Title: Diapositive 1
1Theories and Methods of the Business Cycle. Part
1 Dynamic Stochastic General Equilibrium
Models IV. A New Neoclassical Synthesis? Jean-O
livier HAIRAULT, Professeur à Paris I
Panthéon-Sorbonne et à lEcole dEconomie de
Paris (EEP)
21. Introduction
- The RBC theory is at odds with the neoclassical
synthesis - Real shocks vs. Monetary shocks
- Optimal vs. Suboptimal fluctuations
- RBC theory has not totally convinced that
technology shocks can alone drive the business
cycle. The internal mechanisms of the
neoclassical growth model does not lead to
fluctuations totally consistent with the stylized
facts when calibration is seriously done. - The correlation between hours and labor
productivity is too high - The response of output does not display a
hump-shaped profile - How to reconcile theory with the numerous
empirical works which show the non-neutrality of
money (in particular in the VAR framework)? Gali
1989, Quarterly Journal of Economics
31. Introduction
- Along the development of RBC theory in the 80s,
keynesianism was looking for micro-foundations - How to get market failures when agents are
assumed to optimize? - Imperfect information, imperfect competition,
strategic behaviors,New-Keynesianism based on
real and nominal rigidities. Ball and Romer
1990, Review of Economic Studies - Non-walrasian features in the good market
(monopolistic competition), the labor market
(search frictions), the credit market (adverse
selection and moral hazard) - Mainly theoretical works as new-keynesianism has
to address the Lucas critique. - What a challenge to overcome RBC theory with
their own methodology! - The 90s was the decade during which a new
neoclassical synthesis occurs intertemporal
choices and strategic behaviors
42. Equilibrium unemployment
- Employment volatility represents 70 of total
hours volatility - Hours indivisibility à la Hansen 1985
- Do efficiency wages better explain the relative
volatility of hours to labor productivity?
Danthine and Donaldson 1990, European Economic
Review. Employment is not volatile enough in
their model - Efficiency wages are rigid in the sense they do
not clear the labor market, but they are elastic
to technology shocks. - Fluctuations generated by the model are
essentially the same as those of the RBC
canonical model.
52. Equilibrium unemployment
- Equilibrium unemployment, Pissarides 1990,
Equilibrium unemployment theory, Basil Blackwell - Hirings take time as there is imperfect
information in the process of search search
unemployment - Search frictions could explain the persistence of
fluctuations - Merz 1995, Journal of Monetary Economics,
Andolfatto 1996, American Economic Review
62. Equilibrium unemployment
- Hirings depend on vacancies (V) and unemployed
people (U), but also the search intensity (e) of
these latter. - The participation rate is constant and exogenous.
- The probability to have a job is
- The probability to contact a worker
- There are externalities in the search process
- p depends positively on the number of vacancies
(complementarity) and negatively on the number of
unemployed workers (congestion) - q depends negatively on the number of vacancies
and positively on the number of unemployed
workers (congestion)
72. Equilibrium unemployment
- The dynamics of employment depends on hirings (a
combination of unemploment and vacancy) and on
firings (a fixed proportion s of the employment
stock)
82. Equilibrium unemployment
- Representative household (risk-sharing due to the
large scale of the household) - First order conditions are the same as those in
the canonical RBC model, except there is no labor
supply, no partipation decision and hours are
negociated between households and firms (as wage)
92. Equilibrium unemployment
- The production function is traditional and
combines total hours and capital. - Firm labor demand is no more static, as they
invest in vacancies. The firm program is now
intertemporal. - Labor demand is now determined by the
intertemporal condition
102. Equilibrium unemployment
- Bargaining over hours and wage
- Nash criterion
- With
- is the bargaining power of firms. In Andolfatto
1996, it is equal to the elasticity relative to
vacancy in the matching function. In this case,
the bargaining leads to the first best allocation
as demonstrated by Hosios 1990, Review of
Economic Studies. - Given the existence of search frictions,
fluctuations are not necessarily sub-optimal.
This is why Andolfatto 1996 solves the planner
program.
112. Equilibrium unemployment
- Stylized facts standart deviation in the first
line, correlation with output in the second line - Andolfatto 1996
- The wage is no longer equal to labor productivity
and the labor share is variable and
counter-cyclical. The variance of output is
obtained without infinite labor elasticity, but
results from its higher persistence. - But the correlation between hours and wage is not
replicated. - Increasing the volatility of employment by giving
more bargaining power to firms as their response
to technology shocks will then be more elastic.
122. Equilibrium unemployment
- Productivity cycle and Beveridge curve
- Stylized facts
- Models predictions the productivity cycle is
not replicated contrary to the Beveridge curve
133. Perfect Insurance
- Complete markets perfect risk sharing
- B is the amount of insurance whose price is tau.
- 1-alpha s for employed workers 1-alpha 1-p
for unemployed workers - Two insurance schemes profit
- The budgetary constraints
143. Perfect Insurance
- First-order conditions
- Risk-sharing condition
- For s n, u
- These conditions imply that the capital choices
are identical whatever their employment status.
For separable utility fonction, consumptions are
the same, and the unemployed workers are better
off. See Chéron and Langot 2002, Review of
Economic Dynamics for a case where their welfare
is lower than that of employed workers.
