The IS-LM model

1 / 96
About This Presentation
Title:

The IS-LM model

Description:

The IS-LM model The model The IS-LM model was developed in 1937 by John R. Hicks in an attempt to authentically interpret the General Theory of Employment ... – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:45
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 97
Provided by: Geor316
Learn more at: http://people.ucsc.edu

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: The IS-LM model


1
The IS-LM model
2
The model
  • The IS-LM model was developed in 1937 by John R.
    Hicks in an attempt to authentically interpret
    the General Theory of Employment, Interest and
    Money, the famous book published by John Maynard
    Keynes in 1936.

3
The model
  • The model tries to explain the movement of output
    and interest rate in the short run.
  • To this end, it uses two curves the IS (short
    for Investment and Saving) and the LM (short for
    Liquidity and Money).
  • The IS curve represents equilibrium in the goods
    market.
  • The LM curve represents equilibrium in the
    financial markets.

4
The IS curve
  • We will try to use the goods market to establish
    a relationship between the interest rate and
    output.
  • We already know from introductory macro that
    output in a closed economy is the sum of
    consumption (C), investment (I) and government
    expenditures (G).
  • Y C I G

5
The IS curve (the Keynesian cross)
  • We also know that output (Y) is by definition
    equal to income and that it represents the amount
    of spending undertaken by households, firms and
    the government.
  • But, how much do we want to spend? In other
    words, what is our demand for goods and services?
  • If we denote demand with Z, then
  • Z C I G
  • So, demand (like output) is simply equal to the
    sum of consumption, investment and government
    expenditures.

6
The IS curve (the Keynesian cross)
  • If we try to elaborate a bit more on the form of
    consumption, we can say that consumption must
    depend on our disposable income.
  • Our disposable income must be equal to total
    income (Y) minus the taxes that we pay to the
    government (T).
  • So, consumption is a function of our disposable
    income C(Y-T).

7
The IS curve (the Keynesian cross)
  • What if we want to be more specific about the
    functional form of the consumption function.
  • Lets assume that we must cosume something anyway
    in order to survive, like food. We call this
    amount autonomous consumption and lets denote it
    by c0.
  • The rest of our consumption depends on our
    disposable income (Y-T). It is reasonable to
    assume that we consume a percentage of our
    disposable income and that we save the rest of
    it. We call this percentage marginal propensity
    to consume (MPC) and lets denote it by c1. Since
    we consume less than our disposable income, c1
    must be a number between 0 and 1. So, the non
    autonomous part of consumption must look like
    that c1(Y-T).
  • Therefore, consumption in general must be equal
    to
  • C c0 c1(Y-T)

8
The IS curve (the Keynesian cross)
  • If this is the form of consumption, then demand
    in total must be equal to
  • Z C I G gt
  • Z c0 c1(Y-T) I G gt
  • Z (c0 - c1T I G) c1Y
  • This last equation tells us that demand is equal
    to a sum of some variables that are exogenously
    given, namely
  • c0 the amount of autonomous consumption,
  • c1T the amount of taxes times MPC,
  • I investment, which for now we can assume that
    it is constant, and
  • G government expenditures.
  • We will call this whole expression (c0 - c1T I
    G), autonomous spending.
  • It also tells us that demand is a positive
    function of income (Y) and, moreover, that the
    slope of this positive function is c1, which is
    less than one. So the slope of the demand is
    flatter than the 45o line (the slope of which is
    1).

9
The IS curve (the Keynesian cross)
  • Now we have the first building block of the
    Keynesian cross. We are going to graph the demand
    as a function of income. We already proved
    earlier that the demand is a positive function of
    income and this is what we are going to graph now.

10
The IS curve (the Keynesian cross)
Z
This is a picture of the demand as a function of
income. The vertical intercept of the line ZZ
which represents the demand, is the autonomous
spending and its slope is the marginal propensity
to consume.
ZZ
Slope MPC
1
Vertical intercept autonomous spending
Y
11
The IS curve (the Keynesian cross)
  • Our economy is in equilibrium when actual
    production is equal to the demand, i.e. Y Z.
  • The only place that generally satisfies this
    equilibrium condition is the 45o line in our
    previous graph. So, our equilibrium must be on
    that line.

12
The IS curve (the Keynesian cross)
  • If we assume further, that there is no inventory
    investment, then output ( income) must always be
    equal to the demand.
  • So, in that case, not only are we always on the
    45o line, but also always on the intersection of
    the demand function with the 45o line, which is
    our equilibrium point.

