A Flexible Mathematical Programming Model to Estimate Multiregional InputOutput Accounts - PowerPoint PPT Presentation

1 / 37
About This Presentation
Title:

A Flexible Mathematical Programming Model to Estimate Multiregional InputOutput Accounts

Description:

Patrick Canning and Zhi Wang 'A Flexible Mathematical Programming Model to ... BLS-CES; BEA St. Inc. & tangible wealth; Census. 2000 & Gov; GSA. procurement; ancillary ... – PowerPoint PPT presentation

Number of Views:52
Avg rating:3.0/5.0
Slides: 38
Provided by: usc109
Category:

less

Transcript and Presenter's Notes

Title: A Flexible Mathematical Programming Model to Estimate Multiregional InputOutput Accounts


1
A Flexible Mathematical Programming Model to
Estimate Multiregional Input-Output Accounts
  • Zhi Wang
  • Bureau of Economic Analysis, US Department of
    Commerce
  • Patrick Canning
  • Economic Research Service, US Department of
    Agriculture

2
Presentation Outline
  • Motivations and Objectives
  • Literature Review and Basic Ideas
  • Model Specifications and Major Properties
  • Experiment Design
  • Testing Results
  • Conclusions and Limitations
  • Apply to the U.S. -- the Large Dimension Case

3
Motivations
  • There are tremendous disparities in economic
    development among different regions in large
    developing countries. Globalization has
    different impacts on the urban and coastal areas
    compared to the rural and inland less developed
    regions. How to maintain balanced development to
    reduce income inequalities between different
    parts of the country and achieve a high rate of
    economic growth simultaneously is one of the
    pressing policy challenges faced by governments
    in most large developing countries today.
  • A major obstacle in conducting policy analysis
    for regional economic development is the lack of
    consistent, reliable regional data, especially
    data on interregional trade.

4
Motivations
  • Despite decades of efforts, regional data
    analogous to national input-output accounts and
    international trade accounts remain unavailable,
    even for well defined sub-national regions in
    many developed countries. Regional economists
    have to develop various non-survey methods to
    estimate these data.
  • In the past two decades, there have been well
    developed mathematical procedures to estimate
    unknown data based on limited prior information
    subject to a set of linear constraints
    (Constraint matrix balance), but they have not
    been widely used in regional economic analysis.

5
Objectives
  • This research intend to bridge such gaps. We have
    three objectives
  • develop and implement a formal model to
    estimate inter-regional, inter-industry
    transaction
  • flows based on incomplete regional data
  • To evaluate the models performance using
    real-world data
  • To apply the model in a large dimension case
    using publicly available economic and
    transportation statistics describing the US
    economy in 1997

6
Literature Review Constrained matrix-balancing
problem
  • It involves the computation of the best estimate
    of an unknown matrix from a given matrix, with
    some prior information to constrain the solution.
    It is a core mathematical structure in diverse
    applications
  • Estimating input-output tables and inter-regional
    trade flows in regional science (todays
    presentation)
  • Balancing of social/national accounts in
    economics (on going research)
  • Estimating interregional migration in demography
  • Analysis of voting patterns in political science
  • Treatment of census data and estimation of
    contingency tables in statistics
  • Estimation of transition probabilities in
    stochastic modeling
  • Projection of traffic within telecommunication
    and transportation networks

7
Literature ReviewApplication to interregional
trade flows
  • David F. Batten. The Interregional Linkages
    Between National and Regional Input-Output
    Models. International Regional Science Review,
    Vol.7, No. 1, pp. 53-67, 1982.
  • David F. Batten and D. Martellato. Classical
    versus Modern Approaches to Interregional
    Input-output Analysis. Annals of Regional
    Sciences, 19 1-15, 1985.
  • Golan, Amos, George Judge and Sherman Robinson
    Recovering Information from Incomplete or
    partial Multi-sectoral Economic Data. The Review
    of Economics and Statistics, 76(3),541-49,1994.
  • Robinson, Sherman, Andrea Cattaneo, and Moataz
    El-Said. Updating and Estimating a Social
    Accounting Matrix Using Cross Entropy Methods.
    Economic System Research, 13(1), 47-64,2001
  • Patrick Canning and Zhi Wang A Flexible
    Mathematical Programming Model to Estimate
    Interregional Input-Output Accounts.Journal of
    Regional Sciences, August, 2005.

