Title: FEEM PPT Template
1Teoria delle aste e applicazioni in finanza
Lezione 8Privatizzazioni Teoria e Fatti
Stilizzati
Docente Bernardo Bortolotti
2What is privatization?
- Definition
- a transfer of ownership or voting rights in a
State-owned enterprise from the State to the
private sector. The State includes the central or
local government, ministries, bodies of the
public administration, and companies where the
central or local government acts as shareholder.
The private sector comprises private individuals
and economic entities with private shareholders.
3State vs private ownership theory
- A classic starting point the Fundamental
Theorems of Welfare Economics - A competitive equilibrium is Pareto-efficient
- Any Pareto efficient allocation can be supported
by a competitive equilibrium - Under strong assumptions, when markets are
competitive state ownership of firms cannot be
justified on efficiency grounds
4State vs private ownership theory
- Market failures (info, monopoly, externalities,
public goods, etc.) provide a rationale for
government intervention in the economy - Such a rationale does not support state
ownership the government can provide goods and
services without producing them - Neutrality theorems (Sappington and Stiglitz
1987, Shapiro and Willig 1990)
5Sappington and Stiglitz (1987)
- Fundamental Privatization Theorem
- Suppose government pursues these objectives (a)
economic efficiency (b) equity (c) rent
extraction. Then the government can design an
auction scheme to meet perfectly these
objectives, and public production cannot improve
private production
6Sappington and Stiglitz (1987)
- Proof (sketch)
- Gov has a social valuation of the good (includes
equity). - Production by (risk-neutral) firms.
- Public procurement mechanism the winning firm
will receive a payment to social valuation. - The most efficient firm will win the contract
- If auction competitive, complete rent extraction
7Politicians in firms Vishny and Shleifer (1994)
- Assumptions
- Politicians control SOEs to achieve political
objectives (excess labor, rents, etc.) - Three players the treasury (non strategic) the
politician, the manager - Separation of cash flow and control rights
- Commercialization gov has cash flow rights, but
no control rights - Regulation manager has ownership rights but
govt has control rights
8The incomplete contracts approach
- Neutrality results hinge upon availability of
complete contingent long-term contracts. When
contracts are incomplete, ownership matters
(Williamson 1985, Grossman and Hart 1986) - Suppose that surplus depends upon on some
non-contractible, relation specific investment.
The division of these quasi-rents will be
determined by the ex post bargaining power of the
parties, which in turn depends on the governance
structure - Privatization matter because makes the private
owner is the residual claimant of the surplus.
9 Sketch of Schmidt (1996)
- Monopolistic firm produces y of a public good,
generating social benefit b(y) - Costs are c(y,?) where ? is a state variable
(high, low) which is private information of the
owner of the firm - Manager makes a personal, unobservable
non-monetary investment, e, to reduce future
costs - q(e) is the probability of the low cost state ?
-
10 Sketch of Schmidt (1996)
11 Sketch of Schmidt (1996)
- Nationalization
- Suppose that contingent contracts are not
feasible (wages and subsides are fixed) - The government then chooses the ex post efficient
production level y - Given payments are fixed, managers sets e0,
government will offer w0 - Lack of commitment of the parts of government
induces efficient production level, but
productive inefficiency (costs are high because
manager does not exert effort) -
12 Sketch of Schmidt (1996)
- Privatization
- The government does not know ?, nor the effort
taken by the manager. - Standard mechanism design problem (Baron and
Myerson 1982) to induce the efficient level of
production, the govt must provide an
informational rent - The optimal regulation scheme distorts
production below the efficient level if costs are
high. The manager has now incentives to invest in
cost reduction to get the rent
13 Sketch of Schmidt (1996)
- Key results
- Privatization entails a trade-off between
allocative efficiency (production levels) and
productive efficiency (investment levels) - Normative implication privatization superior
when social benefit is small - However, under these circumstances privatization
is superior even when the govt is fully
benevolent and rational player - Neutrality fails
- Related papers Laffont and Tirole (1991),
Shapiro and Willig (1990)
14 The political economy of privatization
- Previous research assumed governments
preferences as exogenously given (i.e. benevolent
(Schmidt 1996) vs self-interested (Shleifer and
Vishny 1994)) - More recent research in political economy focused
on voters preferences affecting privatization
outcomes and choices - Biais and Perotti (2002), Roland and Verdier
(1994), Schmidt (2000)
15Mass privatization Roland and Verdier (1994)
- Context massive transfer of ownership rights by
free (or quasi free) distribution) - Irreversibility give the domestic population a
stake in the success of privatization - Fast process exploit political windows of
opportunity - Czech Rep, Russia (insiders)