13
The IS curve (the Keynesian cross)
Actual Production YZ
Z
This is a picture of the Keynesian cross. We
observe that in equilibrium, demand is equal to
income and production along the 45o line. In our
model, since there are no inventories, we are
always in equilibrium.
ZZ
Y
45o
Y
Y
14
The IS curve (the multiplier)
  • If we combine the equilibrium condition Y Z,
    with the expression for the demand that we
    derived earlier, Z c0 c1(Y-T) I G, we
    get
  • Y c0 c1(Y-T) I G gt
  • Y c0 c1Y - c1T I G gt
  • Y - c1Y c0 - c1T I G gt
  • Y(1 - c1) c0 - c1T I G gt
  • Y 1/(1 - c1) (c0 - c1T I G)

15
The IS curve (the multiplier)
  • We have already called the (c0 - c1T I G)
    part of the above equation, autonomous spending.
  • Now, we will give a name to the 1/(1 - c1) part
    and we will call it the multiplier. The reason
    for that name is that this fraction is greater
    than one (remember that 0ltc1lt1).

16
The IS curve (the multiplier)
  • Therefore, whatever the change is in any of the
    parts of autonomous spending, the change in
    output is a multiple of that change.
  • So, if the government, e.g., decides to increase
    G by an amount x, this will result in an increase
    of Y by x times the multiplier.
  • Graphically, the demand will shift up by as much
    as the change in autonomous spending (the
    vertical intercept) but output will increase by
    more than that.

17
The IS curve (the multiplier)
  • The size of the multiplier obviously depends on
    c1, the marginal propensity to consume. The
    larger the MPC, the smaller the denominator and
    the larger the multiplier.
  • Graphically, a large MPC corresponds to a steeply
    sloped demand curve. Shifts of a steep demand
    curve have large effects on income.
  • A small MPC corresponds to a relatively flatter
    demand curve. Shifts of a flatter demand curve
    have relatively milder effects on income.
  • We will now graph those two cases.

18
The IS curve (the multiplier)
The Keynesian cross with a flat demand (small
MPC). The shift in demand has a milder effect on
output.
The Keynesian cross with a steep demand (large
MPC). The shift in demand has a large effect on
output.
Actual Production YZ
Actual Production YZ
Z
Z
ZZ2
Y2
ZZ1
ZZ2
Y2
Y1
ZZ1
Y1
45o
45o
Y
Y1
Y
Y1
Y2
Y2
19
Deriving the IS curve
  • The Keynesian cross is an important building
    block toward the IS curve but our mission is not
    accomplished yet.
  • However, from this point the derivation of the IS
    curve is straightforward. It relies on the
    relaxation of an assumption that we made earlier,
    namely that the level of investment is constant.

20
Deriving the IS curve
  • Constant investment is a clear simplification of
    the Keynesian cross model. We already know that
    investment is not constant but rather a negative
    function of the interest rate.
  • At this point we also add that investment is also
    positively related with output. The line of
    reasoning is that as firms see their volume of
    sales going up, they will undertake more
    investment to accommodate this increase. But the
    level of sales is just proportional to output,
    since if output is increasing, more goods are
    going to be sold and if output is decreasing less
    goods are going to be sold. So, the bottom line
    is that we observe a positive relationship
    between the level of investment and the level of
    output.
  • Therefore, investment is a negative function of
    the interest rate and a positive function of
    output. In symbols we write
  • I I(Y,i)

21
Deriving the IS curve
  • Focusing on the interest rate, we can say that if
    the interest rate increases, this reduces the
    level of investment, shifts down the demand and
    consequently, through the multiplier, reduces the
    level of income.
  • On the other hand, if the interest rate
    decreases, the level of investment increases, the
    demand shifts up and the level of income
    increases.

22
Deriving the IS curve
  • We have therefore shown that there exists a
    negative relationship between the interest rate
    and income.
  • This negative relationship is what is known as
    the IS curve.
  • The mathematical form of the IS curve is called
    the IS relation and it is simply
  • Y C(Y-T) I(Y,i) G
  • A more specific form of this equation is the
    already familiar to us equation
  • Y 1/(1 - c1) (c0 - c1T I G)
  • This is the graphical derivation of the IS curve.

23
Deriving the IS curve
Actual Production YZ
Z
A decrease in the interest rate increases the
level of investment (Panel A), which shifts up
the demand and increases income (Panel B). The IS
curve sums up these movements in the goods market
(Panel C).
ZZ2
Y2
Panel B
ZZ1
Y1
45o
Y1
Y2
Y
i
i
i1
i1
Panel A
Panel C
i2
IS
i2
I
Y
I
Y1
Y2
I1
I2
24
Shifts of the IS curve
  • As always in economics, here too we are
    interested in curve shifts.
  • So, we are going to mix things up a bit, shift
    the curves around and see what happens.