8
Basic Ideas of the Framework
  • To apply this methodology as a data
    reconciliation tool, three pieces of information
    are needed
  • Initial estimates of the same economic variables
    from different sources (in national economic
    accounts, estimates of the same variables can
    often be obtained from income, expenditure or
    production data).
  • An accounting framework and other constraints
    (demands have to equal supplies and components
    have to sum to totals, ).
  • Reliability information on the initial estimates
    (standard error, ranking index, )

9
Problems of Proportional Adjustment
10
Problems of Proportional Adjustment(Cont.)
11
Notation Conventions
  • Domestic deliveries
  • Intermediate demand
  • Gross output
  • Value added
  • Final demand
  • Exports
  • Imports
  • Counterparts of national totals without
    superscripts
  • Variables with a bar denote initial estimates for
    that variable
  • An additional w before the variable indicates
    the reliability measure for that variable
  • Superscripts denote regions, subscripts denote
    products

12
The Estimation Problems
  • Given a nm2 non-negative array and a
    n2m non-negative array , determine a
    non-negative array D and a non-negative
    array Z that is close to D and Z such that
    accounting identities hold.
  • In other words, modify a given set of prior
    inter-regional and inter-industrial transaction
    estimates according to the following objective
    function to satisfy known accounting constraints

13
Basic Accounting Identities in a National System
of Economic Regions
14
The Battern Interregional IO Model (1982)
15

Theoretical Properties
  • Statistical interpretations underlying the model
    differ when different reliability weights are
    used
  • The quadratic and entropy objective functions are
    equivalent in the neighborhood of initial
    estimates
  • In all but the trivial case, posterior estimates
    derived from entropy or quadratic loss minimand
    will always be closer to the unknown, true values
    than the associated initial estimates.
  • The choice of weights in the objective function
    has very important impacts on the estimation
    results

16
Why Balanced Estimates Better?
  • Initial estimates
  • W variance matrix of initial estimates ,
  • A coefficient matrix of all linear constraints
    AD 0
  • The BLUE
  • D will always not worse than with equal or
    smaller variance

17
Empirical Advantages
  • Flexibility
  • This model permits a wider variety and volume of
    information to be brought to bear on the
    estimation process than is possible with scaling
    methods such as RAS
  • Incorporation of data reliabilities in a systemic
    way
  • The weights in the objective function reflect the
    relative reliability of a given set of priors.
    Entries with higher reliability should undergo
    less adjustment than entries with lower
    reliability.
  • Smaller model dimension than Batten model
  • Has NG2(N-1) less variables and the same
    constraints. This increases estimation efficiency
    and facilitates the computation process.

18
Testing Data Set
  • Version 4 of the Global Trade Analysis Project
    (GTAP) database was first aggregated into a
    4-region, 10-sector data set.
  • Then 3 of the 4 regions (the United States,
    European Union and Japan) were further aggregated
    into a single open economy which engages in both
    inter-regional trade among its 3 internal regions
    and international trade with rest of the world.
  • The model was used to replicate the underlying
    inter-continental trade flows among Japan, EU and
    the United States as well as the individual
    countrys input-output account.

19
Experiment Design
  • Experiment 1
  • The three regions weighted average I-O flows
    and distorted inter-regional trade data in the
    GTAP were used as initial estimates.
  • Experiment 2
  • The region-specific I-O flows are assumed to be
    constant. The inter-regional shipments in the
    first experiment were re-estimated.
  • Experiment 3
  • The inter-regional shipments are known with
    certainty. The three regions weighted average
    I-O flows were used as priors to estimate the
    region-specific I-O flows.

20
Experiment Design (Cont.)
  • Experiment 4
  • David F. Battens model was used to estimate the
    inter-regional shipments and individual region
    I-O flows.
  • Solutions from both models are compared with the
    true inter-regional trade and inter-sector I-O
    flow data in the GTAP data set.

