Title: EE 369 POWER SYSTEM ANALYSIS
1EE 369POWER SYSTEM ANALYSIS
- Lecture 17
- Optimal Power Flow, LMPs
- Tom Overbye and Ross Baldick
2Announcements
- Read Chapter 7 (sections 7.1 to 7.3).
- Homework 12 is 6.62, 6.63, 6.67 (calculate
economic dispatch for values of load from 55 MW
to 350 MW) due Tuesday, 11/29. - Class review and course evaluation on Tuesday,
11/29. - Midterm III on Thursday, 12/1, including material
through Homework 12.
3Electricity Markets
- Over last 20 years electricity markets have moved
from bilateral contracts between utilities to
also include centralized markets operated by
Independent System Operators/Regional
Transmission Operators - Day-ahead market that establishes unit commitment
and forward financial positions, - Real-time market, run every 5 or 15 minutes that
arranges for physical dispatch, the spot
market. - Basic engine for operating centralized markets
is Optimal Power Flow (OPF).
4Electricity Markets
- OPF is used as basis for day-ahead and real-time
dispatch pricing in US ISO/RTO electricity
markets - MISO, PJM, ISO-NE, NYISO, SPP, CA, and ERCOT.
- Electricity (MWh) is treated as a commodity (like
corn, coffee, natural gas) but with the extent of
the market limited by transmission system
constraints. - Tools of commodity trading have been widely
adopted (options, forwards, hedges, swaps).
5Electricity Futures Example
Source Wall Street Journal Online, 10/30/08
6Ideal Power Market
- Ideal power market is analogous to a lake.
Generators supply energy to lake and loads remove
energy. - Ideal power market has no transmission
constraints - Single marginal cost associated with enforcing
constraint that supply demand - buy from the least cost unit that is not at a
limit - this price is the marginal cost.
- This solution is identical to the economic
dispatch problem solution.
7Two Bus ED Example
8Market Marginal (Incremental) Cost
Below are some graphs associated with this two
bus system. The graph on left shows the marginal
cost for each of the generators. The graph on
the right shows the system supply curve, assuming
the system is optimally dispatched.
Current generator operating point
9Real Power Markets
- Different operating regions impose constraints
may limit ability to achieve economic dispatch
globally. - Transmission system imposes constraints on the
market - Marginal costs differ at different buses.
- Optimal dispatch solution requires solution by an
optimal power flow - Charging for energy based on marginal costs at
different buses is called locational marginal
pricing (LMP) or nodal pricing.
10Pricing Electricity
- LMP indicates the additional cost to supply an
additional amount of electricity to bus. - All North American ISO/RTO electricicity markets
price wholesale energy at LMP. - If there were no transmission limitations then
the LMPs would be the same at all buses - Equal to value of lambda from economic dispatch.
- Transmission constraints result in differing LMPs
at buses. - Determination of LMPs requires the solution of an
Optimal Power Flow (OPF).
11Optimal Power Flow (OPF)
- OPF functionally combines the power flow with
economic dispatch. - Minimize cost function, such as operating cost,
taking into account realistic equality and
inequality constraints. - Equality constraints
- bus real and reactive power balance
- generator voltage setpoints
- area MW interchange
12OPF, contd
- Inequality constraints
- transmission line/transformer/interface flow
limits - generator MW limits
- generator reactive power capability curves
- bus voltage magnitudes (not yet implemented in
Simulator OPF) - Available Controls
- generator MW outputs
- transformer taps and phase angles
13OPF Solution Methods
- Non-linear approach using Newtons method
- handles marginal losses well, but is relatively
slow and has problems determining binding
constraints - Linear Programming (LP)
- fast and efficient in determining binding
constraints, but can have difficulty with
marginal losses. - used in PowerWorld Simulator
14LP OPF Solution Method
- Solution iterates between
- solving a full ac power flow solution
- enforces real/reactive power balance at each bus
- enforces generator reactive limits
- system controls are assumed fixed
- takes into account non-linearities
- solving an LP
- changes system controls to enforce linearized
constraints while minimizing cost
15Two Bus with Unconstrained Line
With no overloads the OPF matches the
economic dispatch
Transmission line is not overloaded
Marginal cost of supplying power to each bus
(locational marginal costs) This would be price
paid by load and paid to the generators.