25
Shifts of the IS curve
  • So, what could possibly move the IS curve?
  • First, lets recall the IS relation, Y C(Y-T)
    I(Y,i) G, the general equation that describes
    the IS curve.
  • Which part of this equation could move the IS
    curve?
  • Maybe, its better if we start by what could by
    no means move the IS curve income (Y) and the
    interest rate (i).
  • Why? Because, these are the endogenous variables
    of our model. These are the variable that we are
    trying to explain. They are the variables on the
    two axes of our graph (like price and quantity in
    a supply and demand diagram). So, if these two
    variables move, we move along the curve. We dont
    shift it.

26
Shifts of the IS curve
  • So, what could move the IS curve is any of the
    other variables that are exogenous, i.e. they are
    taken as given outside the model, namely
  • G, government expenditures (variable controlled
    by the government),
  • T, taxes (variable controlled by the government),
  • C, consumption patterns that are independent of
    disposable income, if for example, the households
    decide to consume more because an asteroid is
    going to hit the earth (variable controlled by
    household preferences), and
  • I, investment patterns that are independent of
    the interest rate and income, if for example
    firms go into an unexplained investing spree
    (variable controlled by the animal spirits of the
    investors).

27
Shifts of the IS curve
  • Out of those four parameters, we are mostly
    interested in the first two (G and T), because it
    is only those that policy makers can control. The
    other two cannot be affected directly by
    government policies.
  • So, our analysis will be primarily focused on
    government expenditures and taxes.
  • However, just bear in mind that changes in
    consumption and investment patterns affect the IS
    curve in exactly the same way as changes in
    government expenditures.

28
What happens if the government decides to
increase government expenditures (G?)?
  • We will use the Keynesian cross to explore the
    effects of such a move.
  • First, lets recall the equation for the demand
    that we derived earlier
  • Z (c0 - c1T I G) c1Y
  • If, ceteris paribus, the government decides to
    increase G (by ?G), then it is obvious that the
    demand curve would shift up by an amount equal to
    ?G. The vertical intercept would move up by ?G
    but the slope would remain the same.

29
What happens if the government decides to
increase government expenditures (G?)?
  • But would happen to income after this shift of
    the demand curve?
  • Now, we have to recall the IS relation in the
    specific form that we also mentioned earlier
  • Y 1/(1 - c1) (c0 - c1T I G)
  • If G?, then Y would go up by as much as ?G times
    the multiplier 1/(1 - c1), so by more than ?G.
  • So, it looks like its a good deal for the
    government to increase G, since with an initial
    amount of increase, it can get income to increase
    more through the multiplier.

30
What happens if the government decides to
increase government expenditures (G?)?
  • But, what does this mean for the IS curve?
  • It means that the increase in government
    expenditures caused an increase in income for a
    given level of interest rate. Remember that the
    interest rate did not move at all.
  • This corresponds to a shift of the IS curve to
    the right. For a given level of interest rate now
    we have more income.
  • Lets look at this effect graphically.

31
The effects of G?
Z
Actual Production YZ
ZZ2
Y2
?G
An initial increase in G shifts up the demand by
?G, which increases income by ?G/(1 - c1) in
Panel A. This means that for a given level of
interest rate, the IS curve in Panel B must shift
to the right by ?G/(1 - c1).
Panel A
ZZ1
Y1
?Y?G1/(1 - c1)
45o
Y1
Y2
Y
i
?Y?G1/(1 - c1)
Panel B
i
IS1
IS2
Y
Y1
Y2
32
What happens if the government decides to
decrease government expenditures (G?)?
  • The process that we follow must be clear by now.
  • Again we use the demand equation
  • Z (c0 - c1T I G) c1Y
  • If, ceteris paribus, the government decides to
    decrease G (by ?G), then it is obvious that the
    demand curve would shift down by an amount equal
    to ?G. The vertical intercept would move down by
    ?G but the slope would remain the same.

33
What happens if the government decides to
decrease government expenditures (G?)?
  • Then we use the IS relation to see what happens
    to income
  • Y 1/(1 - c1) (c0 - c1T I G)
  • If G?, then Y would go down by as much as ?G
    times the multiplier 1/(1 - c1), so by more than
    ?G.
  • This means that the decrease in government
    expenditures caused a decrease in income for a
    given level of interest rate.
  • This corresponds to a shift of the IS curve to
    the left. For a given level of interest rate now
    we have less income.