21
Measures to evaluate test resultsMean absolute
percentage error (MAPE)
22
Estimate Results Mean absolute percentage error
of inter-regional tradePercent difference from
true trade data
23
Estimate Results (Cont.)Mean absolute percentage
error of inter-regional tradePercent difference
from true trade data
24
Estimate Results (Cont.)Mean absolute percentage
error of inter-sector flowsPercent difference
from true IO data
25
Observations
  • In all experiments except the Batten model, most
    of the mean absolute percentage errors are about
    4-7 percent of the true data. In contrast,
    recovering the individual regions input-output
    flows from national averages values only had
    limited success.
  • When there is no additional information that can
    be incorporated into the estimation framework, a
    more detailed model may not perform any better
    than a simpler model. However, the accuracy is
    improved by a more detailed model when more
    detailed data are available.

26
Observations(Cont.)
  • The marginal accuracy gained from actual
    individual regional I-O flows is significant in
    estimating inter-regional trade flow using the
    IRIO model, but quite small in the MRIO version.
    In contrast, the marginal value of accurate
    inter-regional shipment data is rather small in
    estimating individual regional I-O coefficients
    under both versions of the model.
  • However, caution is needed before developing a
    firm conclusion because the particular data set
    used to test the model in this paper may have
    skewed the results. Because the United States, EU
    and Japan are all large economies, their demand
    for intermediates are largely met by their own
    production.

27
Conclusions
  • This paper developed a mathematical model to
    estimate inter-regional trade patterns and I-O
    accounts based on an inter-regional accounting
    framework and initial estimates of inter-regional
    shipments in a national system of economic
    regions.
  • The model is quite flexible in its data
    requirements and has desirable theoretical and
    empirical properties.
  • The model performed remarkably well in
    identifying the true patterns of inter-regional
    trade from highly distorted initial estimates of
    inter-regional shipments.

28
Limitations
  • Based on the data set aggregated from the GTAP
    data, tests show that the current model is
    limited in its ability to improve the IO
    transaction estimates of individual regions from
    national averages.
  • Continuing research on the true underlying causes
    is needed to further enhance the models capacity
    as an estimating and reconciliation tool in
    building inter-regional production and trade
    accounts.

29
Estimating a U.S. Multiregional Input-Output
Account
  • Apply the Mathematical Programming Model to a
    Large Dimension Case
  • Data preparation for the United States

30
1997 Detailed Benchmark Input-Output Account 483
x 494
1997 Detailed Benchmark Input-Output Account 483
x 483
convert to C by C
expand farm sectors
USDA production, cost, and utilization
data, plus other ERS value added statistics
ERS expanded Detailed Input-Output Account 494 x
494
Economic, Ag, and Govt. Census, NASS,
ARMS APHIS, ERS Value added data
U.S. customs Data (SITC) by ports and detailed
data by customs districts (HS)
BLS-CES BEA St. Inc. tangible wealth
Census 2000 Gov GSA procurement ancillary
concordance optimization
concordance optimization
concordance optimization
31
State estimates of gross output, value added,and
wagebill
State estimates of imports and exports
State estimates of household and
govt. consumption investment
  • Commodity flow survey
  • USDA transportation stats
  • Monopolistic comp. model

concordance aggregation optimization
concordance product mix
State-to-State flow estimates for goods and
services 51-regions, 94-sectors
State estimates of inter-sectoral transactions 51-
regions, 94-sectors
Unbalanced 51-region, 94-sector multi-regional
input-output account All initial data for the
final mathematical programming model
32
Specifications for Model to Reconcile Consumption
and Saving Statistics
  • Data available from three different sources
    (observed statistics)
  • Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS) - Consumer
    Expenditure Survey
  • rgexp0ik HHs expenditure by commodity and US
    regions
  • szexp0is HHs expenditure by commodity and
    family size
  • incexp0in HHs expenditure by commodity and
    family income groups
  • rginc0k HHs disposable income by US regions
  • szinc0s HHs disposable income by family size
  • incinc0n HHs disposable income by family income
    groups
  • Census Bureau - Population Census
  • Number of HHs by size, income group and
    state
  • Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA) - Disposable
    income data
  • sinc0r Disposable income by state