16Mass privatization in CEE and FSU countries
17Mass privatization Roland and Verdier (1994)
- Hyp Govt maximized the utility of the average
citizen - Stage 1
- all firms are offered to private investors
(privatized) - Investors decide to enter and restructure, with a
fixed cost k - State 2
- Govt observes the level of privatization, and may
re-nationalize if the level is lower than
expected - Production takes place and unemployment occurs
18Mass privatization Roland and Verdier (1994)
- Trade-off a higher of privatizations increases
the probability of unemployment, but increases
the income of the employed as redundant workers
are no longer subsidized with taxation - At equilibrium, marginal costs will equate
benefits - Unique equilibrium with full, partial
privatization, or re-nationalization depending on
entry costs k
19Mass privatization Roland and Verdier (1994)
- New hyp Positive externalities increasing with
private sector development (spillovers and
complementarities in terms of product quality,
knowledge, RD, etc.) - Privatization (if sufficiently large) may
decrease the probability of unemployment - Multiple equilibria irreversibility if
investment above a critical level. Otherwise,
below that level, risk of policy reversal - Mass privatization free distribution of shares
may couterbalance the negative effects on
unemployment since citizens receive more
dividends. Full priva becomes the only equilibrium
20Credible privatization Perotti (1995)
- Motivation privatization can be designed to
signal commitment to market oriented policies - Hyp
- two types of governments populist and committed
- As in Biais and Perotti, if SOE privatized,
manager exerts efffort - Stage 1
- Govt. decides to sell
- Production takes place
- Govt decides to interfere (regulation,
nationalization) - Profits distrubuted
- Stage 2
- Govt. sells residual stake
- Production
- Interference
21Credible privatization Perotti (1995)
- Results when there is no uncertainty over govt.
preferences, govt maximize utility with a
complete immediate sale. - Obviuosly, the firm net worth (and revenues) will
be lower when government is populist as
interference will adversely affect managers
incentives - Assume private information. Now populist has
incentives to mimick the committed government - Results
- There exists a separating equilibrium where the
committed government sells a small initial stake
as a (credible) commitment device. - The populist government will sell instead its
stake upfront
22Credible privatization Perotti (1995)
- This signalling equilibrium hinges upon the
(problematic) assumption that the first tranche
involves the transfer of control - If a large stake is needed to relinquish control,
committed government need an additional
instrument to signal commitment - Undepricing of shares selling the first tranche
at discount, committed gov. signals patience to
garner privatization benefits overtime - Populist government will sell entire capital at
market price (UK vs France)
23Sketch of privatization history
- 1961, Federal Republic of Germany. Adenauer (CDU)
sells shares in Volkswagen and VEBA. Govt bails
out - 1973, Chile. Pinochet attempts to privatize
companies nationalized under Allende - 1979-97, UK. Still the most important. SOE value
added/GDP from 10 to 0. - 1987-88, Japan. Nippon Telephone and Telegraph
(NTT) the largest share offering in history
US40bn - 1990s, Europe. Italy, Germany, France, Spain
- 1992-1996, Mass privatization in Russia and Czech
Rep. - Mid 1990s CEEC and FSU
24Facts
- From 1977 to 2004, US1.26trn revenues and 4,500
privatization deals in more than 100 countries - Global State-owned Enterprise (SOE) value added
( GDP) decrease from 9 to 6 - SOE market capitalization US3,310bn
- 2004
- 164 operations (75bn) globally
- 53 of operations and 72 of revenues in EU
- 58 in 2004 privatization revenues with respect
to 2001-2003 average - Privatization coming back strong after end of
century plunge.
25Global Privatizations, 1977-2004
26SOE of GDP by stage of national development
27Country ranking by revenues
28Country ranking by revenues
29Revenues distribution by sectors
30Last major deals
31What is left to sell in Europe?
- The central governments (or privatization
agencies) portfolio in listed companies is worth
230bn - 75 of this portfolio is directly held 25 is
held by financial holdings controlled by the
State (Kfw, CDP, CDC, etc.) - This portfolio is worth approximately 1/3 of
total privatization revenues. Privatizing the
final tranche becomes the issue. Will
government relinquish control? - More likely, IPO wave of non-listed State-owned
firms
32European governments portfolio
33What is left to sell in Europe?
- The central governments (or privatization
agencies) portfolio in listed companies is worth
230bn - 75 of this portfolio is directly held 25 is
held by financial holdings controlled by the
State (Kfw, CDP, CDC, etc.) - This portfolio is worth approximately 1/3 of
total privatization revenues. Privatizing the
final tranche becomes the issue. Will
government relinquish control? - More likely, IPO wave of non-listed State-owned
firms
34Ownership and control Two basic questions
- Did governments give up control in privatized
firms? - If they did not, does governments reluctance
affect firm value?