34
The effects of G?
Z
Actual Production YZ
ZZ1
Y1
?G
An initial decrease in G shifts down the demand
by ?G, which decreases income by ?G/(1 - c1) in
Panel A. This means that for a given level of
interest rate, the IS curve in Panel B must shift
to the left by ?G/(1 - c1).
Panel A
ZZ2
Y2
?Y?G1/(1 - c1)
45o
Y1
Y2
Y
i
?Y?G1/(1 - c1)
Panel B
i
IS1
IS2
Y
Y1
Y2
35
What happens if the government decides to
decrease taxes (T?)?
  • Again we use the demand equation
  • Z (c0 - c1T I G) c1Y
  • If, ceteris paribus, the government decides to
    decrease T by ?T (so ?T is negative), then it is
    obvious that the demand curve would shift up by
    an amount equal to -c1?T. The vertical intercept
    would move up by -c1?T but the slope would remain
    the same.

36
What happens if the government decides to
decrease taxes (T?)?
  • Then we use the IS relation to see what happens
    to income
  • Y 1/(1 - c1) (c0 - c1T I G)
  • If T?, then Y would go up by as much as ?T times
    - c1/(1 - c1).
  • The expression - c1/(1 - c1) is the version of
    the multiplier when taxes are changed by the
    government.
  • We observe that in the numerator of this
    expression there is c1, which corresponds to a
    number that is less than one. Therefore, if we
    compare this version of the multiplier with the
    general version 1/(1 - c1), we conclude that
    the general version is larger. This means that
    expansionary fiscal policy is normally more
    effective if conducted through increases in
    government expenditures rather than decreases in
    taxation.

37
What happens if the government decides to
decrease taxes (T?)?
  • So, in effect the decrease in taxes caused an
    increase in income for a given level of interest
    rate.
  • This corresponds to a shift of the IS curve to
    the right. For a given level of interest rate now
    we have more income.

38
The effects of T?
Z
Actual Production YZ
ZZ2
Y2
An initial decrease in T shifts up the demand by
-c1?T, which increases income by ?T-
c1/(1 - c1) in Panel A. This means that for a
given level of interest rate, the IS curve in
Panel B must shift to the right by ?T- c1/(1 -
c1).
Panel A
-c1?T
ZZ1
Y1
?Y?T- c1/(1 - c1)
45o
Y1
Y2
Y
i
?Y?T- c1/(1 - c1)
Panel B
i
IS1
IS2
Y
Y1
Y2
39
What happens if the government decides to
increase taxes (T?)?
  • Again we use the demand equation
  • Z (c0 - c1T I G) c1Y
  • If, ceteris paribus, the government decides to
    increase T by ?T (now ?T is positive), then it is
    obvious that the demand curve would shift down by
    an amount equal to -c1?T. The vertical intercept
    would move down by -c1?T but the slope would
    remain the same.

40
What happens if the government decides to
increase taxes (T?)?
  • Then we use the IS relation to see what happens
    to income
  • Y 1/(1 - c1) (c0 - c1T I G)
  • If T?, then Y would go down by as much as ?T
    times - c1/(1 - c1).
  • So, in effect the increase in taxes caused a
    decrease in income for a given level of interest
    rate.
  • This corresponds to a shift of the IS curve to
    the left. For a given level of interest rate now
    we have less income.

41
The effects of T?
Z
Actual Production YZ
ZZ1
Y1
-c1?T
An initial increase in T shifts down the demand
by -c1?T, which decreases income by ?T- c1/(1 -
c1) in Panel A. This means that for a given
level of interest rate, the IS curve in Panel B
must shift to the left by ?T- c1/(1 - c1).
Panel A
ZZ2
Y2
?Y?T- c1/(1 - c1)
45o
Y1
Y2
Y
i
?Y?T- c1/(1 - c1)
Panel B
i
IS1
IS2
Y
Y1
Y2
42
To sum up IS shifts
Initial Change Shift of IS
G? Right
G? Left
T? Right
T? Left
43
The LM curve
  • To get to the LM curve, we have to use financial
    markets and go through the theory of liquidity
    preference. We have to understand why people
    decide to hold money in their pockets or in non-
    interest bearing bank accounts (checking
    accounts). In other words why we choose to forgo
    the interest rate that the banks offer us when we
    hold illiquid bank products (e.g. CDs, etc.).

44
The LM curve
  • The answer is very simple convenience and
    security.
  • It is true that having highly liquid assets, such
    as cash or immediately available, through an ATM,
    checking accounts makes our life easier.
  • Imagine if we had to go to the bank to liquidate
    part of our investments every time we needed to
    go to the grocery store. Also having liquid
    assets provide us with a sense of security, that
    we will, no matter what, have some money
    immediately available in case an emergency (or a
    new financial opportunity) occurs.

