences
  • Welfare ideals unachievable
  • equality of marginal benefits to marginal costs
    impossible even under perfect competition
  • all market structures will have marginal benefits
    gt marginal costs in profit maximising equilibrium
  • market outcomes will not maximise social benefits
  • How to interpret price-taking behaviour?
  • Firms may take market price as given, but
  • price does not equate price and marginal cost
  • instead reflects markup in that industry
  • For viable firms, price will exceed marginal cost
  • LongConclusion
  • ShortConclusion
  • But at least MCMR rule maximises profit, right?
  • Wrong

35
Dynamics of profit maximisation
  • Profit maximisation rule invalid in dynamic
    setting
  • MCMR rule tells how to maximise profit w.r.t.
    quantity
  • Real firms more interested in maximising profits
    w.r.t. time
  • Time-based rule requires MR gt MC.
  • Time-based analysis shows that profit
    maximisation rules too complex to be a guide to
    determining output, even if diminishing marginal
    returns applies

36
Profit maximising firms?
  • Neoclassical logic
  • Profit a function of quantity
  • Price decreasing and cost increasing functions of
    quantity
  • Maximise profit by setting marginal revenue equal
    to marginal cost
  • Mathematical logic
  • Profit at least a function of quantity and time
  • quantity also a function of time
  • Dynamic goal maximisation of rate of growth of
    profit

37
Profit maximising firms?
  • Rate of growth of profit is
  • This is MR-MC
  • Substituting
  • Under what circumstances will setting MRMC
    maximise the rate of growth of profit?
  • Is this condition relevant to a dynamic economy?
  • No, it is the definition of a static one

No way!
  • Are the values of MR and MC relevant to the
    conditions for maximising the rate of growth of
    the rate of profit?

38
Dynamics of profit maximisation
  • Assuming, for the sake of argument, that the rate
    of growth of profit has a single maximum, set its
    differential to zero
  • Assuming, for the sake of argument, that the rate
    of growth of the rate of profit is monotonic, the
    rate of change of the rate of growth of profit is
    zero where (courtesy of Mathematica)

39
Profit maximising firms?
  • No mathematician in her right mind would advise a
    firm to manage this function!
  • Pulling MC and MR out of this, we derive

40
Dynamics of profit maximisation
  • For profit maximisation

Mathematica
  • Useful rule?
  • Of course not too complex, and firm cant know
    dq/dt anyway but regardless, neoclassical rule
  • invalid if dq/dtgt0
  • would cause lower rate of growth of profits if
    followed in practice.
  • Supports Sraffas 1926 argument MC MR
    irrelevant to firms output decisions

41
Dynamics of profit maximisation
  • Founders of neoclassical analysis realised that
    concepts of statics and short run inadequate
    proper analysis should be dynamic.
  • Only reason to imagine a static economy was to
    make analysis tractable
  • Marshall ...dynamics includes statics... But
    the statical solution is simpler... it may
    afford useful preparation and training for the
    more difficult dynamical solution and it may be
    the first step towards a provisional and partial
    solution in problems so complex that a complete
    dynamical solution is beyond our attainment.
    (1907, in Groenewegen 1996 432)

42
Dynamics of profit maximisation
  • Jevons If we wished to have a complete solution
    ... we should have to treat it as a problem of
    dynamics. But it would surely be absurd to
    attempt the more difficult question when the more
    easy one is yet so imperfectly within our power.
    (1871 1911 93)
  • J.B. Clark on the future of economics A point
    on which opinions differ is the capacity of the
    pure theory of Political Economy for progress.
    There seems to be growing impression that, as a
    mere statement of principles, this science will
    fairly soon be complete It is with this view
    that I take issue. The great coming development
    of economic theory is to take place, I venture to
    assert, through the statement and solution of
    dynamic problems (Clark 1898)

43
Dynamics of profit maximisation
  • Statics has clearly led to misleading and
    irrelevant advice re profit maximisation
  • Dynamic answer different to static one
  • This is a common result in mathematics
  • Static and dynamic results only coincide when
    relevant system is stable
  • Stable in this context means a no-growth
    economy
  • Unstable means growing economy, and MCMR
    irrelevant
  • So if economists cant provide guidance for firms
    from a priori theory of cost and revenue
    functions, what can it do?