153. Perfect Insurance
- Given these optimal choices, the budgetary
constraints can be rewritten as follows - It can be noticed that
- The representative household program is then
164. Monopolistic competition and nominal rigidities
- Considering VAR studies (following the seminal
article of Sims 1980, Econometrica), money
supply shocks would impact the output. J. Gali
1992, Quarterly Journal of Economics, Bec and
Hairault 1993, Annales dEconomie et
Statistiques 1993 - Taking into account money supply shock in DSGE
models implies to have money demand theoretical
foundations Why do we hold money ? Old issue in
economics - Money reduces transaction or search costs in the
good market Kiyotaki and Wright 1989, Journal
of Political Economy - More tractable in DSGE models, cash-in-advance
constraint can be added in the household program,
Cooley and Hansen 1989, American Economic
Review - Without any nominal rigidities, this approach
fails to generate a positive and strong response
of output after a positive monetary (supply)
shock. Only the inflation tax propagation
mechanism which is a negative wealth effect
positive response of labour supply and output,
but very weak effects.
174. Monopolistic competition and nominal rigidities
- (Inflation tax ) nominal rigidities prices are
rigid due to menu costs (New-Keynesian approach)
(an alternative rigidity of the nominal wage due
to the existence of wage contracts) - This implies to consider imperfect competition in
the good market monopolistic competition in the
line of Blanchard and Kiyotacki 1897, American
Economic Review - Nominal rigidities monopolistic competition in
DSGE Hairault and Portier 1993, European
Economic Review
184. Monopolistic competition and nominal rigidities
- Firms have monopoly power due to good
differentiation. - Prices include a mark-up over the marginal cost.
- Firms maximize profit by taking into account the
effect of prices on the good demand. - The demand for good j is a proportion of the
total demand which depends on the relative price
of good j - The total demand for good j is then
194. Monopolistic competition and nominal rigidities
- The nominal profit of firm j is
- Due to the presence of adjustment costs on
prices, firm choices are now intertemporal
204. Monopolistic competition and nominal rigidities
- The first-order conditions are
- Prices are not equalized to marginal costs
-
214. Monopolistic competition and nominal rigidities
- Money is introduced into the utility function
224. Monopolistic competition and nominal rigidities
- The first-order conditions are
- The money supply process is
234. Monopolistic competition and nominal rigidities
- The Solow Residual is no longer a pure measure of
technology. The factor elasticities are not
consistently measured by factor shares in total
revenues due to the existence of markups. - The naive SR is contamined by money supply shocks
as these latter make markups counter-cyclical in
the business cycle - After a money supply shock, firms want to
increase prices in order to leave unchanged their
mark-up. As there exist adjustment costs on
prices, prices do not increase as much as
invariant mark-up would imply. Markups are weaker
than at the steady state.
244. Monopolistic competition and nominal rigidities
- Stylized facts
- Models predictions
255. Financial imperfections
- Limited participation and money supply shocks
- Fuerst 1992, Journal of Monetary Economics,
Christiano and Eichenbaum 1992, American
Economic Review - The nominal and real interest rates decline after
a positive monetary shock in empirical studies
265. Financial imperfections
- The nominal and real interest rates decline after
a positive monetary shock since the supply of
deposits is pre-determined - Firms rent wages
R
Dd, Ds
275. Financial imperfections
- Financial Accelerator, Carlstrom and Fuerst
1997, American Economic Review, Bernanke,
Gertler and Gilchrist, Handbook of
Macroeconomics - Entrepreneurs have access to a risky project.
Lenders have no information about the ex-post
return. They have to pay a verification cost. - The optimal contract is then a debt contract. The
debtor interest rate depends on the
entrepreneurs wealth. - Serial correlation of output growth depends on
the agency costs
286. Sunspot and fluctuations
- Self-fulfilling propheties, Farmer and Guo
1994, Journal of Economic Theory - Animal spirits at the heart of the business cycle
- Extrinsic shocks vs. Shocks on fundamentals
- Indeterminacy of the equilibrium too many
eigenvalues inferior to 1 (more than the number
of pre-determined variables). - Sunspot equilibria can arise in this case.
- This approach must be distinguished from news
about the future of some fundamentals, see
Hairault, Langot and Portier 1997, Journal of
Economic, Dynamics and Control, Beaudry and
Portier 2006, American Economic Review
296. Sunspot and fluctuations
- Final good is produced by using intermediated
inputs - Production of these inputs under increasing
return to scale and monopolistic competition - The reduced form of the model is
- with
306. Sunspot and fluctuations
- If the labor elasticity is small enough relative
to a, ie the labor demande curve is increasing
with a slop superior to that of the labor supply
curve, the eigenvalues are strictly inferior to
one and sunspot equilibria exist
317. Business cycle costs
- Stabilization of business cycle? What does it
mean in the DSGE framework? - Welfare criterion must be considered, and not
volatility criterion, especially the output
volatility - Business cycle costs are very small in terms of
stationary consumption eliminating all
fluctuations is equivalent in welfare units to
0.008 of the steady state consumption, Lucas
1987, Models of Business Cycles, Basil
Blackwell. - This implies that the distorsions introduced by
the stabilization policy must be very small too. - Harberger triangles could be much more important
than Okun gaps, Greenwood and Huffman 1991,
Journal of Monetary Economics. - I argue in the end that, based on what we know
now, it is unrealistic to hope for gains larger
than a tenth of a percent from better
countercyclical policy Lucas 2003, American
Economic Review
327. Business cycle costs
337. Business cycle costs
347. Business cycle costs
357. Business cycle costs
368. Okun Gaps and Harberger triangles
378. Okun Gaps and Harberger triangles
388. Okun Gaps and Harberger triangles
398. Okun Gaps and Harberger triangles
408. Okun Gaps and Harberger triangles
418. Okun Gaps and Harberger triangles
428. Okun Gaps and Harberger triangles