35Definition
- We define Reluctant Privatization as
- A privatization of a State-owned Enterprise (SOE)
characterized by the trasfer of ownership rights
without a (corresponding) transfer of control
rights
36Reluctant Privatizations, Italy
- In December 2003, the Italian MEF corporatized
Cassa Depositi e Prestiti (CDP), a public
financial institution, and then trasferred stakes
in Eni, Enel, Poste Italiane, and STM to CDP. - 30 of CDP was privatized to a consortium of
Italian banking foundations. - 13.1bn privatization revenues cleared by
Eurostat to amortize public debt.
37Reluctant Privatizations, Italy
38Reluctant Privatizations, Italy
39Research Design
- Did governments give up control in privatized
firms? - We analyze empirically the evolution of ultimate
control rights (from end-1996 to 2000) in
privatized companies as opposed to a control
sample. - If they did not, does governments reluctance
affect firm value? - We estimate the (adjusted) performance of
privatized companies as a function of
(government) control rights.
40Theoretical Predictions
- The political interference theory
- (Shleifer and Vishny, QJE1994)
- Governments run SOEs to achieve political
objectives (high employment, high wages, etc.)
and forgo maximizing profits. - H0 Government control rights are not negatively
discounted in market values.
41Novelty
- Huge literature on performance of privatized
companies (Megginson and Netter JEL02 survey). - To our knowledge, our paper is the first to study
in combination - ultimate control (La Porta et al JF02, Tian WP02)
- additional control devices (golden shares)
- adjusted performance using a control sample at
the company level (Dewenter and Malatesta AER01,
Lopez-de-Silanes QJE96)
42Data
- 141 companies privatized by public offerings
before 31/12/1996 in OECD countries - Complete ownership data for 1996 and 2000
- 104 privatization prospectuses to identify
statutory constraints and additional control
devices - Balance sheet data for the period 1996-2000
- Main sources SDC Platinum, WordScope,
Datastream, national exchanges, etc.
43Measuring Control Rights
- We rely on ultimate control (voting) rights
(weakest link concept, 10 cut off) - Six types of ultimate owners
- a family or an individual
- the State
- a widely-held financial institution
- a widely-held corporation
- a miscellaneous investor
- a cross-holding
- (A company that does not have a controlling
shareholder at the 10 cut-off is classified as
widely-held).
44Examples Lufthansa AG, 1996
Govt. direct ownership 1.77 Govt ultimate
control rights 50.7
45Examples SGS-Thomson Microelectronics, 1996
Govt. direct ownership 0 Govt ultimate control
rights 100
46The control sample
- First-best a) country b) sector and c) 30
range of market cap - 68 of cases
- Second-best a) sector and b) 30 range of
market cap - 30 of cases
- Third-best case a) country and b) 30 range of
market cap - 1 case
47The largest shareholders in privatized companies
48Control rights in privatized vs control sample
49Golden Shares
- Governments may enjoy control power in partially
or even in fully privatized firms through golden
share provisions (GSP) - GSP typically involve
- Special powers to the public shareholder (veto or
agreement on MA, representatives in BoD, etc.) - Statutory constraints in the company bylaws to
curb private ownership rights (ownership limits,
voting caps, national control provision, etc.)
50Golden Shares
GSP are widespread in several countries, highly
correlated, and tend to persist overtime. Not
surprisingly, they are typically concentrated in
strategic sectors, such as aerospace and
defence, oil and gas, and utilities. The
rationale is the protection of relevant national
interests (the public counterpart of poison
pills).
51Golden Share Provisions
52Main results on control rights (Summary)
- In 2000, the government is the largest ultimate
shareholder in 30 of privatized companies. - These companies are much more tightly controlled
than their private peers. - In 2000, the government controls directly
(through stakes) or indirectly (through GSP) 62
of privatized companies (65 in 1996). - Thus, governments privatized SOEs but did not
relinquish control - ? Reluctant privatization
53Market valuation
- Does govt. reluctance affect valuation?
- First, we study the evolution of the adjusted
market valuation (market-to-book ratio) in
sub-samples of govt vs non govt controlled
privatized companies. - Second, we perform panel data estimation of M/B
as a function of governments (residual) control
rights.
54Market valuation (M/B) descriptive analysis
55Market valuation (M/B) econometric analysis
Govt. controlled firms have higher (adjusted) M/B
than firms privatized more fully. A thorough
empirical test needed. We estimate the following
model
Where STATE is the covariate for government
ultimate control rights, SPECIAL is a GSP dummy,
and a vector of (pair-specific) control
variables
56OLS results (random effects)
57Endogeneity of market valuation
- Abnormal market performance typically drives
privatization, especially when govt. is in
financial distress. - 2SLS estimation relaxing the exogeneity of govt.
stakes. - Choice of IV Political-institutional variables
(majoritarian vs consentual pattern of
democracy), the partisan orientation of
privatizing governments, public finance
conditions. - These IV are valid strongly correlated with
stakes, but uncorrelated with the error term.