16Two Bus with Constrained Line
With the line loaded to its limit, additional
load at Bus A must be supplied locally, causing
the marginal costs to diverge. Similarly,
prices paid by load and paid to generators will
differ bus by bus. (In practice, some markets
such as ERCOT charge zonal averaged price to
load.)
17Three Bus (B3) Example
- Consider a three bus case (bus 1 is system
slack), with all buses connected through 0.1 pu
reactance lines, each with a 100 MVA limit. - Let the generator marginal costs be
- Bus 1 10 / MWhr Range 0 to 400 MW,
- Bus 2 12 / MWhr Range 0 to 400 MW,
- Bus 3 20 / MWhr Range 0 to 400 MW,
- Assume a single 180 MW load at bus 2.
18B3 with Line Limits NOT Enforced
Line from Bus 1 to Bus 3 is over- loaded all
buses have same marginal cost (but not allowed
to dispatch to overload line!)
19B3 with Line Limits Enforced
LP OPF redispatches to remove violation. Bus
marginal costs are now different. Prices will
be different at each bus.
20Verify Bus 3 Marginal Cost
One additional MW of load at bus 3 raised total
cost by 14 /hr, as G2 went up by 2 MW and
G1 went down by 1MW.
21Why is bus 3 LMP 14 /MWh ?
- All lines have equal impedance. Power flow in a
simple network distributes inversely to impedance
of path. - For bus 1 to supply 1 MW to bus 3, 2/3 MW would
take direct path from 1 to 3, while 1/3 MW would
loop around from 1 to 2 to 3. - Likewise, for bus 2 to supply 1 MW to bus 3,
2/3MW would go from 2 to 3, while 1/3 MW would go
from 2 to 1to 3.
22Why is bus 3 LMP 14 / MWh, contd
- With the line from 1 to 3 limited, no additional
power flows are allowed on it. - To supply 1 more MW to bus 3 we need
- Extra production of 1MW Pg1 Pg2 1 MW
- No more flow on line 1 to 3 2/3 Pg1 1/3 Pg2
0 - Solving requires we increase Pg2 by 2 MW and
decrease Pg1 by 1 MW for a net increase of
14/h for the 1 MW increase. - That is, the marginal cost of delivering power to
bus 3 is 14/MWh.
23Both lines into Bus 3 Congested
For bus 3 loads above 200 MW, the load must
be supplied locally. Then what if the bus 3
generator breaker opens?
24Typical Electricity Markets
- Electricity markets trade various commodities,
with MWh being the most important. - A typical market has two settlement periods day
ahead and real-time - Day Ahead Generators (and possibly loads) submit
offers for the next day (offer roughly represents
marginal costs) OPF is used to determine who
gets dispatched based upon forecasted conditions.
Results are financially binding either
generate or pay for someone else. - Real-time Modifies the conditions from the day
ahead market based upon real-time conditions.
25Payment
- Generators are not paid their offer, rather they
are paid the LMP at their bus, while the loads
pay the LMP - In most systems, loads are charged based on a
zonal weighted average of LMPs. - At the residential/small commercial level the LMP
costs are usually not passed on directly to the
end consumer. Rather, these consumers typically
pay a fixed rate that reflects time and
geographical average of LMPs. - LMPs differ across the system due to transmission
system congestion.
26LMPs at 855 AM on one day in Midwest.
Source www.midwestmarket.org
27LMPs at 930 AM on same day
28MISO LMP Contours 10/30/08
29Limiting Carbon Dioxide Emissions
- There is growing concern about the need to limit
carbon dioxide emissions. - The two main approaches are 1) a carbon tax, or
2) a cap-and-trade system (emissions trading) - The tax approach involves setting a price and
emitter of CO2 pays based upon how much CO2 is
emitted. - A cap-and-trade system limits emissions by
requiring permits (allowances) to emit CO2. The
government sets the number of allowances,
allocates them initially, and then private
markets set their prices and allow trade.