45
The LM curve
  • Since we have answered why, now we have to answer
    how much money we hold.
  • To answer this question, first we have to define
    what is money.
  • Generally, for our purposes money is cash and
    checking (non interest bearing) bank accounts.
    This is known as M1.
  • There are also other measures of money but we are
    not really interested in them.

46
The LM curve
  • Then we have to come up with a measure of money.
    We call the measure of money with the interesting
    name real money balances or real money stock
    (M/P).
  • To determine how much money we hold, as always in
    economics, we will look for an equilibrium.
  • The equilibrium between the supply of real money
    balances and the demand for real money balances.

47
The LM curve (Money supply)
  • The supply of real money balances is easy because
    it is exogenously given. It is controlled by the
    central bank through the ways that we learned in
    introductory macro (open market operations,
    discount rate, required reserves ratio). So the
    supply is just a number decided by the central
    bank and we do not need to worry about it.

48
The LM curve (Money supply)
i
Since money supply (Ms) is independent of the
interest rate, it can be represented by a
vertical line. The amount of money supplied only
depends on the decision of the central bank and
nothing else.
Ms
M/P
49
The LM curve (Money demand)
  • The demand for real money balances is more
    complicated. The amount of real money balances
    that we demand, depends on what?
  • Well, first it depends on income (Y). The more
    income in an economy, the more transactions will
    occur and the more money we will demand to effect
    these transactions. So, there is a positive
    relationship between demand for real money
    balances and income.
  • But also, it depends on the interest rate. The
    higher the interest rate on illiquid financial
    products (e.g. CDs), the less money we will
    demand, since money pays no interest whereas
    these illiquid products do. Because we do not
    want to lose a lot of interest, as interest rates
    go up, we will hold less and less real money
    balances. So, there is a negative relationship
    between demand for real money balances and
    interest rate.

50
The LM curve (Money demand)
  • If we wanted to write down in symbols what we
    just said in words, we would write this
    expression for money demand
  • (M/P)d L(i,Y)
  • Demand for real money balances is a function L of
    the interest rate and income.
  • Or, if we want to assume that money demand is
    exactly proportional to the level of income in an
    economy, we can even more simply write
  • (M/P)d YL(i)

51
The LM curve (Money demand)
i
So, if we want to graph the relationship between
money demand (Md) and the interest rate, it must
be represented by a downward sloping curve. As we
just said, money demand depends negatively on the
interest rate.
Md YL(i)
M/P
52
The LM curve (Money supply and money demand in
equilibrium)
  • So, now that we have all the pieces, we can
    equate money demand and money supply and find the
    equilibrium in the money market, i.e. the
    equilibrium amount of real money balances in our
    economy and the equilibrium level of interest
    rate.
  • Mathematically
  • Ms Md gt
  • (M/P)s (M/P)d gt
  • (M/P)s YL(i)
  • This expression is what is called the LM
    relation. It is the mathematical representation
    of the LM curve.
  • Note that for the purposes of these notes, the
    symbols Ms and Md refer to real money supply and
    real money demand, unless otherwise specified.

53
The LM curve (Money supply and money demand in
equilibrium)
i
Therefore in equilibrium if we equate money
supply and money demand, we get the equilibrium
level of real money balances and the equilibrium
level of interest rate.
Ms
i
Md YL(i)
(M/P)
M/P
54
Deriving the LM curve
  • From here the crucial step in order to derive the
    LM curve is to bring income (Y) into play.
  • We have already said that money demand depends
    positively on income.
  • This means that for a given level of interest
    rate, a higher income would result to a shift of
    the money demand to the right. If income
    increases, for a given level of interest rate, I
    engage in more transactions and I demand more
    real money balances.
  • The picture is as follows

55
Deriving the LM curve
i
So, we notice that a higher level of income (Y2
gtY1), by shifting the money demand to the right,
is associated with a higher level of interest
rate.
Ms
i2
i1
Md Y2L(i)
Md Y1L(i)
(M/P)
M/P
56
Deriving the LM curve
  • Therefore we have proved that, through the
    channel of financial markets and the liquidity
    preference theory, there is a positive
    relationship between the interest rate and
    output.
  • This positive relationship between interest rate
    and output is represented by the LM curve.

57
Deriving the LM curve
Panel A
Panel B
In Panel A, a higher level of income (Y2 gtY1)
shifts the money demand to the right and results
in a higher level of interest rate. In Panel B,
the LM curve sums up this positive relationship
between income and interest rate.
i
i
Ms
LM
i2
i2
Md Y2L(i)
i1
i1
Md Y1L(i)
Y2
Y1
(M/P)
Y
M/P
58
Shifts of the LM curve
  • Now we will explore what shifts the LM curve.
  • To this end, we have to recall the LM relation,
  • (M/P)s YL(i), the equation that describes the
    LM curve.
  • Starting again by what could by no means move the
    LM curve, it is now very easy to say income (Y)
    and the interest rate (i). Exactly like in the IS
    case, if these two variables move, we move along
    the curve. We dont shift it.