44
What can economics do?
  • Become an empirical discipline ask firms what
    they actually do
  • Dominant tendency in economics is a priori
    analysis work out what must be from prior
    axioms
  • A pre-Galilean approach to science
  • Why not experiment/survey?
  • Numerous researchers have done so, and found that
    MC/MR analysis irrelevant to real firms
  • Andrews, Bishop, Downie, Eiteman, Eiteman and
    Guthrie, Haines, Hall Hitch, Lee, Means,
    Tucker, the Oxford Economic Research Group,
    (see Lee 1998 for full details), Blinder et al
    1998

45
Actual firms behaviour
  • Empirical researchers found
  • average costs of production declined as output
    rose
  • marginal costs were always well below their
    average costs, and substantially smaller than
    marginal revenue, and
  • concept of a demand curve (and therefore its
    derivative marginal revenue) was simply
    irrelevant.

46
Actual firms behaviour
  • Eiteman Guthrie (1952) showed factory managers
    graphs indicating possible different cost curve
    relations
  • Outcome was
  • Businessmen viewed the economists concepts of
    perfect competition and monopoly as virtual
    nonsense and the product of the itching
    imaginations of uninformed and inexperienced
    armchair theorizers. (Lee 1998, citing Tucker)

47
Actual firms behaviour
  • Major reason why economic a priori did not apply?
  • Engineers designed factories so as to cause the
    variable factor to be used most efficiently when
    the plant is operated close to capacity. Under
    such conditions an average variable cost curve
    declines steadily until the point of capacity
    output is reached. A marginal cost curve derived
    from such an average cost curve lies below the
    average cost curve at all scales of operation
    short of capacity, a fact that makes it
    physically impossible for an enterprise to
    determine a scale of operations by equating
    marginal cost and marginal revenues. (Eiteman
    1947)
  • As Sraffa put it

48
Actual firms behaviour
  • Business men, who regard themselves as being
    subject to competitive conditions, would consider
    absurd the assertion that the limit to their
    production is to be found in the internal
    conditions of production in their firm, which do
    not permit of the production of a greater
    quantity without an increase in cost. The chief
    obstacle against which they have to contend when
    they want gradually to increase their production
    does not lie in the cost of production-which,
    indeed, generally favours them in that
    direction-but in the difficulty of selling the
    larger quantity of goods without reducing the
    price, or without having to face increased
    marketing expenses. (Sraffa 1926)
  • See also Kalecki 1937 Principle of increasing
    risk

49
Profit maximising firms?
  • Most recent survey work by Blinder et al 1998
  • Over 89 per cent of respondents indicated that
    marginal costs either declined or stayed
    constant with changes in output (sometimes
    involving discrete jumps). Finally, only four of
    200 enterprises had both elastic demand curves
    and increasing marginal costs. (Downward Lee
    2001, reviewing Blinder)
  • Fixed costs appear to be more important in the
    real world than in economic theory. (Blinder)
  • Economists no longer have an excuse to ignore
    this research

50
Conclusion
  • Neoclassical economics has at its core a theory
    of firm behaviour which is
  • mathematically erroneous
  • misleading guide to profit maximisation in a
    dynamic economy
  • contradicted by empirical research
  • Economics needs a theory of firm behaviour which
    is
  • Empirically grounded
  • Dynamic, and cognisant of uncertainty
  • Best existing alternative is Post-Keynesian
    theory of the firm (Lee 1998)
  • much more remains to be done
  • but to start, we must abandon erroneous beliefs