33
Specifications of Model to Reconcile Consumption
and Saving Statistics (Cont.)
  • Dimension of data
  • i Commodity categories, i 1,2,,75
  • s Households by family size, s 1,2,5
  • n Households by income, n 1,2, 7
  • r State
    r 1,2,51
  • k Region k Northeast, Mid-West, South,
    West
  • Unobservable statistics estimated from the model
  • HHs expenditure by commodity and state
  • A Two Stage Quadratic Programming Model to
    Reconcile the data

34
Estimates of Consumer Savings and Expenditures
by Commodities
  • Disposable income by Region and Income Group from
    BLS survey is held constant in the adjustment
  • Percentage adjustments are small for disposable
    income by state from BEA and for expenditure by
    family size from BLS survey.
  • Percent adjustment from BEA state disposable
    income
  • AL 1.621, AK -1.337, AZ 0.280, AR
    2.137, CA -0.894, CO -0.652, CT -1.093,
    DE -0.613,
  • DC 0.733, FL 0.633, GA -0.066,
    HI -1.211, ID 0.894, IL -0.585, IN
    0.174, IA 0.685,
  • KS 0.393, KY 1.711, LA 1.734,
    ME 1.135, MD -1.198, MA -0.725, MI
    -0.293, MN -0.605,
  • MS 2.199, MO 0.916, MT 2.562, NE
    0.663, NV -0.397, NH -0.791, NJ -1.329,
    NM 1.914,
  • NY -0.095, NC 0.636, ND 1.938,
    OH 0.348, OK 1.755, OR 0.369, PA
    0.500, RI 0.238,
  • SC 0.980, SD 1.694, TN 1.167
    TX 0.195, UT -1.092, VT 0.444, VA
    -0.498, WA -0.431
  • WV 2.928, WI -0.136, WY 1.067
  • Percent adjustment from expenditure by family
    size from BLS survey
  • size1
    size2 size3 size4 size5
  • SAVE -6.185 -4.481 -4.085
    -4.541 -7.304

35
Specifications for Model to Fill the Missing
Value in Commodity Flow Survey Data
  • Data available in CFS
  • x0isr State to state shipment by commodity at 2
    digit SCTG level with missing values
  • sx0ir Shipment of commodity i by state of origin
    at 3 digit SCTG (table 5)
  • st0sr Total outbound shipment from state s to
    state r at 3 digit SCTG (table 7)
  • dt0sr Total inbound shipment from state s to
    state r at three 3 SCTG (table 8)
  • us0 i Total shipment of commodity i in the
    United States at 2 and 3 digit (US report table
    5)
  • wsxir Variance of sx0ir (Appendix)
  • wstsr Variance of st0sr (Appendix)
  • wdtsr Variance of dt0sr (Appendix)
  • dx0ir Shipment of commodity i by state of
    destination and x0isr at three digit SCTG are
    complete missing.
  • First fill the missing x0isr at 2 digit SCTG
    level, then fill the missing values of dx0ir at
    3 digit SCTG level, finally fill the missing
    x0isr at 3 digit SCTG level

36
Service Sector Trade Flows
  • Treyz, F., and J. Bumgardner. "Monopolistic
    Competition Estimates of Interregional Trade
    Flows in Services." In H. Kohno, P. Nijkamp, and
    J. Poot. eds. Regional Cohesion and Competition
    in the Age of Globalization. Edward Elgar, 2000.
  • Monopolistic competitive service sector w/
    economies of scale technologies
  • Consumer and producer demands for services are
    characterized by preference for variety, ala
    Dixit-Stiglitz (1977)
  • Free entry and exit drives profits to zero and
    uniform firm sizes
  • location of production and demand markets are
    pre-determined
  • cif prices reflect market and non-market costs of
    overcoming distance
  • Given location of production and demand, demand
    elasticity's, and distance costs, solve the the
    set of fob prices that minimize the cost of
    serving each market--this produces a unique
    spatial equilibrium in service trade flows

37
Specifications for Model to Fill the Missing
Value in Commodity Flow Survey Data

 
Write a Comment
User Comments (0)
About PowerShow.com