59
Shifts of the LM curve
  • So, what could move the LM curve is any of the
    other variables that are exogenous, i.e. they are
    taken as given outside the model, namely
  • Ms, the money supply controlled by the central
    bank (note that the central bank controls the
    nominal money supply, but given that we can
    assume constant prices, effectively the central
    bank can control the real money supply),
  • P, the level of prices, and
  • Md, the demand for real money balances, BUT only
    to the extent that this is affected by factors
    other than the interest rate and income. So, if
    just like that, for some weird reason, we start
    demanding more or less money for a given level of
    interest rate and income. E.g. because an
    asteroid is going to hit the earth and we want to
    engage in more transactions in the last days of
    our earthly existence, we increase our demand for
    money.
  • Since, out of those factors, the policy maker can
    directly control only the money supply (case (a))
    through monetary policy, we are mostly interested
    in changes in this first factor. However, for
    reasons of completeness, we will examine here the
    other two factors as well (cases (b) and (c)).

60
What happens if the central bank decides to
increase the money supply (Ms?)?
  • If the central bank decides to increase the money
    supply, this would certainly mean that the
    interest rate would decrease.
  • So, for a given level of income, now we would
    have a lower level of interest rate.
  • This necessarily means that the LM curve must
    shift down.

61
The effects of Ms?
Panel A
Panel B
In Panel A, the increase in money supply shifts
the money supply to the right and results in a
lower level of interest rate. In Panel B, the LM
curve shifts down since, for the same level of
income, now we have a lower level of interest
rate.
i
i
(Ms)1
(Ms)2
LM1
LM2
i1
i1
i2
i2
Md YL(i)
Y
(M/P)1
(M/P)2
Y
M/P
62
What happens if the central bank decides to
decrease the money supply (Ms?)?
  • If the central bank decides to decrease the money
    supply, this would certainly mean that the
    interest rate would increase.
  • So, for a given level of income, now we would
    have a higher level of interest rate.
  • This necessarily means that the LM curve must
    shift up.

63
The effects of Ms?
Panel A
Panel B
In Panel A, the decrease in money supply shifts
the money supply to the left and results in a
higher level of interest rate. In Panel B, the LM
curve shifts up since, for the same level of
income, now we have a higher level of interest
rate.
i
i
(Ms)1
(Ms)2
LM2
LM1
i2
i2
i1
i1
Md YL(i)
Y
(M/P)1
(M/P)2
Y
M/P
64
What happens if the level of prices goes down
(P?)?
  • Since we are interested in real money balances, a
    decrease in the level of prices effectively means
    that the supply of real money (M/P)s increases.
    The supply of real money balances increases
    without the intervention of the central bank but
    only due the price change.
  • Therefore, because of the increase in money
    supply, the interest rate decreases.
  • So, for a given level of income, now we would
    have a lower level of interest rate.
  • This necessarily means that the LM curve must
    shift down.

65
The effects of P?
In Panel A, the decrease in prices (P2lt P1)
causes the money supply to increase and shift to
the right. This results in a lower level of
interest rate. In Panel B, the LM curve shifts
down since, for the same level of income, now we
have a lower level of interest rate.
Panel A
Panel B
i
i
(M/P1) s
(M/P2) s
LM1
LM2
i1
i1
i2
i2
Md YL(i)
Y
(M/P)1
(M/P)2
Y
M/P
66
What happens if the level of prices goes up (P?)?
  • An increase in the level of prices effectively
    means that the supply of real money (M/P)s
    decreases. The supply of real money balances
    decreases without the intervention of the central
    bank but only due the price change.
  • Therefore, because of the decrease in money
    supply, the interest rate increases.
  • So, for a given level of income, now we would
    have a higher level of interest rate.
  • This necessarily means that the LM curve must
    shift up.

67
The effects of P?
In Panel A, the increase in prices (P2gtP1) causes
the money supply to decrease and shift to the
left. This results in a higher level of interest
rate. In Panel B, the LM curve shifts up since,
for the same level of income, now we have a
higher level of interest rate.
Panel A
Panel B
i
i
(M/P1) s
(M/P2) s
LM2
LM1
i2
i2
i1
i1
Md YL(i)
Y
(M/P)1
(M/P)2
Y
M/P
68
What happens if money demand decreases (Md?)?
  • If money demand decreases for a given level of
    income and interest rate (i.e. the asteroid
    case), then the money demand curve shifts to the
    left. This results in a lower interest rate.
  • So, for a given level of income, now we would
    have a lower level of interest rate.
  • This necessarily means that the LM curve must
    shift down.