582SLS estimates of M/B
59 Summary of results
- Government stakes do matter for valuation. But
quite surprisingly higher stakes are associated
with higher valuation differentials. - Impact not negligible a 10 percent increase in
voting rights (approx a standard deviation
change) brings about 0.6 (25 percent) increase in
adjusted M/B. - Therefore, fully divested companies appear less
valuable than companies where government owns
large stakes.
60Conclusion
- We find evidence broadly consistent with the
concept of Reluctant Privatization. Indeed,
privatizing government do not give up control in
SOEs. - Quite surprisingly, government reluctance does
not attect negatively market valuation. - The null hypothesis on political interference
cannot be rejected. - Interpretation Grabbing hand story very
relevant at the intial stage of the process. But
the government as large shareholder in privatized
firms may also provide benefits such as
contracts, favourable regulation, and stability
61Financial performance of privatized firms
- Idiosyncratic factors may affect the risk and
return characteristics of privatized firms - Scope for efficiency gains
- Sectors of activity (energy, utilities, TLC,
banking) - Large enterprises with a broad clientele
- Manage large infrastructures
- Often regulated and shielded from competition
- Peculiar pricing, sequencing, and ownership
structures - Players in MA (bidder and targets)
62PB Index
- The PB (Privatization Barometer) Index is a
benchmark for tracking the performance of
privatized companies. - It serves primarily as
- Benchmark for portfolio managers and investors
who invest in privatized companies - Performance yardstick for governments and
investment banks floating shares of state-owned
companies - Vehicle for attracting attention to
privatization-related funds in European equity
markets
63PB Index
- The PB Index is developed by the Privatization
Barometer - a web-based info-provider on
privatization in the EU - with the support of
Lehman Brothers - The index is restricted to ordinary shares of
privatized companies trading in the stock
exchanges of the European Union, including the
ten new accession countries. -
64PB Index
- PB Composite Index
- PB Old Europe (EU15)
- PB New Europe (10 new accession countries)
- PB Banking
- PB Industrial
- PB Oil Gas
- PB Utilities
- PB Telecom
65PB Index Constituents
- The constituents are the stocks of companies
privatized from January 1977 to date. - A privatization is defined as a transfer of
ownership or voting rights from the central or
local government, or from bodies of the public
administration, to private investors. - Eligible securities are also traded shares of
equity carve-outs from state-owned enterprises
(Postabank rt or privatized companies (Terna,
Page Jaunes, etc.) - Privatization transactions are identified from
the Global New Issues Database of Thomson-SDC,
and double-checked from official sources.
66PB Index Constituents
as of 23/05/05.
67PB Index Maintenance
- Adjustment for company additions and deletions
and stock price adjustments due to corporate
actions and merger and acquisitions (MA)
activity are made on a quarterly basis. - In case of MA, the privatized companys share
price is replaced by the one of the resulting
newco in case of merger, and by the one of the
acquiror in case of an acquisition, if - the acquiror is listed in the same stock market
where the privatized company was initially
traded. - the acquirors mkt cap is not more than double
the target
68Calculations
- The index is capitalization-weighted, and
calculated with the Laspeyres formula, which
measures price changes against a fixed base
quantity weight. - The index is calculated on a pure price basis
(not total return), and uses daily data and
closing prices of the stocks at the base date and
at each date. - The source for price and quantity data is
Datastream.
69Concentration Ratios by Market Cap
as of 23/05/05.
70PB Index Coverage vs. Benchmark
as of 23/05/05
71PB Index Performance
72PB Index Performance
73PB Index Performance
74PB Index Performance
75PB Index Performance
76PB Index Performance
77PB Index Returns
78PB Index Average Excess Returns
NOTE Average excess return indicates the
historic average differential return of the index
to its respective benchmark. All values are
annualized.
79PB Index Volatility vs Benchmark
NOTE All values are annualized.
80Risk-adjusted returns Information Ratios
NOTE Information Ratio indicates the historic
average differential return of the index to its
respective benchmark per unit of historic
variability of the differential return.
81Risk-adjusted returns Sharpe Ratios
NOTE Sharpe Ratio indicates the historic average
differential return of the index over a risk-free
asset (Germany Interbank Rate 3m) per unit of
historic variability of the differential return.
82PB Index and CAPM
NOTE Estimation is based on daily data.
Sectorial controls included.
83Conclusion
- Strong overperformance of several PB Indexes
(Composite ? 6 over the 3 years period) - Overperformance survives when adjusted for risk
- Incremental performance of PB over well
diversified porfolios (Jensens ? ? 6, 10 on an
annual basis for PB Composite and Industrial,
respectively) - Open issues
- Research identifying the source of idiosyncratic
risk for privatized companies - Does residual ownership matters?