51
Conclusion
  • As Samuelson said in summarising the Capital
    Controversies of the 1960s
  • If all this causes headaches for those nostalgic
    for the old time parables of neoclassical
    writing, we must remind ourselves that scholars
    are not born to live an easy existence. We must
    respect, and appraise, the facts of life.
    (Samuelson 1966)

52
Acknowledgements
  • Geoff Fishburn
  • conjectural variation argument
  • John Legge
  • perturbation analysis proof of non-profit-maximisi
    ng conjecture
  • producer surplus analysis

53
References
  • Bishop, R.L., (1948). 'Cost discontinuities,
    declining costs and marginal analysis', American
    Economic Review 38 607-617.
  • Clapham, J.H., (1922a). 'Of empty economic
    boxes', Economic Journal, 32 303-314.
  • Clapham, J.H., (1922b). 'The economic boxes - a
    rejoinder', Economic Journal, 32 560-563.
  • Clark, J.B. (1898). 'The future of economic
    theory', Quarterly Journal of Economics, 13
    1-14).
  • Eiteman, W.J., (1947). 'Factors determining the
    location of the least cost point', American
    Economic Review 37 910-918.
  • Eiteman, W.J., (1948). 'The least cost point,
    capacity and marginal analysis a rejoinder',
    American Economic Review 38 899-904.
  • Eiteman, W.J. And Guthrie, G.E., (1952). 'The
    shape of the average cost curve', American
    Economic Review 42 832-838.
  • Groenewegen, P., (1995). A soaring eagle Alfred
    Marshall 1842-1924, Edward Elgar, Cheltenham.
  • Haines, W.W., (1948). 'Capacity production and
    the least cost point', American Economic Review
    38 617-624.
  • Harrod, R.F., (1934). Doctrines of Imperfect
    Competition, The Quarterly Journal of Economics,
    48 442-470
  • Kalecki, M., 1937, "The principle of increasing
    risk", Economica, 440-447.
  • Keen, S., (2001). Debunking Economics, Pluto
    Press Zed Books, Sydney.
  • Langlois, C., (1989). 'Markup pricing versus
    marginalism a controversy revisited', Journal of
    Post Keynesian Economics 12 127-151.

54
References
  • Lee, F., (1996). 'Pricing and the business
    enterprise', in C.W. Whalen (ed.), Political
    Economy for the 21st century, ME Sharpe, Armonk.
  • Lee, F., (1998). Post Keynesian Price Theory,
    Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.
  • Marshall, A., (1907 1961). Principles of
    economics. Macmillan, London.
  • Means, G.C, (1972). 'The administered-price
    thesis reconsidered', American Economic Review
    62 292-306.
  • Pigou, A.C., (1922). 'Empty economic boxes - a
    reply', Economic Journal, 36 459-465.
  • Pigou, A.C., (1927). 'The law of diminishing and
    increasing cost', Economic Journal, 41 188-197
  • Pigou, A.C., (1928). 'An analysis of supply',
    Economic Journal, 42 238-257.
  • Robertson D.H., (1924). 'Those empty boxes',
    Economic Journal, 34 16-31.
  • Robertson D.H., (1930). 'The trees of the
    forest', Economic Journal, 44 80-89.
  • Robbins, L. (1928). 'The representative firm',
    Economic Journal, 42 387-404.
  • Samuelson, P., (1966). 'A Summing Up', Quarterly
    Journal of Economics, 80 568-583.
  • Shove, G.F., (1930). 'The representative firm and
    increasing returns', Economic Journal, 44
    93-116.
  • Sraffa, P. (1926). 'The Law of returns under
    competitive conditions', Economic Journal, 40
    538-550.
  • Sraffa, P. (1930). 'The trees of the forest - a
    criticism', Economic Journal, 44 89-92.
  • Shepherd, W.G., (1984). ''Contestability' vs.
    competition', American Economic Review, 74
    572-587.
  • Sato, K., (1979). 'A note on capital and output
    aggregation in a general equilibrium model of
    production', Econometrica 47 1559-1568.
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)
About PowerShow.com