69
Effects of Md?
Panel A
Panel B
In Panel A, a decrease in the demand for money
shifts the money demand to the left and results
in a lower level of interest rate. In Panel B,
the LM curve shifts down since, for the same
level of income, now we have a lower level of
interest rate.
LM1
i
i
Ms
LM2
i1
i1
(Md)1
i2
i2
(Md)2
Y
(M/P)
Y
M/P
70
What happens if money demand increases (Md?)?
  • If money demand increases for a given level of
    income and interest rate (again the asteroid
    case), then the money demand shifts to the right.
    This results in a higher interest rate.
  • So, for a given level of income, now we would
    have a higher level of interest rate.
  • This necessarily means that the LM curve must
    shift up.

71
Effects of Md?
Panel A
Panel B
In Panel A, an increase in the demand for money
shifts the money demand to the right and results
in a higher level of interest rate. In Panel B,
the LM curve shifts up since, for the same level
of income, now we have a higher level of interest
rate.
LM2
i
i
Ms
LM1
i2
i2
(Md)2
i1
i1
(Md)1
Y
(M/P)
Y
M/P
72
To sum up LM shifts
Initial change Shift of LM
Ms? Down
Ms? Up
P? Down
P? Up
Md? Down
Md? Up
73
The IS-LM model in all its glory
i
LM
If we put the IS and the LM curves together in a
diagram we are able to determine the equilibrium
level of output and interest rate in a closed
economy.
i
IS
Y
Y
74
So, what happens if we shift the curves in the
full scale model?
  • Now its time to use our model to see what
    happens when we use fiscal or monetary policy in
    order to affect different macro variables.
  • We will examine in turn fiscal expansion and
    contraction and monetary expansion and
    contraction.

75
Fiscal expansion
  • As we already know, a fiscal expansion is a
    situation where the government increases
    government expenditures (G) or reduces taxes (T).
  • As we have mentioned, this corresponds to a shift
    of the IS curve to the right.
  • The result is a higher a level of output and a
    higher level of interest rate.

76
Fiscal expansion
i
If the government engages in a fiscal expansion,
the IS curve shifts to the right. The LM stays
still. The equilibrium moves from A to B
indicating a higher level of output and a higher
level of interest rate.
LM
B
B
i2
A
A
i1
IS2
IS1
Y2
Y1
Y
77
Fiscal expansion elaborated
  • Now, lets ask ourselves why did this happen?
  • The first move was made by the government that
    chose to embark on a fiscal expansion (by raising
    G or cutting T). Whats the result?
  • Either way (G? or T?), the demand (Z) increases
    and therefore output ( income) increases
    (remember the Keynesian cross). Whats next?
  • The increase in income, through the LM relation,
    increases the demand for money leading to a
    higher interest rate (remember the money supply
    and demand graph). Whats next?
  • The higher interest rate, by reducing private
    investment, reduces demand and output but not
    enough to offset the positive effect of the
    fiscal expansion on them.

78
Fiscal expansion elaborated
  • So now, we have a clear picture of how all our
    variables moved
  • C consumption is positively affected either the
    fiscal expansion was effected by an increase in G
    or through a reduction in T (disposable income
    increases in both cases).
  • I the movement of investment is ambiguous
    because on the one hand output went up and we
    know that this boosts I, but on the other hand
    the interest rate increased and we also know that
    this shrinks investment. So the net effect is
    ambiguous.
  • G government expenditures went up if the fiscal
    expansion was effected by an increase in G or
    were unaffected if the fiscal expansion was
    effected by a decrease in T.
  • T taxes went down if the fiscal expansion was
    effected by a decrease in T or were unaffected if
    the fiscal expansion was effected by an increase
    in G.

79
Aggregate effects of a fiscal expansion conducted
by G?
Y i C I G T
? ? ? ? ? 0
80
Aggregate effects of a fiscal expansion conducted
by T?
Y i C I G T
? ? ? ? 0 ?
81
Fiscal contraction
  • As we already know, a fiscal contraction is a
    situation where the government decreases
    government expenditures (G) or increases taxes
    (T).
  • This corresponds to a shift of the IS curve to
    the left.
  • The result is a lower level of output and a lower
    level of interest rate.

82
Fiscal contraction
i
If the government engages in a fiscal
contraction, the IS curve shifts to the left. The
LM stays still. The equilibrium moves from A to B
indicating a lower level of output and a lower
level of interest rate.
LM
A
i1
B
i2
IS1
IS2
Y2
Y1
Y
83
Fiscal contraction elaborated
  • Now, lets ask again ourselves why did this
    happen?
  • The first move was made by the government that
    chose to embark on a fiscal contraction (by
    reducing G or increasing T). Whats the result?
  • Either way (G? or T?), the demand (Z) decreases
    and therefore output ( income) decreases
    (remember the Keynesian cross). Whats next?
  • The decrease in income, through the LM relation,
    decreases the demand for money leading to a lower
    interest rate (remember the money supply and
    demand graph). Whats next?
  • The lower interest rate, by increasing private
    investment, increases demand and output but not
    enough to offset the negative effect of the
    fiscal expansion on them.

84
Fiscal contraction elaborated
  • So now, we have a clear picture of how all the
    variables moved
  • C consumption is negatively affected either the
    fiscal contraction was effected by a decrease in
    G or through an increase in T (disposable income
    decreases in both cases).
  • I the movement of investment is ambiguous
    because on the one hand output went down and this
    decreases I, but on the other hand the interest
    rate decreased and this boosts investment. So the
    net effect is ambiguous.
  • G government expenditures went down if the
    fiscal contraction was effected by a decrease in
    G or were unaffected if the fiscal contraction
    was effected by an increase in T.
  • T taxes went up if the fiscal expansion was
    effected by an increase in T or were unaffected
    if the fiscal expansion was effected by a
    decrease in G.

85
Aggregate effects of a fiscal contraction
conducted by G?
Y i C I G T
? ? ? ? ? 0
86
Aggregate effects of a fiscal contraction
conducted by T?
Y i C I G T
? ? ? ? 0 ?
87
Monetary expansion
  • We already know that a monetary expansion is a
    situation where the central bank increases the
    money supply.
  • We also know that this shifts the LM curve down.
  • The result is a higher a level of output and a
    lower level of interest rate.

88
Monetary expansion
i
LM1
LM2
If the central bank engages in a monetary
expansion, the LM curve shifts down. The IS stays
still. The equilibrium moves from A to B
indicating a higher level of output and a lower
level of interest rate.
A
i1
B
B
B
i2
IS
Y2
Y
Y1
89
Monetary expansion elaborated
  • Now we have to tell the story again.
  • The first move was made by the central bank that
    chose to expand the money supply. Whats the
    result?
  • By remembering the money supply and money demand
    graph, we conclude that this leads to a lower
    interest rate. Whats next?
  • The lower interest rate in turn leads to higher
    investment and thus, higher demand and output
    (remember the Keynesian cross).

90
Monetary expansion elaborated
  • So now, we have a clear picture of how all our
    variables moved
  • C consumption increases since income went up and
    so our disposable income (Y-T) went up.
  • I investment unambiguously increased because we
    saw that the interest rate went down (this
    increases investment) and also income went up
    (this also increases investment). So a monetary
    expansion gives a twofold boost to investment
    (compare that to the fiscal expansion which had
    an ambiguous effect on investment).
  • G government expenditures are unchanged.
  • T taxes are unchanged.

91
Aggregate effects of a monetary expansion
Y i C I G T
? ? ? ? 0 0
92
Monetary contraction
  • We already know that a monetary contraction is a
    situation where the central bank decreases the
    money supply.
  • We also know that this shifts the LM curve up.
  • The result is a lower level of output and a
    higher level of interest rate.

93
Monetary contraction
i
LM2
LM1
If the central bank engages in a monetary
contraction, the LM curve shifts up. The IS stays
still. The equilibrium moves from A to B
indicating a lower level of output and a higher
level of interest rate.
B
i2
A
i1
IS
Y2
Y1
Y
94
Monetary contraction elaborated
  • Lets tell the story for one last time.
  • The first move was made by the central bank that
    chose to contract the money supply. Whats the
    result?
  • By remembering the money supply and money demand
    graph, we conclude that this leads to a higher
    interest rate. Whats next?
  • The higher interest rate in turn leads to lower
    investment and thus, lower demand and output
    (remember the Keynesian cross).

95
Monetary contraction elaborated
  • So now, we have a clear picture of how all our
    variables moved
  • C consumption decreases since income went down
    and so our disposable income (Y-T) went down.
  • I investment unambiguously decreased because we
    saw that the interest rate went up (this
    decreases investment) and also income went down
    (this also decreases investment). So a monetary
    contraction gives a twofold blow to investment.
  • G government expenditures are unchanged.
  • T taxes are unchanged.

96
Aggregate effects of a monetary contraction
Y i C I G T
? ? ? ? 0 0
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)